We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
This chapter discusses the Court’s 1961 judgment, Pork Products, where the Court insisted that the member states had no right to unilaterally adopt safeguard measures within the European Economic Community. Unlike many other trade treaties, the Treaty of Rome required that its member states request prior authorization from the European Commission before any safeguard or escape measures could be adopted. The Pork Products judgment, however, also revealed the inadequacy of the mechanisms explicitly provided for by the Treaty to ensure the effectiveness of this system. Making the Treaty of Rome’s prohibition on unilateral safeguard mechanisms effective would therefore require the direct effect of European law before national courts within the member states.
This chapter discusses the Court’s 1964 judgment, Dairy Products, where the Court declared that self-help mechanisms of reciprocity and retaliation, so important in many trade treaty systems, were comprehensively prohibited within the European legal order. This judgment is often rightly understood as marking an essential difference between European law and general international law. This chapter demonstrates that the principle announced in Dairy Products was also directly connected to the direct effect and supremacy doctrines of European law, again as shown by national court enforcement of treaty obligations in other treaty systems, and by the writings of judge Lecourt.
This chapter builds on the detailed discussions of particular ECJ judgments earlier in the book to put forward a new way of understanding the founding of the European legal order. It includes both the doctrines establishing rights for individual litigants before national courts and the doctrines specifying new and demanding relationships between the European states, and demonstrates how each is related to the other. It concludes with a discussion of judge Robert Lecourt’s role in the early decades of the European Court of Justice.
This chapter discusses the Court’s 1972 judgment, International Fruit, where the Court denied that provisions of the General Agreement on Tariffs and Trade (GATT) should be granted direct effect within the European legal order. This judgment is often understood as the first of many instances in which the Court denied the direct effect of GATT, and later World Trade Organization (WTO), obligations. This chapter uses the Court’s rejection of direct effect in International Fruit to offer an improved understanding of the Court’s declaration of direct effect in Van Gend en Loos, highlighting its connections to the prohibition of inter-state retaliation and unilateral safeguard mechanisms within the European legal order.
This chapter discusses the Court’s 1979 judgment, Sheep Meat, where the Court insisted on its longstanding prohibitions of both unilateral safeguards and inter-state retaliation during a difficult agricultural dispute between France and the United Kingdom. This chapter uses the Sheep Meat dispute to elaborate on the strengths and limitations of the system of direct effect as a solution to international collective action problems within the European legal order.
This chapter discusses the Court’s 1974 judgment, Van Duyn, where the Court declared that provisions of Directives could enjoy direct effect in the national legal order. This judgment is often recognized as the landmark judgment on the ‘direct effect of Directives’, and remains a controversial decision. This chapter demonstrates that the direct effect of Directives was a logical consequence of the Court’s use of direct effect as a substitute for inter-state retaliation, and shows that this understanding of the direct effect of Directives can be found in the early writings of judge Lecourt.
This chapter discusses the Court’s 1963 judgment, Van Gend en Loos, where the Court declared that European law could be relied upon by private individuals before their national courts. The direct effect of European law is often understood as empowering private individuals and national courts, as supplementing the European Commission-initiated compliance procedure set out in Article 169 of the Treaty of Rome, and increasing the binding nature of European law. This chapter demonstrates that the direct effect of European law was also directly connected to the Court’s rejection of the possibility of inter-state retaliation within the European Economic Community. This is demonstrated both by advocacy of direct effect for other trade-related treaty systems, where reformers often wish to suppress retaliatory enforcement mechanisms, and by the writings of judge Lecourt, which demonstrate that this important aspect of direct effect was well recognized by one of the Court’s then most influential judges.
This chapter discusses a mechanism linking revolutionary terrorism and interwar development paths. The mechanism relates to the constraints imposed by the community of support on the terrorist groups. According to the argument, in those places in which the radical Left was stronger (as revealed by a powerful anarchist and/or communist movement), the likelihood of a segment of the Left supporting armed struggle was higher. This was typically the case in countries with a non-liberal past. To show this, evidence about negative cases is examined in depth. Negative cases refer to armed groups that had the capacity to kill but refrained from doing so. Almost all of the negative cases (such as the Weather Underground Organization) are concentrated in countries that had a liberal past throughout the twentieth century. In countries with a non-liberal past, repression of the protests of the late 1960s and early 1970s was interpreted by the radical Left as evidence of the persistence of an authoritarian state operating under a democratic facade; this deficit of state legitimacy was crucial for radical activists to support revolutionary terrorism.
This chapter presents first the historical context under which revolutionary terrorism emerged and then summarizes the general argument of the book. Regarding the historical context, the 1950s and 1960s were years of economic convergence, with developing countries catching up with those that were more advanced. Despite this economic convergence, the countries responded very differently to the shock of the radical protests of the late 1960s. In some countries lethal violence emerged, in some others it did not. It is argued that this variation matches the variation between liberal and non-liberal developments in the interwar years. The reasons why the relevant comparison is with the interwar period are analyzed and discussed.
The introduction presents the research question on the cross-national variation in revolutionary terrorism; it justifies its historical and political relevance; it criticizes the existing quantitative literature (that is too focused on contemporary explanatory variables); it presents the research design (an intermediate-N design with a historical-comparative approach); it discusses methodological issues on historical causation; and it analyzes previous work on revolutionary terrorism; and it explains the structure of the book.
This chapter presents the phenomenon to be studied, revolutionary terrorism. The chapter has three parts. In the first, the ideology of this form of terrorism and its historical precedents are discussed. The basic tenet of the revolutionary terrorists was that violence was necessary to provoke insurrection among the broad working class and its allies against capitalism and liberal, bourgeois democracy. The different mechanisms through which terrorist violence may be linked to mobilization are analyzed, paying special attention to the anarchist doctrine of “propaganda by the deed” developed at the end of nineteenth century. The second part explores revolutionary terrorism as a late and deviant branch of the revolutionary activity that starts with the success of Fidel Castro and Ernesto “Che” Guevara in the Cuban revolution. In more advanced Latin American countries, Uruguay and Argentina, rural guerrilla groups of the Cuban type evolved into urban, underground groups; and this is the form of violence that traveled to affluent countries in the early 1970s. The third part of the chapter provides detailed data about the characteristics of terrorist revolutionary violence (levels of lethality, evolution, target selection, selectivity of violence, and mode of organization) based on an original data set.