We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Land reforms have been critical to the development of Chinese capitalism over the last several decades, yet land in China remains publicly owned. This book explores the political logic of reforms to land ownership and control, accounting for how land development and real estate have become synonymous with economic growth and prosperity in China. Drawing on extensive fieldwork and archival research, the book tracks land reforms and urban development at the national level and in three cities in a single Chinese region. The study reveals that the initial liberalization of land was reversed after China's first contemporary real estate bubble in the early 1990s and that property rights arrangements at the local level varied widely according to different local strategies for economic prosperity and political stability. In particular, the author links fiscal relations and economic bases to property rights regimes, finding that more 'open' cities are subject to greater state control over land.
From a regulatory perspective, philanthropy in China has been officially modernized. Since the government established a legal framework in 2004 based on models from overseas, the number of private foundations in China has grown more than six-fold. Drawing on a nationally representative survey of 214 private foundations conducted in 2012, we present a landscape view of these new philanthropic institutions, discussing both who begins foundations and how their monies are used. We find that despite the rise of new private wealth in China and the adoption of the private foundation form, government priorities are structuring the field of Chinese philanthropy in key and consequential ways. We conclude with some considerations of the implications of these findings for the development of broader civil society.
While most mainland Chinese today have extremely few direct contacts with either America or Americans, their indirect contacts with both, via globalized American popular culture, are increasing rapidly. Do daily parasocial contacts with American celebrities shape Chinese views of America? Based on two experimental studies, this paper argues that even indirect, subconscious exposure to American celebrities via popular magazine covers shapes Chinese views of America. However, the impact of that exposure depends upon both the specific nature of the bicultural exposure and the psychological predispositions of the Chinese involved. Not all Chinese are alike, and their personality differences shape whether they experience American popular culture as enriching or threatening, leading to integrative and exclusionary reactions, respectively.
Since the mid-2000s, the Chinese government has promoted village modernization under the banner of “building a new socialist countryside.” To explain the origins and outcomes of this policy, this article examines the case of Ganzhou city in Jiangxi province. Ganzhou became a national model for rural development known for involving organizations called peasant councils in policy implementation. The study found that despite an initial emphasis on rural participation and moderate change, the new socialist countryside evolved into a top-down campaign to demolish and reconstruct villages. Three factors shaped this process: the strength of bureaucratic mobilization, the weakness of rural organizations, and shifting national policy priorities. After obtaining model status, Ganzhou's rural policy became more ambitious and politicized, leaving little space for participation. This insight suggests there are both benefits and costs to China's policy process. Despite the advantages of policy innovation, scaling up local experiments may actually undermine their success.
Drawing from ethnographic data from 48 households in four villages in rural Anhui, this study explores how two practices known for upholding son preference are affected by rural–urban out-migration, with a particular focus on the division of labour in agricultural work and patrilocality. The study deploys the concepts of an intergenerational contract and the “unsubstitutability” of sons and finds that a weakening of the intergenerational contract can take place without substantially challenging the unsubstitutability of sons. The study concludes that although male out-migration undermines the argument that sons are needed to secure male manual labour in family farming, the vital role of male labour as a rural livelihood strategy largely persists. Moreover, although the study identifies migration-induced exceptions, patrilocality remains the main organizing principle for social and economic life for both male and female migrants. Hence, the study finds little support for the prospect that migration is attenuating son preference in rural China.
Recent studies on internet politics in China have gone beyond the once dominant control–liberalization perspective and directed intellectual attention to the varieties of online activism. Based on extensive in-depth online ethnographic work, this project explores the pluralization of online expression in Chinese cyberspace. Following a constituency of internet users who identify themselves as the “voluntary fifty-cent army,” the paper explores how these users acquire and consolidate their identity and combat criticism that targets the authoritarian regime. Analysis of the confrontational exchanges between the “voluntary fifty-cent army” and their opponents suggests that a perspective that goes beyond state censorship and regime-challenging activism is required in order to gain a better understanding of online expression in China. Close examination of why and how internet users may voluntarily defend the authoritarian regime also reveals how the dynamics in online discourse competition may work to the authoritarian regime's advantage.
Dalian, a city of a little more than six million people on the tip of the Liaodong peninsula in Liaoning province, is most frequently mentioned outside China for one of two reasons. First, as the host of the “Summer Davos,” Dalian has a reputation as one of China's cleanest and most beautiful cities. Dalian is also noted for its connection to one of China's most recognizable and notorious contemporary politicians: Bo Xilai. Before Bo attracted global attention for “smashing” corruption and singing Red songs as part of his populist reform campaign in Chongqing, and notoriety for the murder scandal that felled him in 2012, he served in the city of Dalian from 1984 through 2000 in various positions, and ultimately as mayor. However, Bo's populist turn in Chongqing was not at all predictable in terms of his tenure in Dalian, during which he presided over the city's opening to foreign direct investment (FDI) and its transformation from a socialist industrial base to an area for global corporate outsourcing.
Dalian's two reputations are, to be sure, deeply intertwined. Under Bo's leadership, the city initiated a massive transformation of the urban built environment and undertook a substantial public relations campaign to highlight its success in urban planning and economic reforms. Dalian's rise, both economically and publicly, coincided with Bo's political rise such that we cannot disentangle the effect of one from the other. The same is true of the mutual dependence of the city's economic trajectory and its pursuit of land and real estate development. As Dalian grew out of the rust belt into a global capital hub, the local government monopolized property rights and deployed land development as a tool for government financing, a model that almost all Chinese cities would replicate in the 2000s. This chapter narrates Dalian's economic growth and physical transformation, illustrating how its statist property-rights regime emerged as a result of the sequencing of global opening and economic reforms.
The Argument in Brief
The integral relationship between economic strategies and property-rights practices experienced throughout China is on particular display in Dalian. Dalian's reform era economic performance was made possible by a dramatic reorganization of its political economy from a state socialist heavy industry base to a global capital hub. This reorganization, itself possible because of Dalian's preferential status and therefore early access to global capital, generated a shift in local political alliances.
If “all politics is local,” then most of Chinese politics is about land. By the mid-2000s, as a result of the dual dependence on land revenue as a key source of finance and on the real estate sector for economic growth, the pursuit of land control and development became the primary activity undertaken by local (city and county) governments in China. The ratio of land leasing and property – or land-related taxes to local government budgetary revenues – grew from 25 percent in 2000 to more than 90 percent in 2010. Real estate investment – funds invested in the development of land and property – grew from 2 percent of GDP in 1992 to 13 percent in 2011.
The extent of China's political and economic dependence on land and real estate was likely surprising even to the land-reform architects who made them possible. Zhao Ziyang, premier from 1980 to 1987 and general secretary of the Chinese Communist Party (CCP) from 1987 until his purge during the Tiananmen protests in 1989, writes in his memoir: “It was perhaps 1985 or 1986 when I talked to Huo Yingdong [a Hong Kong tycoon, better known as Henry Fok] and mentioned that we didn't have funds for urban development. He asked me, ‘If you have land, how can you not have money?' I thought this was a strange comment. Having land was one issue; a lack of funds was another. What did the two have to do with one another?” Zhao goes on to describe how, presumably after he made the connection between landownership and capital accumulation, he presided over the initial experiments to separate ownership and use rights of land, and leasing the latter in return for capita – essentially, commodifying urban land.
This discovery of the “exchange value” of land – its ability to serve as a means of capital accumulation independent of its productive or use value – has resulted in a dramatic reorganization of intergovernmental and political economic relations in China during the last three decades. This chapter narrates the CCP's relationship to land, tracing how land evolved from a national resource to be distributed in the service of socialist production and consumption to a form of capital to an instrument of fiscal and financial policy.
Some have suggested that the entire process of economic reform in China can be viewed as a reassignment of property rights. Property rights – over firms, firm assets, land, and so forth – have changed hands between central and local levels of the state, among different intrastate agencies, and between the state and various elements of the private sector. The speed and direction of this process have been dynamic, tortuous, and politically contingent rather than proceeding steadily from plan to market or toward private-property rights. Decisions about who controls land and property have been at the center of political contests for power and for recognition, in which a variety of players both inside and outside the Chinese state have staked claims. The chapters in this book have examined this “reassignment of property rights” at the national and subnational levels. Doing so has revealed a process of political bargaining over land control that contains theoretical lessons about the nature of property-rights change and empirical lessons about the role of land and property in Chinese capitalism. In this concluding chapter, I review the theoretical and empirical findings of the book, explore the argument about property rights as political bargains in comparative perspective, and finally turn to the present and future of land and capitalism in China.
The Politics of Property Rights
In the first chapter of this book, I outlined a theoretical approach that positions political choice and bargaining at the center of property-rights changes. Such changes, during the modern era, are rarely imposed on societies or economies by some exogenous forces; rather they emerge through political processes in which actors consciously seek to implement changes to property-rights arrangements. Whereas classical approaches envisage that changes in value – of land, labor, goods, and so forth – stimulate changes in the arrangements of control over property, this political approach sees value as endogenous to the political process. Property assumes greater or lesser value as the result of political decisions that assign value.
Political decisions that assign or change value and property rights are the products of political bargaining and moral argument, both of which occur under conditions of uncertainty. Social and economic actors bargain over property rights as they do over the distribution of any other power resource. However, actors do not adopt positions on property rights with exclusive attention to the expected distributional gains.