We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
War crimes constitute breaches of LOIAC giving rise to penal accountability of the individuals who perpetrated the proscribed acts. In the past, it was frequently asserted that every breach of LOIAC was a war crime, but – as pointed out already by H. Lauterpacht – ‘textbook writers and, occasionally, military manuals and official pronouncements have erred on the side of comprehensiveness’ in making ‘no attempt to distinguish between violations of the rules of warfare and war crimes’.2179 It is currently clear that only select violations of LOIAC are stigmatized as war crimes.2180 Some of these violations are regarded as ‘grave’ breaches (see infra 1066). But ‘[o]ther serious violations’ of LOIAC are listed as war crimes in Article 8(2)(b) of the Rome Statute (see infra 1067). Of course, by itself, the adjective ‘serious’ (or, for that matter, ‘grave’) does not provide a useful compass indicating the contours of war crimes.2181 War crimes must be defined in specie.
This chapter is the final component of this book’s complexity theory of economic evolution, but not the least: it brings together all the elements developed in previous chapters to build a general macro theory of innovation and economic growth. As debated in Chapter 3, in economic theory, there is no real consensus across schools on the nature of growth. There is, however, consensus on the idea that growth originates from the cumulative effect of innovation. In Chapter 8, a theory of creative destruction was developed that explains, at the very least, productivity growth from cumulative process innovation. To a lesser degree, it explains product innovation and product diversity growth. In this chapter, it is shown that process and product innovation have a co-evolutionary role in generating economic growth in a demand-led model of economic evolution. From there, a closed set of relationships is derived to represent the macroeconomic connection and causation between innovation, productivity, employment, production, investment and demand, offering a complete model of endogenous economic growth based on innovation.
The closing act of the story concerns the drafting of the final judgment. The final task of judicial bureaucrats is to stitch together the fragmentary instructions received from the judges to create coherent and persuasive texts. Like weaving, the drafting process is all but smooth. Every time the warp meets the weft, loose threads come out which must be ironed out. Likewise, every new paragraph added to the text of a judgment reveals logical leaps, internal inconsistencies, and gaps in the reasoning that must be papered over for the decision to wield its prescriptive and symbolic authority. Despite these difficulties, the final decision – the magical artefact that makes the pride of our lot – is somehow churned out on time. Its seamless fabric, now up for scrutiny by journalists, practitioners, and scholars, carefully conceals the infinite series of choices, confrontations, and hesitations that marked every turn of the proceedings.
The requirement of distinction between combatants and civilians – as well as between military objectives and civilian objects – is underscored in Article 48 of AP/I, entitled ‘[b]asic rule’:
This chapter flashes back to the first days of Sophie’s employment at the ICJ registry, and sees her and her girlfriend Norma mull over the socio-professional features of the international judicial community. The chapter lays the theoretical foundations of the book and provides the reader with pointers to interpret the unfolding of judicial proceedings. The international judicial community has a twofold structure, at once cooperative and competitive. On the one hand, its members work together to secure control on courts and tribunals and insulate their internal activities from outside interference. On the other hand, community members ceaselessly strive to maximize their relative capital in a ruthless struggle for authority and prestige. The practices of the community are patterned, as they present regularities over time; they are competent, as they rest on collective background knowledge; and they weave together the discursive and the material world. Thus, community practices are the vehicle of both continuity and change, constraint and freedom in international adjudication.
Energy and climate policies may have significant economy-wide impacts that are regularly assessed based on quantitative energy-environment-economy models. These tend to vary in their conclusions on the scale and direction of the likely macroeconomic impacts of a low-carbon transition. This chapter traces the characteristic discrepancies in models’ outcomes to their origins in different macroeconomic theories, most importantly their treatment of technological innovation and finance. The relevant branches of macro-innovation theory are analysed and grouped into two classes: ‘equilibrium’ and ‘non-equilibrium’, which yield opposite conclusions for the economic impacts of low-carbon policies. It is shown that model outcomes are mainly determined by their representations of monetary and finance dimensions, and their interactions with investment, innovation and technological change.
This chapter explores the scientific consistency problems with current economic analysis of policy, offering a way forward to rebuild a consistent framework under the umbrella of complexity economics. A standard simple representation of the policy cycle is used, in order to place the role of scientists and economists into the policy-making process, and thus identify what kind of evidence is used in which stage of the policy-making process. Normative and positive traditions of policy analysis are described, with their respective roles in the policy cycle, and current inconsistencies identified. Inconsistencies in the philosophy of science currently used in economics are discussed. The Lucas critique is reviewed, arguably the main problem in economics. A list is drawn for desired empirical evidence to develop a complexity theory of economics.
This chapter concludes the discussion of interpretation by focusing on the emotions and mental processes of the interpreter. Each case presents at least one dilemma that cannot be solved through pure legal deduction. What options, then, does the interpreter have? First, they will seek the illusory comfort of legal objectivity, and convince themselves that the answer is out there, buried somewhere in the record. But it is not. Second, the interpreter will try to exercise responsible agency and provide an answer that best resonates with their ethical or political commitments. But the interpreter does not really know which interpretive outcome is preferable. Third, the interpreter will turn to the standard practices of the community and write pages upon pages of corollary analysis, hoping that the intractable issue will magically vanish. Finally, the interpreter will stick to their decision and defend it as the sole logical solution.
Support for redistribution in developing countries has been found to be weakly related to income, meaning the poor are not much likelier than the rich to support redistribution. If not economic self-interest, what explains support for redistribution? A multilevel regression analysis covering a decade of public opinion data from 18 Latin American countries finds support for explanations centered on social affinity. Specifically, people in more culturally divided countries are less supportive of redistribution. This relationship is strongest among low-income individuals, who are more likely to support redistribution than richer people in countries with low levels of diversity, but no more likely and, by some measures, less likely to support redistribution where diversity is highest. Economic distance between groups also matters. Support for redistribution increases when middle-class incomes are closer to those of the poor than the rich. Support declines as the middle class pulls ahead of the poor.
The Cuba Reader: History, Culture, Politics. 2nd ed., revised and updated. Edited by Aviva Chomsky, Barry Carr, Alfredo Prieto, and Pamela Maria Smorkaloff. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2019. Pp. xi + 744. $32.95 paperback. ISBN: 9781478003939.
Picturing Cuba: Art, Culture, and Identity on the Island and in the Diaspora. Edited by Jorge Duany. Gainesville: University Press of Florida, 2019. Pp. xii + 320. $35.00 paperback. ISBN: 9781683402091.
The Cuban Hustle: Culture, Politics, Everyday Life. By Sujatha Fernandes. Durham, NC: Duke University Press, 2020. Pp. ix + 184. $24.95 paperback. ISBN: 9781478009641.
Entangled Terrains and Identities in Cuba: Memories of Guantánamo. By Asa McKercher and Catherine Krull. Lanham, MD: Lexington Books, 2019. Pp. xxiv + 188. $90.00 hardcover. ISBN: 9781793602770.
El árbol de las revoluciones: Ideas y poder en América Latina. By Rafael Rojas. Madrid: Turner, 2021. Pp. 302. ISBN: 9788418895029.
Beyond Cuban Waters: África, La Yuma, and the Island’s Global Imagination. By Paul Ryer. Nashville: Vanderbilt University Press, 2018. Pp. x + 240. $39.95 paperback. ISBN: 9780826521194.
Dancing with the Revolution: Power, Politics, and Privilege in Cuba. By Elizabeth B. Schwall. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press, 2021. Pp. xi + 298. $34.95 paperback. ISBN: 9781469662978.
Women’s Empowerment and Disempowerment in Brazil: The Rise and Fall of President Dilma Rousseff. By Pedro A. G. dos Santos and Farida Jalalzai. Philadelphia: Temple University Press, 2021. Pp. 213. $91.05 hardcover. ISBN: 9781439916179.
A Horizon of (Im)possibilities: A Chronicle of Brazil’s Conservative Turn. Edited by Katerina Hatzikidi and Eduardo Dullo. London: University of London Press, 2021. Pp. 195. $35.00 paperback. IBSN: 9781908857897.
Cynical Citizenship: Gender, Regionalism, and Political Subjectivity in Porto Alegre, Brazil. By Benjamin Junge. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press, 2018. Pp. xi + 304. $64.70 hardcover. ISBN: 9780826359445.
Precarious Democracy: Ethnographies of Hope, Despair, and Resistance in Brazil. Edited by Benjamin Junge, Sean T. Mitchell, Alvaro Jarrín, and Lucia Cantero. New Brunswick, NJ: Rutgers University Press, 2021. Pp. 238. $39.95 paperback. ISBN: 9781978825659.
O Brasil dobrou à direita: Uma radiografia da eleição de Bolsonaro em 2018. By Jairo Nicolau. Rio de Janeiro: Zahar, 2019. Pp. 144. $23.04 paperback. ISBN: 9788537818886.
Dilma’s Downfall: The Impeachment of Brazil’s First Woman President and the Pathway to Power for Jair Bolsonaro’s Far-Right. By Peter Prengaman and Mauricio Savarese. New York: Associated Press. Pp. 274. $14.52 paper. ISBN: 9781735845999.
Gender and Representation in Latin America. Edited by Leslie A. Schwindt-Bayer. New York: Oxford University Press, 2018. Pp. xv + 352. $38.95 paper. ISBN: 9780190851231.
Democracy against Parties: The Divergent Fates of Latin America’s New Left Contenders. By Brandon Van Dyck. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press, 2021. Pp. 288. $55.00 hardcover. ISBN: 9780822946946.
As the climate emergency intensifies, rights-based climate cases – litigation that is based on human rights law – are becoming an increasingly important tool for securing more ambitious climate action. This book is the first to offer a systematic analysis of the universe of these cases known as human rights and climate change (HRCC) cases. By combining theory, empirical documentation, and strategic debate among preeminent scholars and practitioners from around the world, the book captures the roots, legal innovations, empirical richness, impact, and challenges of this dynamic field of sociolegal practice. It looks specifically at the sociolegal origins and trajectory of HRCC cases, the legal innovations of this type of litigation, and the strategies and impacts of these cases. In doing so, this book equips litigators, researchers, practitioners, students, and concerned citizens with an understanding of an important method of holding governments and corporations accountable for climate harms. This book is also available as Open Access on Cambridge Core.
This book explores the comparative historical evolution of the European, Inter-American and African regional human rights systems. The book devotes attention to various factors that have shaped the systems: the different circumstances in which they were founded; the influence of major states and inter-state politics within their respective regions; gradual processes of institutional evolution; and the impact of human rights advocates and claimants. Throughout, the book devotes careful attention to the impact of institutional and procedural choices on the functioning of human rights systems. Overarchingly, the book explores the contextually-generated differences between the three systems, suggesting that human rights practice is less unitary than it might at times appear. Prescriptively, the book proposes that, contrary to the received wisdom in some quarters, the Inter-American system's dual-track approach may provide the most promising model in regards to future human rights system design.