Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-mkpzs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-26T02:11:02.142Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Framing, equivalence, and rational inference

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  25 October 2022

David R. Mandel*
Affiliation:
Intelligence, Influence, and Collaboration Section, Defence Research and Development Canada, Toronto, Ontario M3K 2C9, [email protected]://sites.google.com/site/themandelian/home

Abstract

Bermúdez's case for rational framing effects, while original, is unconvincing and gives only parenthetical treatment to the problematic assumptions of extensional and semantic equivalence of alternative frames in framing experiments. If the assumptions are false, which they sometimes are, no valid inferences about “framing effects” follow and, then, neither do inferences about human rationality. This commentary recaps the central problem.

Type
Open Peer Commentary
Copyright
Copyright © The Crown in Right of Canada (Defence R&D Canada), 2022

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bruni, R., Giacobazzi, R., Gori, R., Garcia-Contreras, I., & Pavlovic, D. (2020). Abstract extensionality: On the properties of incomplete abstract interpretations. Proceedings of the ACM on Programming Languages, 4(POPL), Article 28, 128. https://doi.org/10.1145/3371096CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, S., & Mandel, D. R. (2021). Risky-choice framing and rational decision-making. Philosophy Compass, 16(8), e12763. https://doi.org/10.1111/phc3.12763Google Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1979). Prospect theory: An analysis of decision under risk. Econometrica, 47, 263291. http://dx.doi.org/10.2307/1914185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., & Tversky, A. (1984). Choices, values, and frames. American Psychologist, 39, 341350. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/0003-066X.39.4.341CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Macdonald, R. R. (1986). Credible conceptions and implausible probabilities. British Journal of Mathematical and Statistical Psychology, 39, 1527. http://dx.doi.org/10.1111/j.2044-8317.1986.tb00842.xCrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mandel, D. R. (2014). Do framing effects reveal irrational choice? Journal of Experimental Psychology: General, 143, 11851198. http://dx.doi.org/10.1037/a0034207CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Mandel, D. R. (2021). Theories, queries, “frames” and linguistic games: commentary on Wall, Crookes, Johnson & Weber (2020) (and the literature on risky-choice framing). March 19. https://doi.org/10.31234/osf.io/c5bf4Google Scholar
McKenzie, C. R. M., & Nelson, J. D. (2003). What a speaker's choice of frame reveals: Reference points, frame selection, and framing effects. Psychonomic Bulletin & Review, 10, 596602. https://doi.org/10.3758/BF03196520CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Sher, S., & McKenzie, C. R. M. (2006). Information leakage from logically equivalent frames. Cognition, 101, 467494. http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/j.cognition.2005.11.001CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., & Kahneman, D. (1981). The framing of decisions and the psychology of choice. Science, 211, 453458. http://dx.doi.org/10.1126/science.7455683CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed