Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-21T11:22:34.478Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Experimental evidence suggests intergroup relations are, by default, neutral rather than aggressive

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  15 January 2024

Hirotaka Imada
Affiliation:
School of Economics & Management, Kochi University of Technology, Kochi City, Kochi, Japan [email protected] [email protected]; https://www.kochi-tech.ac.jp/profile/en/mifune-nobuhiro.html
Nobuhiro Mifune*
Affiliation:
School of Economics & Management, Kochi University of Technology, Kochi City, Kochi, Japan [email protected] [email protected]; https://www.kochi-tech.ac.jp/profile/en/mifune-nobuhiro.html
*
*Corresponding author.

Abstract

The target article offers a game-theoretical analysis of primitive intergroup aggression (i.e., raiding) and discusses difficulties in achieving peace. We argue the analysis does not capture the actual strategy space, missing out “do-nothing.” Experimental evidence robustly shows people prefer doing nothing against out-group members over cooperating with/attacking them. Thus, the target article overestimates the likelihood of intergroup aggression.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press

In the target article, Glowacki offers the game-theoretical analysis of war and peace. Glowacki further argues that each member of groups face a social dilemma in which they have to make a choice between intergroup cooperation (cooperation) and conflict (defection), and, all members of both groups must choose intergroup cooperation to establish peace (Fig. 1 in the target article). Referencing anthropological and archaeological evidence, Glowacki pointed out that social structures were necessary for people to coordinate individuals' behaviour so that they could establish peace.

We would like to first point out that Glowacki's game-theoretical analysis fails to represent the true strategy space; more specifically, Glowacki rules out the strategy of “doing nothing” and assumes that people either cooperated or attacked an out-group member (see Fig. 1). We argue that the lack of the strategy in Glowacki's discussion leads to an overestimation of the likelihood of people initiating intergroup conflict and an overstatement of the role of social structures in helping people avoid intergroup conflict and promoting peace.

Figure 1. Peace as an elaborated prisoner's dilemma.

Intergroup cooperation and conflicts have been extensively studied in the experimental literature in psychology (Balliet, Wu, & De Dreu, Reference Balliet, Wu and De Dreu2014; Everett, Faber, & Crockett, Reference Everett, Faber and Crockett2015), economics (Charness & Chen, Reference Charness and Chen2020), and evolutionary biology (Rusch, Reference Rusch2014; Rusch & Gavrilets, Reference Rusch and Gavrilets2020). Regarding intergroup cooperation, previous studies have documented in-group favouritism, using a variety of economic games such as prisoner's dilemma, dictator, trust, and public goods games, and they have robustly shown that it is increased in-group cooperation, rather than reduced out-group cooperation that explains in-group favouritism (Aaldering, Ten Velden, van Kleef, & De Dreu, Reference Aaldering, Ten Velden, van Kleef and De Dreu2018; Balliet et al., Reference Balliet, Wu and De Dreu2014). That is, people do not discriminate between out-group members and strangers whose group membership is unknown. In other words, people do not actively reduce out-group cooperation (i.e., out-group hate).

Regarding intergroup aggression, Mifune and colleagues developed the preemptive strike game in which two players choose between preemptively attacking their partner and doing nothing until the end of the game (Mifune, Hizen, Kamijo, & Okano, Reference Mifune, Hizen, Kamijo and Okano2016; Mifune, Simunovic, & Yamagishi, Reference Mifune, Simunovic and Yamagishi2017; Simunovic, Mifune, & Yamagishi, Reference Simunovic, Mifune and Yamagishi2013). Using the game and focusing on arbitrarily created experimental groups (i.e., minimal groups; Tajfel, Billig, Bundy, & Flament, Reference Tajfel, Billig, Bundy and Flament1971), they have consistently found that people are not more likely to preemptively attack an out-group partner than an in-group partner. In other words, when people are presented with a choice between the intergroup aggression and do-nothing strategies, the latter is preferred.

Importantly, previous studies using the preemptive strike game have also revealed that people by default do not hold the expectation that out-group members are aggressive towards in-group members. This suggests that people expect out-group members to choose do-nothing rather than aggression. This is in stark contrast to Glowacki's argument that people originally lack the expectation that out-group members are not aggressive.

Nevertheless, while out-group membership per se does not lead people to believe that out-group members would attack them, some concrete out-group memberships such as certain nationalities may elicit such a belief (Jing et al., Reference Jing, Gries, Li, Stivers, Mifune, Kuhlman and Bai2017; Romano, Gross, & De Dreu, Reference Romano, Gross and De Dreu2022). Jing et al. (Reference Jing, Gries, Li, Stivers, Mifune, Kuhlman and Bai2017) let participants play the preemptive strike game using national intergroup contexts rather than minimal group contexts. They found that Japanese participants were more likely to preemptively strike their partner when the partner was American or Chinese, compared to when their partner was Japanese. Similarly, Chinese participants also displayed the increased tendency to preemptively attack others when their partner was Japanese or American as compared to when their partner was Chinese. Yet, Americans did not show such a tendency, replicating the studies using the minimal group contexts. More recently, Romano et al. (Reference Romano, Gross and De Dreu2022) revealed that people expect others from certain nations to be more aggressive and competitive than they actually are. The comparisons of the findings from minimal versus actual intergroup contexts suggest that there are situations and intergroup contexts that mirror the Glowacki's view that intergroup conflicts are inevitable without social structures. In other words, there are some contexts in which intergroup aggression dominates do-nothing and individuals need social structures to get out of intergroup conflicts.

Empirical support for the absence of the tendency to attack out-group members also comes from studies using intergroup prisoner's dilemma-maximizing difference game (IPD-MD; Halevy, Bornstein, & Sagiv, Reference Halevy, Bornstein and Sagiv2008) and its variants (Aaldering & Böhm, Reference Aaldering and Böhm2019; Wit & Kerr, Reference Wit and Kerr2002). In IPD-MD, for instance, participants can choose between selfish, weak parochial cooperation (in-group cooperation + do-nothing to out-group members), and strong parochial cooperation (i.e., in-group cooperation + out-group aggression). Previous studies have demonstrated that people have a strong preference to weak over strong parochial cooperation (Mifune, Reference Mifune2022; Weisel & Zultan, Reference Weisel and Zultan2021; Yamagishi & Mifune, Reference Yamagishi and Mifune2016).

In summary, the series of the experimental evidence suggest that the do-nothing strategy is dominant when people could choose between cooperation, aggression, and do-nothing. Similarly, people would expect out-group members to prefer the do-nothing strategy. As such, we argue that Glowacki overestimated the tendency of people to initiate intergroup aggression without social structures. Starting from the overestimated tendency to instigate intergroup aggression and the likelihood of intergroup conflict, Glowacki discusses the role of social structures (i.e., hierarchies and leadership) in coordinating people's interests and argues that they either enables and facilitates mutual cooperation or exacerbates intergroup conflicts. As such, Glowacki does not discuss how social structures instigate people to initiate intergroup conflicts. In light of the experimental evidence, we argue that it is fruitful to revisit the roles that institutions and leadership played in steering intergroup relations. Namely, it is of vital importance to elucidate how social structures help people move from the mutual do-nothing towards peace and war (Fig. 2).

Figure 2. Revised role of social structures in coordinating people in the dilemma.

Financial support

This research is supported by JSPS KAKENHI Grant Number 21H00934.

Competing interest

None.

References

Aaldering, H., & Böhm, R. (2019). Parochial versus universal cooperation: Introducing a novel economic game of within- and between-group interaction. Social Psychological and Personality Science, 11(1), 3645. https://doi.org/10.1177/1948550619841627CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aaldering, H., Ten Velden, F. S., van Kleef, G. A., & De Dreu, C. K. W. (2018). Parochial cooperation in nested intergroup dilemmas is reduced when it harms out-groups. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 114(6), 909923. https://doi.org/10.1037/pspi0000125CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Balliet, D., Wu, J., & De Dreu, C. K. W. (2014). Ingroup favoritism in cooperation: A meta-analysis. Psychological Bulletin, 140(6), 15561581. https://doi.org/10.1037/a0037737CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Charness, G., & Chen, Y. (2020). Social identity, group behavior, and teams. Annual Review of Economics, 12, 691713. https://doi.org/10.1146/ANNUREV-ECONOMICS-091619-032800CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Everett, J. A. C., Faber, N. S., & Crockett, M. (2015). Preferences and beliefs in ingroup favoritism. Frontiers in Behavioral Neuroscience, 9(Feb), 121. https://doi.org/10.3389/fnbeh.2015.00015CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Halevy, N., Bornstein, G., & Sagiv, L. (2008). “In-group love” and “out-group hate” as motives for individual participation in intergroup conflict: A new game paradigm. Psychological Science, 19(4), 405411. https://doi.org/10.1111/j.1467-9280.2008.02100.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Jing, Y., Gries, P. H., Li, Y., Stivers, A. W., Mifune, N., Kuhlman, D. M., & Bai, L. (2017). War or peace? How the subjective perception of great power interdependence shapes preemptive defensive aggression. Frontiers in Psychology, 8, 864. https://www.frontiersin.org/articles/10.3389/fpsyg.2017.00864CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mifune, N. (2022). Null results for the steal-framing effect on out-group aggression. Scientific Reports, 12(1), 19. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41598-021-04729-zCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mifune, N., Hizen, Y., Kamijo, Y., & Okano, Y. (2016). Preemptive striking in individual and group conflict. PLoS ONE, 11(5), e0154859. https://doi.org/10.1371/journal.pone.0154859CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mifune, N., Simunovic, D., & Yamagishi, T. (2017). Intergroup biases in fear-induced aggression. Frontiers in Psychology, 8(Jan), 49. https://doi.org/10.3389/FPSYG.2017.00049/BIBTEXCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Romano, A., Gross, J., & De Dreu, C. K. W. (2022). Conflict misperceptions between citizens and foreigners across the globe. PNAS Nexus, 1(5), pgac267. https://doi.org/10.1093/pnasnexus/pgac267CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rusch, H. (2014). The evolutionary interplay of intergroup conflict and altruism in humans: A review of parochial altruism theory and prospects for its extension. Proceedings of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 281(1794), 20141539. https://doi.org/10.1098/rspb.2014.1539CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Rusch, H., & Gavrilets, S. (2020). The logic of animal intergroup conflict: A review. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 178, 10141030. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jebo.2017.05.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simunovic, D., Mifune, N., & Yamagishi, T. (2013). Preemptive strike: An experimental study of fear-based aggression. Journal of Experimental Social Psychology, 49(6), 11201123. https://doi.org/10.1016/J.JESP.2013.08.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tajfel, H., Billig, M. G., Bundy, R. P., & Flament, C. (1971). Social categorization and intergroup behaviour. European Journal of Social Psychology, 1(2), 149178. https://doi.org/10.1002/ejsp.2420010202CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weisel, O., & Zultan, R. (2021). Perceptions of conflict: Parochial cooperation and outgroup spite revisited. Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 167, 5771. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.obhdp.2021.04.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wit, A. P., & Kerr, N. L. (2002). “Me versus just us versus us all” categorization and cooperation in nested social dilemmas. Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 83(3), 616637. https://doi.org/10.1037/0022-3514.83.3.616CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Yamagishi, T., & Mifune, N. (2016). Parochial altruism: Does it explain modern human group psychology? Current Opinion in Psychology, 7, 3943. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.copsyc.2015.07.015CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Figure 1. Peace as an elaborated prisoner's dilemma.

Figure 1

Figure 2. Revised role of social structures in coordinating people in the dilemma.