We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
We examine the question of whether economic winners were more likely to support European Union (EU) membership than economic losers in post-communist countries. We include in our analysis every cross-national survey of post-communist countries with both a measure of individual attitudes toward EU membership as well as an appropriate measure of individual self-assessment of economic progress. The resultant data set contains data from 67 different surveys over a 12-year period (1991–2003) in all 10 post-communist countries that have joined the EU to date. Using a variety of analytical techniques, ranging from simple cross-tables and multivariate analysis of the individual surveys to multilevel models of a fully pooled data set, we show that the pattern of economic winners being more likely to support EU membership for their country is remarkably consistent across both time and space. At the same time, the dynamic component of the analysis allows us to show that the size of this gap varies over time, with winners being even more likely to support EU membership than losers when EU membership is a more realistic possibility.
This article seeks to establish a better scholarly understanding of former Russian President Boris Yeltsin’s decision to launch an ill-planned, risky, and ultimately disastrous invasion of the breakaway republic of Chechnya in 1994. Examining the decision-making environment that led up to the invasion, I conclude that while neorealism provides an adequate explanation for Yeltsin’s motives in this case, the decisions that he made in pursuit of these goals do not reflect the logic of rational utility maximization commonly associated with neorealist theory. Instead, I suggest that prospect theory – based on the idea that decision-makers tend to be risk averse when confronted with choices between gains while risk acceptant when confronted with losses – offers significantly more explanatory insight in this case. Thus, the article offers further support for an alternative theoretical approach to international relations that some scholars have termed ‘cognitive realism’, incorporating neorealist motives with a more empirically accurate perspective on the decision-making processes undertaken in pursuit of these motives.
Improvement of regulatory quality has become one of the most important items on the European Union’s (EU) Lisbon Strategy for Growth and Jobs. In this context, the European Commission has sought to influence the regulatory reform policies of the Member States, focusing on the implementation of better regulation principles and tools. This article explores the interactive nature of Europeanization, viewing domestic institutions as ‘users’ of European policies according to their strategies. The author performs a within-case study based on a bottom–up research design, analysing the impact of EU better regulation on Italy. The results show that the effects of Europeanization relate more to agenda setting than to implementation – the latter is still, prevalently, determined by domestic factors.
In theory, lower-level governments (provinces, regional governments, or member states) operating in multilevel systems within and beyond the nation-state can choose from a wide repertoire of modes of policy coordination to solve collective problems non-hierarchically. These modes range from unilateral policy emulation over informal intergovernmental agreements to binding interstate law. The modes that governments are willing and capable to use, however, vary considerably across multilevel systems which affects governments’ collective problem-solving capacity. This paper argues that the nature of executive–legislative relations in lower-level governments is crucial to account for this variation. The presence (or absence) of power sharing shapes the willingness of lower-level governments to enter agreements that greatly constrain individual government autonomy. Power-concentrating governments, as opposed to power-sharing ones, tend to avoid such agreements. The type of power sharing affects the capacity to enter agreements that require legislative approval. Compulsory power-sharing governments, as opposed to voluntary power-sharing governments, should find it difficult to enter such agreements, since this type of power sharing invites inter-branch divides. To substantiate these arguments, we apply them to Canada, Switzerland, the United States, and the European Union.
Institutional democratization has made considerable progress in the history of the European Union (EU). Mainstream theories of democratization, however, fail to capture this process because they are wedded to the nation-state context. This paper therefore proposes a transformationalist theory of democratization beyond the state. EU democratization results from the conflict about the redistribution of political competences between institutional actors in a multilevel system, in which liberal democracy is the shared norm of legitimate authority. To the extent that institutional actors, who push for further integration in order to increase efficiency, undermine existing democratic institutions at the national level, their competitors can put into question the legitimacy of integration by invoking the shared liberal democratic community norms and shame them into making democratic concessions. The normative origins of democracy in the EU are illustrated in case studies on democratic membership conditionality, legislative rights of the European Parliament, and the institutionalization of human rights in the EU.
The field of judicial politics had long been neglected by political scientists outside the United States. But the past 20 years have witnessed considerable change. There is now a large body of scholarship on European courts and judges. In addition, judicial politics is on its way to become a sub-field of comparative politics in its own right. Examining the models used in the literature, this article suggests that this geographical convergence is also bringing about theoretical convergence. One manifestation of theoretical convergence is that models of judicial decision-making once deemed inapplicable in Europe are now used in studies of European courts too. But the convergence trend goes further. What we already know about judges and the contexts in which they operate suggests a way of reconciling the various attitudinal and institutionalist approaches used by scholars on both sides of the Atlantic within a general, unifying theory of judicial behaviour. The emerging theory provides a framework to assess the weight and interactions of a wide range of determinants of judicial decision-making across countries and legal systems.
The study of ethnic riots has a substantial pedigree in the social sciences, but so far there has been no systematic attempt to unify insights from scholars working on different areas of the world, nor has there been any extensive application of existing knowledge to the study of Western Europe. We address these two lacunae by drawing on contemporary scholarship to generate testable hypotheses about state responses to ethnic riots in liberal democracies, and by conducting a preliminary test of these hypotheses on four controlled comparison cases from Britain and France. Our cases reveal that states employ a relatively even balance of repression and accommodation in keeping with the social control perspective, but that the precise balance is affected by the electoral incentives of the party in power. This evidence suggests the external validity of findings by Fording (2001) – who emphasizes the significance of social control in the American context – and Wilkinson (2004) – who stresses the importance of electoral incentives in the Indian environment – but it implies that these separate insights may be more powerful in combination. Our study also demonstrates the limitations of perspectives that predict either simple repression or accommodation of rioters, and of those that emphasize distinctive national responses to riots.
One striking characteristic of the Lisbon Treaty is that it is deeply rooted in human rights, as was the case of the failed Constitutional Treaty. As mentioned by an American author, ‘much of the Constitution is given over to the issue of fundamental human rights. It might be said that human rights are the very heart and soul of the document.’
The Lisbon Treaty puts to the forefront the values on which the EU is based (see Box 15). It also takes the highly symbolic steps both of giving the Charter of Fundamental Rights the same legal value as the treaties (Article 6(1) TEU) and of providing for an obligation for the EU to accede to the European Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms (Article 6(2) TEU).
Box 15. THE UNION'S VALUES (ARTICLE 2 TEU)
The Union is founded on the values of respect for human dignity, freedom, democracy, equality, the rule of law and respect for human rights, including the rights of persons belonging to minorities. These values are common to the Member States in a society in which pluralism, non-discrimination, tolerance, justice, solidarity and equality between women and men prevail.
Article 2 TEU on the Union's values is not only a political and symbolic statement. It has concrete legal effects.
Among the most visible changes brought about by the Lisbon Treaty are the reforms of the institutions: these reforms concern the number of the institutions and their respective powers, composition and internal functioning. The institutions will now have to cope with the increased rights given to other political actors, such as the national parliaments, the Committee of the Regions and the citizens themselves.
The Lisbon Treaty increases the number of the EU institutions from five to seven, by giving the European Council and the European Central Bank the status of institution. The respective powers of the institutions are somewhat reshuffled, most notably through a widening of the scope of the codecision procedure, an increase in the number of cases where a (redefined) QMV in the Council will apply, a reform of the budget decision-making procedure, the creation of the new offices of a full-time European Council President, elected for up to five years, and of a Union High Representative for Foreign Affairs and Security Policy, appointed for five years, who is the president of the Foreign Affairs Council as well as one of the vice-presidents of the Commission, a reference to the Eurogroup which is chaired by a president elected by his/her peers and an extension of the jurisdiction of the Court of Justice.
May and June 2005: the peoples of two of the six founding members of the European Union, France and the Netherlands, consulted by referendum, refuse to ratify the Constitutional Treaty for Europe.
June 2008: the people of Ireland, one of the countries which has benefited most from the European Union, rejects the ratification of the Lisbon Treaty.
What is happening?
Does this mean that the dreams of a reconciled and more united Europe are dying? What exactly are those dreams? And, to begin with, which countries and peoples are concerned?
It is not easy to give a definition of Europe, whether geographically, historically or culturally.
Geographically, Europe is not a precise concept. It is not a continent, but rather a peninsula at the western edge of the Eurasian continent. Its eastern borders are far from being precise. It presents a vast variety of landscapes and climates, from the driest places of its Mediterranean coasts to the polar regions of Lapland.
It has always been populated by many diverse peoples, mainly but not only Christians, using dozens of languages and even different alphabets.
Historically, these peoples have organised themselves into national entities, according to their religions, languages or geographical situation. Over the centuries, Europeans have developed and strengthened the concept of the nation state. The European nation states have nurtured their differences, thus favouring nationalism, something which often led to wars with their neighbours. Nationalism explains why European nations have been fighting each other over the centuries.
Both in the 2002–3 Convention and in the 2003–4 IGC, the ambition was to take a major qualitative step forward in the field of external affairs. The aim was to make the Union more ‘present in the world’, as the European Council had requested in the 2001 Laeken Declaration. This was to be achieved by improving the functioning of the CFSP, as well as the consistency between the different areas of EU external policy: CFSP, trade, development, humanitarian aid and other sectoral external policies in environment, transport and so on, essentially through the establishment of new institutional tools.
External affairs before the Lisbon Treaty
The origins and scope of the external competence of the Community
In the 1957 Rome Treaty, the EC competence in external affairs was purely economic, and in particular linked to the fact that the EC was first created as a customs union, with a common customs tariff. As international trade developed, and the EC progressively liberalised its internal trade and made use of its internal competences to create its internal market, with free movement of goods, services, capital and persons and harmonised internal rules, the corresponding external competences also developed. This was necessary to avoid the possibility that, by concluding international agreements on matters covered by internal EC rules, Member States would affect these rules or impede their development.
The origins of the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights
The original EC Treaty did not make any reference to fundamental rights. It was the 1992 Maastricht Treaty which inserted Article 6(2) in the EU Treaty, providing that ‘the Union shall respect fundamental rights, as guaranteed by the European Convention for the Protection of Human Rights and Fundamental Freedoms … and as they result from the constitutional traditions common to the Member States, as general principles of Community law’. Before that, the EU Court of Justice had, as early as in 1969, stated that fundamental human rights are ‘enshrined in the general principles of Community law and protected by the Court’. Thereafter, the Court continued strengthening this protection so that ‘respect for human rights is … a condition of the lawfulness of Community acts’.
Such a guarantee was a prerequisite for the acceptance by Member States of the principle that EU law has primacy over national law, a principle which the Court of Justice had already enunciated in 1964. Without a guarantee that fundamental rights were properly protected at EU level, the conferral by Member States of competences on the EU might have entailed a lowering of the level of protection of human rights. This link with primacy was made very clearly by the German Constitutional Court in its case law which became known as Solange (meaning ‘as long as’ in German).
In its judgment of 26 November 2008 (71 pages, 218 paragraphs), the Czech Constitutional Court concluded that the Lisbon Treaty and the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights are not in conflict with the Czech constitutional order.
It stressed that the Court had concentrated its review only on those provisions of the Treaty whose consistency with the Czech Constitutional order were expressly contested. Therefore it remained legally possible that a group of deputies or senators might submit a new petition on the constitutionality of other provisions of the Lisbon Treaty.
The Court stressed that the transfer of powers from State organs of the Czech Republic to an international organisation cannot go as far as to violate the very essence of the Republic as a democratic State governed by the rule of law, founded on respect for the rights and freedoms of human beings and of citizens. A transfer to the EU of the competence to define its own competences (Kompetenz-Kompetenz) would also be inconsistent with the Czech Constitution. However, the Court noted that the Lisbon Treaty does not have such consequences and it concluded that the Lisbon Treaty, together with the EU Charter of Fundamental Rights, is consistent with the Czech constitutional order. The Court stressed that the transfer of certain competences of the State to the EU, which arises from the free will of the State and which will be exercised with its participation, is not a weakening of the sovereignty of the State.