We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
The incidence of shoplifting was so extensive that it was crippling London's retail trade. This was the unequivocal message that the capital's traders intended to convey to Parliament in the late 1690s as the country's lawmakers debated the need for dedicated legislation. Petitioning Parliament, they related a litany of ills. Shoplifting was the daily experience of all London shopkeepers, they declared, ‘against which their strictest diligence cannot secure them’. They bewailed that due to the shoplifter's cunning and the inadequacy of sentencing under the law, those actually prosecuted were but a fraction of the shoplifters plying the crime: ‘Experience shews, that burning and whipping increases their number, and ripens their invention; so that few offenders are taken; when taken, not one in ten prosecuted.’ But how accurate were their accusations: was shoplifting indeed as frequent, pervasive and under-prosecuted as they asserted? In this chapter we interrogate that view, examining the extent of the crime.
We begin by projecting the true prevalence of the crime, calculating its scale from prosecution, retailer and offender evidence. An examination of the many factors impeding the stopping and prosecuting of perpetrators lends credence to the traders’ claims. The chapter then explores the geography and topography of the crime, identifying the location of incidents over time and the significance of their spatial patterning. It shows how retail specialisation and the casual nature of most offending, imparted in the last chapter, was formative to its spread. The exercise reveals that the shopkeepers most at risk were not those that previous historiography may lead us to expect. Perhaps surprisingly, shoplifting had a greater impact on local neighbourhood shops than the elite stores that were most emblematic of England's consumer renaissance.
Assessing the prevalence of the crime
In attempting to accurately quantify shoplifting we must grapple with a problem that has long frustrated historians. Only a proportion of actual thefts will ever be detected and prosecuted. The remainder, termed the ‘dark figure’ of unreported crime, can be as elusive today as in the eighteenth century. British self-report surveys in the last fifty years have suggested that only between one in forty and one in 250 shoplifting incidents result in a conviction or caution.
The prisoners came into our shop, in Chandois Street, Covent Garden, and looked upon some striped thread sattins and at last bought 14 yards. I heard a piece fall, and one of them took it up and laid it on the counter. I observed that they were shuffling something under their riding-hoods, and I told Mr Young, that I suspected they had stole a piece, upon which he presently follow'd them, and found this piece of satin upon Ward … They were both carried to Covent-Garden Round-house: and the same day examined before Justice Hilder, who granted a warrant for committing them to the Gatehouse, but in their way thither, with two constables with them in a coach and the Beadle behind, they were rescued, by several men.
This account of the trial of Ann Ward and Sarah Bream in 1735 only served to fuel contemporary suspicion that shoplifting was a form of organised crime. Pleading some years earlier for harsher laws, London retailers had complained bitterly that shoplifters ‘personate all degrees of buyers, in all their respective qualifications, having their several societies and walks, their cabals, receivers, solicitors and even their bullies to rescue them if taken’. While we may question the sincerity of their conviction, shopkeepers sought to convey a message that professional thieves, masquerading as customers, were plundering their businesses. By design or through ignorance they promoted a false understanding of a crime that, from the evidence of this study, was principally an intermittent form of makeshift for the poor. As this chapter discloses, those brought to court were more often amateur than professional, occasional than full-time, and opportunist than conspiring. This book begins by examining who within society became a shoplifter and why they stole. While offending behaviour formed a spectrum that stretched from recurrent through intermittent offending to the occasional bravado act, it was predominantly an economic resource for those struggling to make a living. So, let us review the evidence.
From fabrics to flat irons, shoplifters systematically sought items they valued. But did they privilege the same items that appealed to their middling and elite peers? Their choice can be of particular interest to historians who continue to debate what has been termed one of the conundrums of eighteenth-century consumption: how far down the social scale did the new goods and expanded consumption opportunities extend. By examining what items shoplifters stole we can observe whether their ‘alternative’ mode of consumption played a part in distributing novel and fashionable goods more widely throughout the eighteenth-century population. If, as some economic historians have suggested, the working incomes of the poor remained at too low a level for them to meaningfully participate in the century's reputed consumer boom, did shoplifting serve an enabling function?
However, suggesting that the crime brought unaffordable goods within financial reach begs a further and perhaps more interesting question: how actively did the poor avail themselves of this opportunity to acquire stylish attire and home embellishments? Historians have speculated that over the course of the century an appetite for consumer goods animated all levels of society. Jan de Vries has proposed that the desire for new home comforts was strong enough to encourage a greater industriousness in working households. Beverly Lemire has also been prominent in affirming the importance of fashion to such communities, albeit in a more democratised and popular guise. She contends that demand for this was widely met by the second-hand trade, supplied in part by shop theft, and asserts that ‘legal records abound with vivid depictions of the selectivity of … shoplifters, who in turn reflect the preferences of the wider market for stylish clothes’. But how sound is this conclusion? In its specific targeting of retail outlets, shoplifting was intriguingly different from other property theft. While burglars, housebreakers and pickpockets can rarely anticipate the exact content of their haul, this was a type of thieving in which perpetrators could very deliberately take their pick from the same range of new manufactured and imported goods on display to better-off shoppers.
In the summer of 1719 William Marvell entered a shop in the City of London and ‘cheapened’ the price of some silk handkerchiefs with the owner. Cheapening or bargaining for goods was standard practice in an age before fixed pricing. He then took the handkerchiefs to the door to show a female companion. Again, this desire to see goods in daylight was not unusual: early-eighteenth-century shop interiors were invariably dim or poorly candlelit. Marvell declined to purchase at the offered price of 12 shillings, but no sooner had he left than the handkerchiefs were found to be missing. Only then, too late, did the shopkeeper realise that his customer was a shoplifter. Sending his daughter fruitlessly after the thief, she returned shortly with the information that he had been seen by a neighbour who had recognised him as London's former hangman. There was to be no escape from justice for such an infamous figure. Six weeks later Marvell was captured in farmland on London's outskirts and taken to a local alehouse where he was identified by the shopkeeper's wife and daughter. His initial offer of recompense and claim he had been drunk at the time rejected, Marvell was swiftly charged with shoplifting and committed to appear at the next session of the Old Bailey. Within a fortnight he was found guilty and facing a sentence of death. Only witnesses to his character as ‘an honest and industrious man’ narrowly earned him the reprieve of transportation.
Marvell's celebrity appearance in the dock focused public attention on this newly capital crime, but it also highlighted many of its paradoxes. Was his theft driven by need? It was common knowledge that he had lost his executioner post two years earlier through debt. Or could it be the compulsion of greed? This period was witnessing a relaxing of older moral constraints on consumption, and social commentators were swift to predict the criminal implications of the poor coveting luxury. The silk handkerchief, worn as a neck adornment, had become the quintessential fashion accessory for working Londoners.
For the shoplifting crew are so vigilant and dextrous and come under so many disguises, that the tradesman cannot be too watchful, and in spight of all their sharp-sighted servants, they are sometimes out-witted and over-reach'd.
Daniel Defoe, writing his early-eighteenth-century trade manual, had no doubt that shoplifting was a battle of wits between shopkeeper and thief. In this chapter we draw on the wealth of information found in contemporary court transcripts to anatomise the tactics that shoplifters employed in order to steal, and the measures store owners took to resist their incursions. To better understand their respective stratagems and the dynamics of these encounters we turn to an explanatory framework developed in modern criminology. Routine activity theory seeks to define criminal behaviour in terms of the routines of the participants. It specifies that for a crime to occur there needs to be an offender, a target and the absence of an effective guardian against the crime. The target will be an object of high value to the thief: visible, accessible and portable. The crime will occur in a place which has a manager: for a shop, this will be the shopkeeper. Guardians, in the case of shoplifting, may be shop staff, police or very commonly other shoppers and the general public. This theory provides a useful model for illuminating the tactical manoeuvrings of eighteenth-century shoplifters and shopkeepers in their competing struggle for advantage. Repeatedly we find the evidence from the London and Northern sample cases endorses its validity for explaining patterns of customer theft behaviour in this earlier period. So, first, how did offenders identify the personal value and accessibility of their target object?
Planning the crime
While some thefts may have been on impulse, witness evidence suggests that thieves commonly took great care to size up the risks and potential rewards offered by individual shops. Birkhead Hitchcock noticed Thomas Smith ‘pass and repass the shop two or three times’, before stealing cloth from his open shop window, while Alexander White was spotted observing his chosen hosier's shop for an hour and a half.
On Saturday, 24 April 1784, William Mawhood, a London woollen draper with a shop in West Smithfield, recorded an eventful day in his diary:
Call'd on Sargeaunt. His clerk says they'll pay Bunting dividend of 10s. More next week. Lukin nor Rackett at home. See Mr Lamb and came to the Bank in his chariot. … Was meet by Mr Webb and others and told I had been robb'd. On arriving at my house found the[y] had taken the thief by the assistance of 2 blacksmiths, & likewise Mr Sargeaunts lad as an accomplice the witnesses having seen the lad come out of the shop and say to the two lurking fellows. viz I will do presently. The neighbours persuaded son Charles to let the Constable and Mr Brocklebank go with the 2 before a Magistrate, it happen'd to be Mr Aldm Hart who committed them both to Newgate. Self went to Mr Sargeaunt but he was from home but the clerk and a Mr Fawkes went to Newgate to see the lad and they think in Tuesday. The father and mother of the lad came, they say their son was always good till about a fortnight since
This is the only surviving example we have of an eighteenth-century shopkeeper's unmediated, contemporaneous reaction to a shoplifting incident which was subsequently tried at the Old Bailey. Perhaps surprisingly, there is no dwelling on the items stolen, or their value – later declared in court to be £5. The episode is portrayed as a minor neighbourhood drama; Mawhood's diary entry implies some regret that his son was persuaded to charge the perpetrators, some concern to keep on terms with a local business associate, and even some sympathy for a fellow parent. In financial terms, he is clearly more exercised by his earlier visit to the bank and the uncertainty of the forthcoming dividend.
William Mawhood may have been among London's wealthier traders. Joseph Collyer in 1761 estimated start-up costs for woollen drapers to be £1,000 to £5,000, the highest for any London retail trade.
England's law and criminal justice system were commonly accepted to be the primary means by which retailers could discourage theft of their stock, protect it from depredation and obtain a measure of legal redress for losses suffered. But prior to 1699 there was no specific law on shoplifting. It was the accession of William III and Mary II in February 1689 that heralded a period of more active parliamentary government and the fresh possibility of tackling perceived criminal ills legislatively. Beattie asserts that the ensuing momentum to extend the law was driven not by any formal programme or campaign, but by a pervasive national anxiety. In the wake of the Glorious Revolution England had entered a period of war and financial instability, intensifying a public suspicion that society was becoming increasingly immoral; crime, particularly that committed by women, was viewed with new alarm as a serious and growing problem. The institution of regular parliamentary sessions provided back-bench MPs with an unprecedented opportunity to confront these fears by lobbying for change. They, rather than the state, were the proposers of repeated Bills over the following two decades designed to address what was conceived to be the threat to life and property presented by an increasingly vicious working populace. The overall intention of these parliamentarians and their supporters was to strengthen the punitive impact of the criminal law. However, one of their first Acts, passed in 1691, carried a clause that sought to remedy an apparent unfairness by extending ‘benefit of clergy’ to women on the same terms as men. As a result, women were no longer subject to the death penalty for the theft of goods over 10 shillings. It was in part the adverse impact of this on London retailing that culminated in the passing of the discrete Shoplifting Act in 1699 by which the theft of goods with a value exceeding 5 shillings became a capital offence.
In this chapter we explore retailers’ engagement with the law on shoplifting, from their formative role in the genesis of the Shoplifting Act to their more equivocal part in its repeal some 120 years later.
With the passing of the Shoplifting Act in 1699, the crime of shoplifting acquired a new prominence. Heightened alarm at retail losses and a pervading belief in the deterrent effect of harsher laws had converged to make shoplifting a capital offence, a notorious status that it retained for the next 120 years. The focus of this book has been how retailers and the wider population experienced and responded to customer theft within the cultural and economic context of the period. It has analysed the crime's social characteristics, its impact on commerce and its potential influence on the development of contemporary criminal justice and material culture, exhibiting the emblematic nature of the offence. The preceding chapters have examined in some detail the demography of those charged with shoplifting, their tactics and shopkeepers’ countermeasures, the nature and significance of what was stolen, and the economic effect of the crime on the retail sector. At the same time the book has followed the changes in retailers’ relationship to the law on shoplifting and concurrent shifts in public attitudes, arguing that in both of these there was a notable transformation in outlook and perception over time.
Shoplifting became an accustomed expedient for some of the most economically vulnerable in society, attracting both men and women. The nation's multiplying stores were increasingly available and the routine of shopping offered a plausible pretext for customers constrained to steal. Theft from neighbourhood shops and those with busy passing trade furnished some of the poorest, largely urban populace with a source of intermittent subsidy. Analysis of the occupational circumstances and times of theft of those prosecuted indicates that shoplifting was only a full-time occupation for a minority of these thieves, for most it was a casual and opportunist means to supplement low incomes or tide them over patches of unemployment. Few shoplifters from higher classes reached court, certainly in part due to retailers’ demonstrable reluctance to suspect or detain such customers. But while we cannot know the degree to which this disguised the scale of middling theft, there is no evidence to suggest it was substantial in this period.
In the late eighteenth and early nineteenth centuries, the internal migration of a growing population transformed Britain into a 'society of strangers'. The coming and going of so many people wreaked havoc on the institutions through which Britons had previously addressed questions of collective responsibility. Poor relief, charity briefs, box clubs, and the like relied on personal knowledge of reputations for their effectiveness and struggled to accommodate the increasing number of unknown migrants. Trust among Strangers re-centers problems of trust in the making of modern Britain and examines the ways in which upper-class reformers and working-class laborers fashioned and refashioned the concept and practice of friendly society to make promises of collective responsibility effective - even among strangers. The result is a profoundly new account of how Britons navigated their way into the modern world.