Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T23:01:43.093Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Legal Boundaries, Organizational Fields, and Trade Union Politics: The Development of Railway Unions in the US and the UK

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  12 September 2024

Maya Adereth*
Affiliation:
Department of Sociology, The London School of Economics and Political Science, London, UK
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

Throughout the nineteenth century, powerful railway unions in the USA and the UK cultivated an expansive system of voluntary sickness, death, unemployment, and superannuation benefits. By the early twentieth century, the movements had diverged: while the British Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants relinquished its commitment to voluntarism in favor of state healthcare and pensions, the American Railway Brotherhoods persisted along voluntarist lines, resisting social insurance in favor of exclusive schemes for their white male membership. What accounts for these diverging orientations? I highlight the importance of organizational forms as a lens for understanding comparative trade union strategy, emphasizing the role of law in designating legitimate forms of working-class association. I demonstrate that governing elites in both countries promoted voluntarism as a benign form of working-class organization throughout much of the nineteenth century. Consequently, I argue, early American and British trade unions adopted benefits in part because they enabled them to mimic the far more respected and legitimate friendly and fraternal mutual benefit societies. Toward the end of the century, the context had changed: while alternative organizational avenues were opened for trade unions in the UK, benefits presented an ongoing organizational lifeline for American unions. In defining and redefining the boundaries of legitimate forms of workers’ associations, legal decisions in both countries shaped not only trade union organizing strategies in the short run but also their positioning in broader social struggles.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of Social Science History Association

Introduction

In a 1916 article, American Federation of Labor (AFL) President Samuel Gompers declared: “The workers of America adhere to voluntary institutions in preference to compulsory systems which are held to be not only impractical but a menace to their rights, welfare and their liberty” (Gompers Reference Gompers1916: 270). By contrast, in a speech to members of the 1899 British Trades Union Congress (TUC), President W. J. Vernon pronounced, “The majority of workers who are identified with trade unions and friendly societies…have done all that was possible for them to do…therefore, in my opinion, a pension should be the right of every worker when incapacitated from further labour” (Trades Union Congress 1899: 48). The leaders’ differing views on universal state benefits were not to be taken for granted: as two of the most closely affiliated labor federations in the Western world, the British TUC and American AFL had regularly looked to each other for guidance on organizing strategies and political orientations. In the previous century, they had differed from their European counterparts in the promotion of craft unionism and focus on “bread and butter” issues affecting a layer of “respectable” white male workers.

Essential to this craft model was an expansive system of mutual benefits – well-paid craftsmen were willing and able to contribute a small portion of their weekly earnings toward sickness, death, funeral, unemployment, and pension fund for themselves and their dependents. Toward the end of the century, these craft unions also faced similar threats from mechanization and industrialization. And ultimately, both labor movements reconciled with the need for political action through the state, setting up Labour Representation Committees (1900 in England and 1906 in the USA) and mobilizing members in favor of legislative reforms (Dubofsky and Dulles Reference Dubofsky and Dulles2010; Greene Reference Greene2006; Kirk Reference Kirk1994; Pelling Reference Pelling1992).

The two movements diverged, however, on the form that this political participation took. Whereas the British TUC came to embrace a solidaristic politics and advocate for universal public benefits, the AFL preserved its exclusivist line, strengthening its system of union benefits and resisting proposals for social insurance. This difference was historically meaningful: while British workers gained a skeletal welfare state with the Old Age Pensions Act of 1908 and National Insurance Act of 1911, Americans missed the opportunity to lay down a welfare infrastructure upon which subsequent expansions could take place.

This article aims to understand the diverging trajectory of the two labor movements on the spectrum of solidarity. It does so by analyzing developments in their most powerful respective railway unions – the Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants (ASRS) in the UK and the Railway Brotherhoods (primarily the Brotherhood of Locomotive Firemen or BLF) in the USA. Emerging in the mid-1860s, the Brotherhoods would come to constitute the most powerful and longstanding organizations of US railway workers until a century after their founding. Occupying a separate but commanding space from the AFL, they exhibited a persistently exclusive form of “labor fraternalism” (Weir Reference Weir1952: 62) in which insurance benefits played a central role. Beginning with the period examined in this paper, they positioned themselves as key negotiators within the arbitration infrastructure culminating in the 1926 Railway Labor Act (McCartin Reference McCartin2023). As one of the key agents behind the formation of the Labour Representation Committee and, later, the Labour Party, the ASRS similarly embodied a transformational era in British Trade Unionism. The first sustained organization of railway workers in the country, it initially embraced the form and politics of the earlier craft unions. By the end of the century, however, it had turned sharply in defense of industrial organization, political engagement, and mass mobilization, electing its general secretary Richard Bell as one of the first Labour representatives in Parliament in 1900 (Crompton Reference Crompton and Worley2009).

The cases are treated as influential – in both countries, the railway industry was a pillar of economic development that actively shaped the structure of industries and labor markets (Dobbin Reference Dobbin, Scott and Moller Christensen1995; Jenks Reference Jenks1944; Mitchell Reference Mitchell1964). Railways were also important sites of class contestation – the sharp contrast between their highly exploited labor force and vastly wealthy corporate owners, as well as their position as the arteries of industrial development, made them fruitful grounds for labor organizing and a mobilizing symbol for broader political struggles. Indeed, many of the most dramatic strikes in US and UK labor history – including the Great Railway Strike of 1877 and the Pullman Strike of 1894 in the USA, as well as the Taff Vale Strike of 1900 in the UK – were led by railway unions. As a result, railways were also the arena out of which important industrial relations regimes emerged: notably with the system of arbitration emerging out of the 1898 Erdman Act in the USA and the 1906 Trades Disputes Bill in the UK. Unlike most industries that were regulated at the state level, then, American railway unions offer a lens onto national legal and normative debate surrounding organizational forms.

Though trade union strategy is often depicted as an expression of broadly held class sentiments or the result of industrial circumstances, I demonstrate that organizational logics played a decisive role in promoting the persistence of voluntarism within the US labor movement. By the late nineteenth century, formidable challenges to craft unionism emerged in both countries: in the UK, low-wage dock and factory workers prompted a wave of radical unions known as the New Union movement. In the USA, alternatives to craft unionism emerged with the progressive Knights of Labor and American Railway Union (ARU), as well as AFL affiliates like the International Ladies Garment Workers Union who promoted universal state benefits through political mobilization. The relative success of these challenges would be mediated by their respective institutional environment and specifically by legal developments in the definition and standing of voluntary associations.

In what follows, I demonstrate that trade unions in both countries turned toward benefit provision in hostile legal environments – contrary to dangerous forms of combination like strikes and boycotts, “benevolent” insurance was a widely respected and morally revered form of working-class association (Cordery Reference Cordery1995: 42). Until their legitimation with the Trade Union Acts of 1871 and 1875, trade unions in the UK commonly registered as mutual benefit societies. Their emphasis on voluntary benefits would make a brief comeback during the repressive period of Taff Vale, after which they could safely turn toward support for state insurance and wider politicization. Similarly emerging in the USA, voluntary benefits would continue to constitute an essential organizational tool as ongoing injunctions under the Sherman Anti-trust Act and the system of arbitration initiated with the Erdman Act of 1898 would condemn strikes and boycotts while validating voluntary benefits. Crucially, I do not argue that the legal environment created voluntarism as an organizational form, but rather that it acted as a filter that strengthened and elevated specific modes of autonomous working-class organizations over others.

While the role of law in shaping the American labor movement has been richly exposed, the existing literature overwhelmingly emphasizes legal constraints to working-class organization in the form of persisting master–servant and conspiracy laws (Ernst Reference Ernst1995; Forbath Reference Forbath1991; Hattam Reference Hattam1993; Orren Reference Orren1991; Tomlins Reference Tomlins1985). Paying attention to benefit provision, by contrast, shifts the focus toward organizational doors opened. In emphasizing what trade unions could do, I explain the strategies they did adopt; not just those that they did not. In other words, I suggest that the form taken by the American labor movement in the early twentieth century depends not only on the roadblocks to an inclusive political orientation, but on the continuing appeal of exclusive insurance provision. I demonstrate how UK policymakers narrowed the scope for voluntary benefit provision at the same time as they expanded the scope for strike mobilization. On the other hand, I show that American policymakers obstructed strikes and boycotts while protecting voluntary methods. Drawing on organizational sociology, the paper thus demonstrates how legal categories can influence the form that working-class politics takes – including the character of labor movements and the direction of welfare state development.

Labor in the making of the welfare state

Welfare states, by most accounts, depend on labor movements, but labor movements do not always support welfare states (Boxall Reference Boxall, Blyton, Heery, Bacon and Fiorito2008; Hyman Reference Hyman2001; Marks Reference Marks2014). The exclusive orientation of the early-twentieth-century American labor movement is particularly stark when compared to its anti-socialist, “bread and butter” counterpart in the UK. The movement’s unique commitment to business unionism has been explained in various ways. Among these is the timing of democratization – whereas most British white male workers were granted the right to vote by the mid-1880s, many American property-less white males had received voting rights as early as the late 1820s. The result was a shared white male political identity that cut across class lines; deviating from the class-based struggles for political representation, which characterized late-nineteenth-century Europe (Dawley Reference Dawley2000). The ethnic and racialized nature of American labor markets has equally been held to have divided the labor movement along lines of ethnicity, race, and grade level. While ongoing influxes of immigration created segregated linguistic, cultural, and occupational communities, the exclusion of newly freed Black workers from the crafts perpetuated exploitation and discrimination by both employers and labor associations (Bridges Reference Bridges, Katznelson and Zolberg1986; Davis Reference Davis1980; Du Bois Reference Du Bois2022 [1906]; Roediger Reference Roediger1999). These dynamics were compounded by patterns of urbanization and the resulting division between work and community (Katznelson and Zolberg Reference Katznelson and Zolberg1986). Additionally, the proliferation of scientific management practices in the USA is thought to have divided workers’ interests and prevented all-grades organization. And finally, the federal structure of the US government, and the realities of sectional politics, made it difficult for workers to form a single national interest group advancing a labor cause (Archer Reference Archer2008; Friedman Reference Friedman1988; Hacker Reference Hacker1998; Haydu Reference Haydu1991; Kirk Reference Kirk1994; Shefter Reference Shefter1994; Skocpol and Amenta Reference Skocpol and Amenta1986; Skowronek Reference Skowronek1982).

While these are certainly powerful factors in explaining the emergence and persistence of a conservative tradition within the American labor movement (Taft Reference Taft1963), they do not necessarily explain why this wing came to define the strategy of the movement as a whole. Toward the end of the nineteenth century, a parallel wing led by immigrant, precarious, and women workers emerged and gained momentum (Montgomery Reference Montgomery and Morris2014). The railway industry is especially demonstrative of this tendency: during the 1870s, immigrant workers were recruited en masse to feed the industry’s insatiable demand for labor. In subsequent decades, these workers organized into radical trade unions and delivered groundbreaking strikes – but ultimately, their organizational model would not prevail.

Why, then, did the exclusive orientation of the AFL and the Railway Brotherhoods come to predominate over the more progressive vision of the Knights of Labor and the ARU? Kim Voss (Reference Voss1993) convincingly points to the violent mobilization of American employers in crushing this alternative model. The power of US employers was sanctioned and strengthened by the military and economic weight of the American government. Far from a state of “courts and parties” (Skowronek Reference Skowronek1982: 24), the US government actively shaped the resolution of labor disputes (Forbath Reference Forbath1991). I argue that its interventions were not only decisive in determining the outcome of monumental national strikes; they also served to delimit the boundaries of legitimate organization and diffuse particular organizational forms.

This claim is drawn from substantial work in the field of organizational sociology, which pays special attention to the rules of political behavior – expressed through the routines, procedures, conventions, and codes through which political participation takes place. Rather than rational or utilitarian calculation, organizational sociologists have argued that organizations navigate these existing repertoires and adapt their operations in line with “logics of appropriateness” mirroring their environment (March and Olsen Reference March and Olsen1989: 22). In the words of John Meyer and Brian Rowan, “Institutional rules function as myths which organizations incorporate, gaining legitimacy, resources, stability, and enhanced survival prospects” (Meyer and Rowan Reference Meyer and Rowan1977: 340). The state has a special role in legitimating or delegitimating various organizing models (DiMaggio and Powell Reference DiMaggio and Powell1983; Meyer and Rowan Reference Meyer and Rowan1977; Stryker Reference Stryker and Lounsbury2000). Organizational change, then, is likely to take place: “when the transformation of environmental conditions renders previous organizational strategies and orientations obsolete, such that an organizational form…is faced with extinction” (Haveman Reference Haveman1992: 49).

Law has an especially important role in the proliferation of organizational identities and practices. In relation to the US labor movement, the persistence of the master–servant laws, power of judicial interpretation, emphasis on procedural rights, ongoing use of the conspiracy doctrines, and injunctions under the Sherman Anti-trust laws have all been linked with the evolution of “business unionism” (Hattam Reference Hattam1993: 18; Ernst Reference Ernst1995; Forbath Reference Forbath1991; O’Brien Reference O’Brien1998; Orren Reference Orren1991; Tomlins Reference Tomlins1985). While the expansive body of literature on law and the American labor movement demonstrates the barriers to industrial unionism, it does less to demonstrate why key trade unions did maintain and expand their own insurance benefit schemes. The following sections build on existing accounts, highlighting the importance of benefit provision in offering a legal cover for trade unions operating in hostile judicial settings. In doing so, they illustrate how nineteenth-century liberal elites made use of organizational laws to circumscribe the activities of a growing industrial working class. They also demonstrate how the organizational environment in which trade unions operate affects their political orientations.

The legal context for the emergence of voluntarism

The emergence of voluntary benefits among trade unions is widely attributed to the practicalities of sectoral development, management practices, and opportunities for gradual reform (Haydu Reference Haydu1991; Joseph Reference Joseph2000; Kirk Reference Kirk1994; Marks Reference Marks2014). In the following section, I argue that, in addition to these concrete variables, cultural and institutional norms played a significant role in encouraging trade union provision of voluntary benefits. In particular, I look at how the legal regulation of associational life defined legitimate and illegitimate combinations of workers and what role benefits played in this process of legitimation.

At first glance, the trajectory of legislation on workers’ associations in the USA and the UK might seem dramatically different – in the former, trade unions received legal recognition as early as 1842 with the Commonwealth v. Hunts case. By contrast, the latter left trade union activity outside the law until the Trades union Act of 1871. The differences were far less meaningful in practice: in both countries, trade unions were able to obtain legal recognition so long as they were organized toward admissible ends.

The provision of voluntary insurance benefits was high on the list of such respectable aims. This is quite apparent in the UK, where legal recognition for trade unions depended entirely on their registration as friendly benefit societies. First emerging among craftsmen in the 1760s, by 1794 friendly societies were to be found across England (Eden Reference Eden2011 [1797]). Originally characterized as “mischievous” and “dangerous” combinations (Gosden Reference Gosden1961: 156–57),Footnote 1 friendly societies were soon embraced as vehicles for the promotion of voluntarist Victorian values like hard work, self-help, and thrift. Much like the invisible hand, the ideology of voluntarism linked individual rights and responsibilities with collective enrichment (Smiles Reference Smiles1862).

The first law regulating friendly societies was Rose’s Act of 1793. The Act offered legal protection to societies “of good fellowship” organized “for the purpose of raising from time to time…by voluntary contributions…a fund for the mutual relief and maintenance of all and ever the members thereof in old age, sickness, and infirmity” (House of Commons 1793: 125). To be exempt from the prevailing combination laws, societies had to submit their rules and accounting books for approval by a government body known as the Registrar of Friendly Societies. In 1828, the societies were permitted to appoint trustees, “of whom the majority shall be substantial householders” to manage property and represent them in court (UK Parliament 1828: 3). As their membership surged, the societies engaged in cautious tit for tat negotiations, whereby they progressively surrendered to greater government oversight in exchange for legalization and protection.

The Act of 1834 extended the purposes for which societies could be formed – to include provision for widows and orphans, as well as insurance for sickness and advanced age. In exchange for this recognition, the societies “discountenance[ed] trade unions, and [did] not allow assistance to be given to those who leave employment in strikes or turnouts,” thus “promoting good will to all men” (Spry Reference Spry1867: 39). In one of many letters sent to the Queen, Oddfellows officials write:

We assure your Majesty that the Society we represent is of a philanthropic and charitable description, formed for the relief of its members in sickness and distress…that the sole qualification for admission is the possession of a good moral character—no reference whatever being had to the religious or political feelings of the person, so that he be well attached to this Government under which we live. (cited in Spry Reference Spry1867: 44)

After offering full legal protection to the Oddfellows and the Foresters in 1848, the Acts of 1849, 1850, 1855, and 1858 protected the funds of registered societies at the same time as they increased regulation of insurance rates and promoted greater society solvency (Cordery Reference Cordery1995). Progressively, the societies were granted the legal protection offered corporations under the guise of voluntary association (Davis Reference Davis1876).

Despite the claims of the Oddfellows officials, British trade unions commonly registered as friendly societies throughout the nineteenth century. In the first report from the Select Committee on Artizans and Machinery, trade union representatives questioned repeatedly stress the benefit features of their associations. Nevertheless, the report concluded that:

Societies, legally enrolled as benefit societies, have been frequently made the cloak under which funds have been raised for the support of combinations and strikes attended with acts of violence and intimidation…it is absolutely necessary when repealing the combination laws to enact such a law as may efficiently and by summary process punish either workmen or masters who by threats, intimidation, or acts of violence should interfere with that perfect freedom which ought to be allowed to each party of employing his labor or capital in the manner he may deem most advantageous. (House of Commons 1824: 590)

It is no surprise, then, that the national amalgamated unions of the mid-nineteenth century cultivated an extensive system of craft benefits; this benefit system is precisely what enabled them to claim that they were organized for “benevolent, rather than fighting purposes” (Amalgamated Society of Engineers July 1851: 137). Over the course of decades, leaders of these craft unions managed to avoid elite hostility by maintaining that the organizations were mere occupationally friendly societies. Like friendly societies, craft unions argued that their benefit system enabled workers to morally uplift themselves and their communities by enhancing their independence and promoting thrift. In August of 1851, the General Secretary of the Amalgamated Society of Engineers (ASE) pronounced, “Instead of accumulating power to do battle with other interests, [trade unions] must husband resources to forward that peaceable, intelligent, industrial process which shall lift the operative into a higher condition” (ASE October 1851: 137). Far more than a practical necessity, benefits thus served as a symbol of cultural alignment and respectable values that enabled early British trade unions to survive amid ruling class hostility.

By most accounts, the voluntary ideal originating in the UK reached unrivaled proportions in the USA. Across the early states, voluntary association was encouraged and promoted – in the words of William Novak (Reference Novak2001: 172), “Nineteenth century legislators, judges, and commentators defended associations not as alternatives to a legal-constitutional state, but as constitutive components of it.” With the proliferation of associational bodies, the nascent American government delegated authority while exercising public power. Jurist Francis Leiber argued that self-ruling associations constituted “a vast system of institutions whose number supports the whole as many pillars support the rotunda of our capital” (Novak Reference Novak2001: 174; see also Clemens Reference Clemens2020).

Voluntary associations were also viewed as an alternative to wasteful working-class leisure activities. Benefit societies held a special place in this framework – providing material assistance in times of hardship and thus reducing support for political radicalism (Witt Reference Witt2009). The principle of voluntarism reinforced the contract as the foundation for social arrangements, harnessing the advantages of collective association without the threat of conspiracy. Unlike British-friendly societies, American fraternals were organized on a cross-class basis, and benefits were distributed exclusively to “deserving” members (Beito Reference Beito1997, Reference Beito2000).

Similar to the British-friendly societies, then, American fraternals for the most part advanced a politics of respectability, contending that “labor, to be respected, must respect itself among mankind as well as at home. It must command the respect of the rich, and thus influence and induce a willingness to divide the accumulations of wealth” (Upchurch Reference Upchurch1887: 140). In Mary Ann Clawson’s words, the organizations represented “a cultural institution which not only maintained but idealized solidarity among white men…offer[ing] gender and race as appropriate categories for the organization of collective identity” (Clawson Reference Clawson1985: 694). In the words of Brian Greenberg, they were “bulwarks of the status quo, conservers of traditional morality, transmitters of existing social values” (Greenberg Reference Greenberg1985: 97).

Just as in the UK, US trade unions adopted the character of mutual benefit societies in their early form. Trade union names like the Knights of St. Crispin, Patrons of Husbandry, and the Knights of Labor make explicit reference to the imagery and ritual practices of fraternal organizations, testifying to the societies’ overlapping membership and the importance of the fraternal mode in early trade union organization. The arrangement of these unions according to local, grand, and supreme lodges and frequent reference to fraternal ties further indicates the importance of the fraternal form for the early US labor movement.

This organic embrace of fraternal benefits by trade unions was fortified by legal means. Early fraternal benefit societies in the USA gained easy recognition through statutes of incorporation. Mutual aid societies and fraternal orders were granted special charters that facilitated this status. In 1848, New York allowed for the incorporation of “benevolent, charitable, scientific, and missionary societies” (Bloch and Lamoreaux Reference Bloch and Lamoreaux2015: 3). In the following two decades, California, Ohio, Maryland, North Carolina, New Jersey, Kentucky, Massachusetts, Kansas, Iowa Illinois, and Wisconsin passed similar regulations (ibid.). Such rights were expressly denied to labor unions, radical reform associations, anti-slavery groups, and immigrant organizations. In this way, early laws of association explicitly elevated mutual benefit organizations over other organized groups. In both the USA and the UK, association for the purpose of benefit provision was recognized, while other trade union functions were not.

The legitimating function of benefits is visible across records from early labor disputes. In the first reported legal case arising from a strike in US history, the Cordwainers trial of 1806, the Federal Society of Journeymen Cordwainers were accused of being neither “an incorporated society…[nor] a society instituted for benevolent purposes…but merely a society for compelling by the most arbitrary and malignant means the whole body of journeymen to submit to their rules and regulations” (Lloyd Reference Lloyd1806: 8).

To gauge the accuracy of such accusations, the jury enquired “whether there was any provision made for married or other distressed members,” to which the witness responded, “No; the sole object was to raise and support their wages.” In defense of the union, it was held that “the objects of their thus uniting, and meeting together, were the advancement of their mutual interests; the relief of the distressed and indigent members; and, generally, to promote the happiness of the individuals of which their society was composed” (ibid.: 44). Across early labor disputes, trade unions like the Cordwainers, Journeymen Tailors, Shoemakers, and Typographical associations similarly resisted accusations of malicious combination with reference to their beneficial features (Commons and Sumner Reference Commons and Sumner1910).Footnote 2

In 1842, the Massachusetts Supreme Court was the first to legalize labor combinations with the Commonwealth v. Hunts decision. A close reading of the decision, however, reveals that this legality depended almost entirely on the legitimacy of their stated objects. In his decision, Chief Justice Lemuel Shaw reasoned that legalizing combinations

would give [trade unions] a power which might be exerted for useful and honorable purposes, or for dangerous and pernicious ones…such an association might be used to afford each other assistance in times of poverty, sickness, and distress; or to raise their intellectual, moral, and social condition. (Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court 1866: 129)

He maintains, however, that “if, under cover of meritorious and avowed objects, people associate for secret purposes injurious to the piece of society or the rights of its members, it is undoubtedly a criminal conspiracy” (ibid.: 129). In the following decades, the legality of any working-class association would depend on an assessment of its objects. In Pennsylvania, an 1869 law reiterated that trade unions would be legal if formed for “mutual aid, benefit, and protection” (Pennsylvania General Assembly 1869). Even as conspiracy laws were repealed, the objects of trade unions remained under scrutiny. In both the USA and the UK, then, the benefit features of trade unions emerged not only as a protection against the vicissitudes of industrial development but as an organizational lifeline in a legal environment that primarily legitimated them as benefit societies.

The emergence of a voluntarist railway movement

The importance of benefits as a vehicle for legitimation is evident in the development of railway unions in both contexts – while their overall strategy differed, with the British Railway Servants organized along industrial lines and the American Brotherhoods along a craft basis, both developed an expansive benefit infrastructure that explicitly mimicked that of friendly and fraternal societies.

Following decades of unsuccessful organization among railway workers and a 170% increase in the railway labor force, the ASRS was founded in 1871 by George Chapman and Baxter Langley. The former was a mechanic who had participated in efforts to organize the signalmen of the South London Railways throughout the strike wave of 1866; the latter was a radical journalist and reformer (Gupta Reference Gupta1960). The union was able to consolidate and grow thanks to backing and support from Liberal Member of Parliament Michael Thomas Bass. The head of a large brewing company, Bass represented a “direct link between the early factory paternalism…the philanthropy of mid-Victorian stability and the beginnings of nationally based union organization” (Revill Reference Revill1999: 203). As the parliamentary representative for Derby, he appealed directly to railwaymen as an electoral base at the same time as he became a major shareholder of the Midland Railway Company. His was a vision of working-class representation rooted in respectful collaboration and philanthropic efforts by employers (ibid.).

Friendly society benefits were a cornerstone of this vision. The first delegate meeting of the society emphasized the respect and support of middle-class patrons through “promoting good relations between employers and employed, preventing strikes, and advocating arbitration for the settlement of disputes” (Gupta Reference Gupta1960: 18).

In the society’s 1875 report, its executive committee acknowledges that “influential friends of the society often give considerable donations as tokens of their support of the society. Hitherto these have been devoted entirely to the local benevolent funds” (ASRS 1875: 3). Through the expansion of its benefit features, the organization demonstrated its benevolence, drawing both financial support and elite recognition. The committee continues,

No trade union has ever effected its purposes in a more legitimate manner or by less objectionable means. That it wins and retains public friends, who are influential and just, is an indication that our path is a right one, and gives us encouragement to still push forward. Self-reliance is the lesson our society teaches to all railway servants. To them as to others the application of this lesson will be their greatest assistance. (ibid.: 6)

The adoption of voluntary benefit features was stimulated by cultural elements that far surpassed considerations of industrial development. Instead, the society’s friendly features demonstrated an organizational logic that symbolized complacency, cooperation, and collective self-help, in line with the preferences of governing elites.

In the USA, the first railroad union to successfully emerge was the Brotherhood of the Footboard, which formed in Michigan in 1863 in response to a railroad merger. Adopting the name Brotherhood of Locomotive Engineers (BLE) the following year, the combination identified its purpose with “win[ning] the good graces of the employers through elevating the character of its members and thus raising their efficiency as workmen” (Hostler Reference Hostler1955: 4). Disavowing the use of strikes, the BLE’s strategy anticipated that “the employer would be so well pleased with their work that he would of his own free will provide better recognition of labor and higher pay” (Hostler Reference Hostler1955: 4).

Indeed, the railroad Brotherhoods were exemplary of “labor fraternalism” (Weir Reference Weir1952: 62), a tradition of labor organizing that grew out of the work of fraternal societies. The society’s founders were active participants in the Freemasons, and the organization mimicked the societies’ hierarchy of subordinate, grand, and supreme lodges. Many of its early members were already paying into fraternals, as evidenced by funeral processions that often included representatives of both the Brotherhoods and fraternal associations (Stevens Reference Stevens1907; Taillon Reference Taillon1997).

Leaders of the BLE were similarly referred to in the fraternal language of grand masters, and they presided over a series of secret ritual practices. Alongside these practices, the Brotherhoods adopted the fraternal system of benefit provision. In 1866, the union initiated a widows, orphans, and disabled members fund, and this was to be followed by a mutual insurance fund in 1867.

The BLE would come to inspire a number of organizations known as the Railway Brotherhoods. Among these was the Brotherhood of Locomotive Firemen and Enginemen (BLF), which was initiated by lower-grade workers in Port Jervis, New York, in 1873. Like the BLE and the ASRS, Firemen records attest to the importance of benefits in legitimizing its operations. In the convention of 1876, Grand Master J. A. Leach holds that the association’s primary purpose is “to protect worthy brothers, and aid in the noble work of relieving suffering humanity” (BLF Proceedings 1876: 6). The formulation draws on benefits to emphasize the worthiness of membership and benign aims. The trade union’s motto, “benevolence, sobriety, and industry” similarly conjures the language of respectable voluntarism (BLF Proceedings 1874: 8).

Like the Railway Servants, the Firemen were in the habit of inviting respectable speakers to their public meetings. Their 1874 convention was graced with the presence of Joseph Brown, president of the Missouri Pacific Railroad and War Democratic Mayor of St. Louis. In his speech to the convention, Brown observes, “I notice by your constitution and bylaws that your organization…is not only charitable but moral in its tendencies.” To which the society’s Grand Master responds, “I also hope… that we have improved our condition as regards our respectability and standing before the public” (BLF Proceedings 1874: 46). In the following speech, Mayor of Buffalo Lewis P. Dayton, also a Democrat, states, “Yours is an institution formed for the mutual protection and assistance of its members, and as such is worthy to be classed among the many charitable institutions of the day… yours is an honorable calling” (ibid.: 112). And, in its 1875 convention, the organization declared that:

It is not a society for evil purposes…we are beneficial not only to our members, but to railroad companies, the public, and our families. Benevolence is the key which opens to the sick a fountain of comfort and care, but when a member’s trials are over on this earth we consign him to his last resting place. If he leaves behind him a widow or children, we look to their wants, and you do not witness a poor fireman as heretofor [sic] known, being conveyed to a paupers [sic] grave, nor his family begging from door to door. (BLF Proceedings 1875: 450)

In both trade unions, the provision of benefits thus performed a vital cultural function – by mimicking friendly and fraternal societies, early railway unions signaled their compliance with elite preferences for a voluntarist ethic and vied for legitimacy and respectability in a legal environment that recognized working-class associations for mutual benefit. While institutional structure, racial and ethnic segregation, urbanization, and sectoral development fundamentally contributed to the formation of a conservative working-class identity among skilled white men, the legal sanctioning of exclusive benefit schemes guaranteed this identity its organizational manifestation.

The UK’s Legislative Shift: The railway servants embrace the state

The first signs of a diverging legal environment would come with the Hornby v. Close case of 1867. As a prototypical craft union organized around mutual benefit provision, the United Society of Boilermakers confidently took a member to court for lack of payment. Upon review of their funds, which had increasingly been devoted to strike support, the judge determined that the society was organized for illegal purposes. An initial blow for craft unions, the case prompted a Royal Commission investigation into trade unions that would presage the debates of the monumental Taff Vale case of 1901. The Commission’s majority report concluded that “facilities should be granted for such registration as will give to the unions capacity for rights and duties resembling in some degree that of corporations,” including, importantly, the ability for the trade union as an organization to be sued based on the actions of its members (House of Commons 1868: xxiv).

The far more influential Minority report, by contrast, held that trade unions should be given the status of friendly societies, noting: “the state should accord to trade unions bare legal recognition…In return for this recognition a guarantee of perfect publicity in their laws and in their expenditure would be enacted, but these would be in no way interfered with so long as they were clear from crime” (ibid.: xxix).

Consensus on the matter would not be reached until 1871, when the minority report position won their case. The Trade Union Act and Criminal Law Amendment Acts of 1871 and 1875 invested trade unions with equal rights as friendly societies, preserving their status as voluntary associations and freeing them from criminal prosecution for restraint of trade. As a result, “neither a strike, nor the sanctioning contributing to or assisting a strike, [was] illegal, not merely in a criminal sense, but in the sense of rendering an association unlawful” (Schloesser and Clark Reference Schloesser and Clark1912: 121). Thanks to the newfound distinction between trade unions and friendly societies, regulations on the latter were loosened – they no longer had to send along their rules to the chief registrar for approval, while trade unions had to register their rules on an annual basis (Davis Reference Davis1876). Nevertheless, the laws confirmed the status of trade unions as clubs or associations of individual members who could not be sued as legal entities before the law (Adams Reference Adams1902). At first glance, the Acts of 1871 and 1875 may seem like a convergence with the legal precedent in the USA, which already provided trade unions with legal status. By legitimating the use of funds for strike support, however, the acts represented a substantive divergence on the question of what the recognized functions of a trade unions could openly be.

This monumental decision coincided with a burgeoning crisis in the friendly society movement. As a result of government ambitions to regulate and monitor what had become powerful national bodies, an investigation into their operations was commissioned in 1872. The Friendly Societies Act of 1874 stipulated that the government would thenceforward circulate model forms of accounts, balance sheets, and valuations and ensure that tables of payments would be constructed and published. The Registrar was also granted the power to investigate any society accused of nearing dissolution (UK Parliament 1874). As a result of these investigations, persistent and pervasive insolvency among the societies was uncovered (Cordery 2003).

In response, friendly society leaders formed the National Conference of Friendly Societies (NCFS) to defend their interests. The NCFS would advance the voluntarist cause even as friendly society members grew wary of participation – in testimonies given before the Royal Commission on Provident Insurance in 1886 and the Royal Commission on the Poor Laws of 1895, working-class society members stress the need for state intervention to ensure receipt of their benefits (Brodie Reference Brodie2014; Gilbert Reference Gilbert1965; Treble Reference Treble1970). In one of many such testimonies, a gardener from Sleaford argues that the new generation of workers “would not go into the present societies of today. They do not do it, and they will not do it.” He continues, “From hearing such unfavourable reports about friendly societies, there have been some terrible revelations about them…I quite believe that in time all these voluntary societies would be entirely done away with. they would not be required at all” (House of Commons 1886: 1613).

Popular awareness of friendly society insolvency visibly shook the faith in the sustainability of voluntary organizations as a whole. In the 1880s, sales of Samuel Smiles’ bestselling book, Self Help, began to decline, as fears over the health of the empire began to take hold (House of Commons 1909; White Reference White1901). In the final quarter of the nineteenth century, British governing elites increasingly began to lose confidence in the ability of working-class thrift to compensate for the growing inequalities of industrial capitalism (Davies Reference Davies1997). As they expanded the scope of trade union organization, they also more actively intervened in the management of friendly societies.

Thus, avenues for strike mobilization were opened just as the possibilities for voluntarism narrowed. Equally exemplary of this effort was a loophole opened for compulsory employers’ insurance schemes with the Shop Clubs Act of 1902. The Act permitted compulsory employer’s benefits to compete with those of workers under strict circumstances. While the actual registration of compulsory employer’s clubs may have been limited, their legality shaped the organizational reasoning of trade union leaders (Melling Reference Melling1980).

Each of these developments rippled through the ASRS. In 1879 Michael Thomas Bass sold the Railway Gazette (Gupta Reference Gupta1960). With the launching of the Railway Review in 1880, the organization’s General Secretary Fred Evans attempted to transform the union from a friendly society into a “fighting union” (Gupta Reference Gupta1960: 33). In its rebranding, the ASRS advanced itself as “the only organisation free from official influences and patronage” (ASRS Reports 1880: 63). Emboldened by the legislation and free from Bass’s supervision, Evans began to gently distinguish the organization from a benefit society. His opening article for an August 1882 issue of the Railway Review insists:

The ASRS is designed to provide help when it is not provided by [friendly societies]. If you are in health but out of employment the Oddfellows society does not give you monetary benefit to help maintain yourself and your family … Nor will any of those excellent bodies take part in battles affecting your hours, your wages, your safety at work. (ASRS Railway Review August 11 1882: 11)

In the next week’s issue, he continues:

As the majority of you are members of the companies and other provident or friendly societies, you can readily appreciate the value of provident assurance when applied to times of sickness… the ASRS is also a provident assurance, but against other vicissitudes than sickness. But the ASRS is more than this. It is an active influence, protecting and asserting the rights of railway workmen. It is an aggressive organisation, attacking practices than [sic] inflict wrong or injustice on you… The very opposition which the society has experienced is the highest testimony of its value. (ibid.: 8)

In these speeches, the language of aggression and open class struggle contrast sharply with that of benevolence and respectability, which dominated earlier declarations.

In addition to distancing itself from friendly societies, the ASRS also exhibited intense discussions regarding proliferating employer’s insurance schemes. In short yet increasingly frequent accounts of meetings regarding the Great Western Railway Pension Fund, members complain:

In almost every case membership in the fund is compulsory and a condition of service, and it is to the latter that so much objection is taken and from which trouble is continually arising, for it cannot be said that on any single line in the kingdom where one of these funds exists it is popular or that it has been introduced with the approval of the men. (ASRS Railway Review February 22 1889: 90)

In contrast to the tyranny of compulsory contributions to employer funds, ASRS members begin to “contend that if any compulsory provision has to be made it should be made by the state, and not left to employers of labour or anyone else” (ASRS Railway Review March 15 1889: 122). To counter employer’s funds, railway workers increasingly looked toward state regulation.

The events of the Taff Railway case would act as a microcosm of the broader relationship between repression, respectability, and voluntary benefits. In 1901, the Taff Vale Railway Companies sued the ASRS for damages perpetrated by its members during a strike. The judge interpreted the accusation in line with the majority report decision of 1867 – holding the union liable as a corporate entity. With the legitimacy of the trade union once again thrown into question, its leadership resorted to emphasizing its benefit functions.

In a 1902 Parliamentary debate radical Liberal Robert Reid insisted that a trade union’s “chief work is…that of conferring benefits, administering sick funds, pension funds, unemployed funds, widows’ funds, and so forth, on a very large scale” (UK Parliament 1902). MP for Leeds South John Walton held that trade union funds “represent the hard-earned savings of a large and most worthy section of the community, and they have been contributed in no small degree for the purpose of making provision against misfortune” (ibid.). And in 1906, Reid noted, “Between 1895–1904, 100 principal trade unions spent £16,060,000 of which only 14% was spent on dispute pay, the rest being all spent on benefits of various kinds” (ibid.).

This sort of defense was taken up by the ASRS’s own Parliamentary representative, Ramsay MacDonald. In a pamphlet on the dispute, he urges, “Trade unions are benefit societies, and though their industrial aspect is most important, their expenditure in relation to the unemployed and in subsidizing the aged, is one of the most striking features of the industrial history of the last half century” (MacDonald Reference MacDonald1903: 13).

The Trades Disputes Bill of 1906 restored the status of trade unions and consequently reopened alternative avenues for organization. With their legality and the accumulation of strike funds guaranteed, they were able to let go of insurance benefits, embrace state provision, and undertake a wider and more political role in British Society. By 1913, an observer declared, “The purely voluntary character of associative effort in Great Britain for mutual assurance is now a thing of the past. The state has stepped in” (Robinson Reference Robinson1913: 10). Thus, legal transformations in the late nineteenth and early century UK legitimated alternative organizational avenues for trade unions at the same time as they weakened the appeal of mutual benefit provision.

Persisting voluntarism in the USA: The brotherhoods commit to benefits

The legal environment looked very different for American trade unions. In the aftermath of the Civil War and up until the late nineteenth century, a wave of powerful conspiracy prosecutions were made against organized labor (Ernst Reference Ernst1995; Hattam Reference Hattam1993; Orren Reference Orren1991). Following the Haymarket Affair of 1886 – in which demonstrations for the 8-hour day ended in open fire from the police – courts consistently ruled that it was unlawful for “two or more persons to confederate and agree to deprive another of his liberty or property” (cited in Ernst Reference Ernst1995: 73). Unlike the Trades Union Acts of 1871 and 1875, this principle effectively rendered strikes and boycotts illegal during this period (Ernst Reference Ernst1995).

In the mid-1880s, the focus shifted from conspiracy to injunctions (Ernst Reference Ernst1995; Hattam Reference Hattam1993). Far from fragile associational clubs, governing elites perceived the trade unions of the late nineteenth century as powerful organized bodies capable of interfering not only in national markets but also in the political process, thereby threatening individual rights and market competition. With the introduction of the Sherman Anti-trust Act in 1890, trade unions were increasingly prosecuted as monopolistic “trusts” in restraint of free trade. While policymakers upheld the procedural rights of individual workers, they consistently denied substantive rights to unions – individuals could voluntarily associate, but, unless they incorporated, national associations were perceived as a threat (O’Brien Reference O’Brien1998; Orren Reference Orren1991). In a series of infamous labor cases, including the Danbury Hatter’s case and Gompers v. Buck’s Stove & Range Co., it was consistently held that strikes and boycotts unfairly restrained free trade. Just as before, trade unions could operate only so long as they pursued “respectable” objects.

Refusing to identify as either a corporation or a trust meant that American trade unions had to double down on their voluntary status. In its decades-long campaign to protect trade unions from injunctions under the Sherman Anti-trust Act, the AFL clung to voluntarism as a critical organizing tool. In his opening speech at the 1905 annual convention, AFL President Samuel Gompers noted:

There is no good reason why our unions should not…become the guarantee to our members for the payment of benefits by reason of illness, unemployment, loss of tools, superannuation, traveling, death, etc. etc…nor need we fear court decisions or suits at law mulcting our organizations and endangering the security of our funds…substantial funds once accumulated for provident as well as protective features, will compel better and higher regard for their sanctity by both the public and the bench. (American Federation of Labor 1905: 19)

While strikes and boycotts were continually outlawed, benefit provision only increased in legitimacy. American fraternal associations began to proliferate between the late 1860s and 1890s, reaching their peak after 1910. While only 78 fraternals formed before 1880, 490 were created between 1880 and 1901 alone (Cordery Reference Cordery, Gibaud, Lucassen, van der Lindon and Dreyfus1996). In November of 1886, 47 of the most significant societies, representing roughly 2.5 million members, combined to form the National Fraternal Congress (NFC) (Vondracek Reference Vondracek1972). In 1906, NFC member societies represented 91,434 lodges. By 1925, they reached their peak at 120,000 lodges around the country and over 30 million members – roughly one half of all adult males (Beito Reference Beito2000; Meyer Reference Meyer1901; Rosenweig Reference Rosenweig1977). American fraternals were not impervious to the actuarial crises of their British counterparts. In the 1920s, they entered their own prolonged period of crisis, and were soon overtaken by insurance companies in catering for workers. Indeed, their crisis would shortly precede the founding of the Congress of Industrial Organizations (CIO) and the rise of industrial unionism within the USA. During the critical policy conjuncture posed by the Progressive Era, however, their organizational form was in the midst of its rise.

Having been grouped as “benevolent” or “charitable” associations (Hardy Reference Hardy1908: 68), fraternals were excluded from any regulation relating to ordinary insurance companies until the mid-1880s. In 1885, Massachusetts was the first state to regulate the operations of fraternal societies, with Maine, Nebraska, New York, and Wisconsin following in subsequent years. In 1887 the NFC formed a committee to secure legislation protecting fraternal insurance. The bill that was proposed by the NFC in 1888 sought to establish uniform rules for the contribution rates and benefits paid across fraternal organizations. Throughout the 1890s fraternal organizations were preoccupied with “placing themselves on a perpetuating basis” (National Fraternal Congress 1886–96: 18, 61, 138), noting in 1896 that “it is the imperative duty of several societies to make at the earliest practical moment proper provision for meeting the inevitable increase in mortality by an adjustment of rates, so that the contribution shall be equally proportioned to the hazard of risk” (NFC 1896: 20). The congress developed a “mortality table” to guide other societies in 1898. As they centralized and systematized, they were increasingly incorporated and integrated into the insurance infrastructure.Footnote 3

Contemporary legal scholar Frederick Hampden Bacon observed:

The business has assumed enormous proportions and the courts have been called on with increasing frequency to determine the rights and construe the agreements of these societies and corporations. They are required by most states to have a representative form of government, the leadership of which is incorporated. The lodge system remains voluntary, but the national representatives are incorporated. (Bacon Reference Bacon1917, 2: 2)

Despite greater legitimacy and proliferating corporate status, the societies received little actual supervision or regulation. Unlike the Friendly Societies Acts, the Uniform Bill of 1893 made no requirement for a reserve fund and did little to assess the stability of the societies (Landis Reference Landis1900). Armed with legal protection and the ability to accumulate property, and facing little scrutiny, fraternal insurance organizations became the leading form of insurance among workers (Bacon Reference Bacon1917: 2; Witt Reference Witt2009). During this expansion, fraternals maintained their racial exclusivity: of the 200 largest fraternals in America at the turn of the century, roughly 2/3 excluded immigrants and racial minorities (Glenn Reference Glenn2001).

By 1911, eleven states had adopted uniform laws with rate tables and reserve requirements giving legal status to fraternal societies. By 1919, the number of states had increased to 40 (Witt Reference Witt2009). As the NFC Proceedings from 1892 noted, “From the insignificant beginning twenty years ago has grown a system of business exceeded in dimension by but few interests in the country. It began in a gracious spirit of beneficence; it outran its founders” (NFC 1892: 25).

The legal environment of American trade unions thus continued to outlaw their trade features while legitimizing fraternal insurance. The dynamic is made evident in the language of the 1914 Clayton Act – a modification of the Sherman Anti-Trust Act in which the AFL had gruelingly fought for exemptions for organized labor. The final Act held,

That nothing contained in the antitrust laws shall be construed to forbid the existence and operation of fraternal, labor, consumers, agricultural, or horticultural organizations, orders, or associations…instituted for the purposes of mutual help…or to forbid or restrain individual members of such orders or associations from carrying out the legitimate objects of such associations. (cited in Ernst Reference Ernst1992: 184)

Just like Hunt’s decision of 1842, the Clayton Act thus was “a bill to legalize lawful conduct” (ibid.: 187) in which mutual benefit features played a leading part.

The history of labor law in the American railroad industry is indispensable to this broader story. Thanks to the industry’s enormous expansion throughout the 1870s, the number of railway workers grew dramatically. In response to a rising threat of unionization, employers in the industry increasingly made use of yellow-dog contracts that prevented workers from joining any trade-related association. During the late 1870s, laws were passed in New Jersey, Pennsylvania, and Delaware that threatened to fine or imprison any worker who abandoned his position on the job. During this period, the railway Brotherhoods were purely aiming to survive (Taillon Reference Taillon1997).

In their efforts at legitimation, society members regularly sought a position equal to that of fraternal benefit societies. In 1878, the Brotherhood’s General Secretary and magazine editor William Sayre urged, “If it is a crime for engineers to belong to a brotherhood, why not discharge them also for their relations with the Masonry, Odd Fellows, etc.?” (BLF Magazine 1878: 47–48). This desire to appear as a fraternal society became more pronounced with the Great Railroad Strike of 1877, which was violently suppressed by the National Guard, federal troops, and employer-hired militias.

Though Sayre publicly supported the strike, he oriented the organization squarely against strike tactics in the following years. Asked about the Firemen’s relationship to strikes in 1877, he responded, “No. To disregard the laws which govern our land? We again say No, a thousand times No…Benevolence being the principal object, it is obvious that we are organized to protect and not to infure [sic]” (BLF Magazine 1877: 345–46). Associate editor of the BLF Magazine and later socialist leader Eugene Debs, similarly declared that “A strike at present time signifies anarchy and revolution, and the one of but a few days ago will never be blotted from the records of memory” (ibid.: 362).

In 1879, the membership of the organization would vote to reject strike activity wholesale, and, at the 1880 convention, the Grand Master Frank Arnold reflected that the decision “has gained us the unlimited confidence of our employers, gained us the sympathy of the best classes of people” (BLF Magazine 1880: 334–35). In the opening speech of the 1882 convention, Chairman Thomas Harper states,

It is the common belief and understanding among the uninitiated that the object of the organization is to prepare for and promote strikes… but this is not the case… It is not a labor organization, but rather a benevolent organization. Its object is to relieve the distressed, take care of its widows and organs, bury its dead and make better men and citizens of its members, their motto begin benevolence, sobriety, and industry. (BLF Proceedings 1882: 4–5)

The same year honorary speaker Colonel W.E. McLean confesses, “I am pleased to learn that it is not among the aims and purposes of the brotherhood either to foster or encourage labor strikes” (ibid.: 17). In 1883, Debs wrote “strikes are the knives with which laborers cut their own throat.” And as late as 1884, he noted that “the impression that the brotherhood is a combination to influence wages, or labor, or anything of the kind is a mistaken idea, as the organization is a purely beneficient one” (cited in Taillon Reference Taillon1997: 404).

The value system represented by benefits also held other cultural connotations. The independence and hard work representative of manhood were, more specifically, attributes of white manhood. The firemen’s constitution identified its membership as “white born, of good moral character, sober and industrious, sound in body and limb, not less than 18 or more than 45 years of age, able to read and right in English” (BLF Proceedings 1892: 109). Their moral system wholeheartedly excluded women, African Americans, recent immigrants, and lower grade workers. Organization documents are brimming with overtly racist and derogatory language that echoes that of the fraternal orders they aimed to mimic.

Despite a brief period of radicalization leading up to 1886, the Brotherhoods would return to their strategy of respectability in its aftermath. After the failure of a long and bitter strike along the Chicago Burlington and Quincy railroad in 1888, the Firemen would participate in the construction of the 1888 Arbitration Act, which introduced voluntary arbitration for all labor disputes threatening to interrupt interstate commerce. In doing so, the organizations positioned itself as the cordial face of labor opposed to industrial disputes.

This tendency would become even more profound following the Pullman Strike of 1894. The strike resulted in the crushing of the progressive ARU. In 1895, an injunction was granted against Eugene Debs, who had left the Brotherhoods to become the ARU’s leader. In distinguishing themselves from the ARU, the Brotherhoods referenced their benefit over their strike features:

A strike is the heaviest financial burden that members of existing organizations are called upon to bear…The expense of insurance can hardly be called a burden, it is a self-imposed expense and is voluntarily accepted by nearly all members of the BLF. (BLF Proceedings 1894: 63)

As insurance providers, the Brotherhoods would be praised by President Theodore Roosevelt for their promotion of the “faculty of individual initiative” (BLF Proceedings 1902: 26). In meetings with then secretary of state Richard Olney, they stressed the expulsion of thousands of members who were perceived to be in support of the Pullman strike, positioning the Brotherhood as a reliable partner for government negotiations (Tomlins Reference Tomlins1985).

The Erdman Act of 1898 would solidify this relationship. Even prior to the passing of the Act, a communication signed by the chiefs of the Brotherhoods supported its principles (Congressional Record vol 28, cited in Fisher Reference Fisher1922). In debates on the bill, then Commissioner of Labor Carroll D. Wright encouraged trade unions to take the opportunity to “dignify their bodies” through a policy which “places labor and capital on an equality as to the enforcement of contracts” – echoing the language of class compromise and respectability that prevailed in earlier decades (US Congress 1897: 2388). Defenders of the act explicitly argued that “a strike which would involve our railroad systems would be appalling,” and held that “this bill is designed to obviate such disaster” (ibid.: 2389). At the hearings, the Firemen sent a circular in which they urge a representative to “use your influence and utmost endeavors to have [the bill] passed” (ibid.: 2390).

In exchange for surrendering participation in mass strikes and representing workers on arbitration boards, the Brotherhoods obtained “a level of security and stability unprecedented for any national union until that time or until the New Deal era” (Taillon Reference Taillon1997: 434). Section 9 of the Act outlawed the use of yellow-dog contracts, prevented the blacklisting of unionized workers, and, notably, forbade employers from “require[ing] any employee or any person seeking employment, as a condition of such employment, to enter into a contract whereby such employee or applicant for employment shall agree to contribute to any fund for charitable, social, or beneficial purposes” (US Congress 1897: 2388). While the Erdman Act did not outlaw all employer insurance schemes, it did make compulsory membership in the schemes illegal at the same time as it legalized trade union membership. In this way, it actively protected the position of the Brotherhoods as benefit providers.

Legal boundaries, organizational fields, and trade union politics

In this paper, I have argued that organizational sociology, with its emphasis on the institutional promotion of organizational forms, offers crucial insights regarding the political orientation of labor movements. I have sought to demonstrate the importance of law in delineating legitimate and illegitimate forms of public association throughout the nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Notably, I have argued that the regulation of friendly and fraternal mutual benefit societies was significant in shaping the organizational opportunities of trade unions: throughout much of the nineteenth century, trade unions in both the USA and the UK adopted exclusive craft benefits as a symbol of respectability and compliance. Toward the end of the century, the legal environment within which these movements operated shifted. UK legislators recognized the use of strikes and boycotts, closely monitored the solvency of friendly societies, and left an opening for compulsory employer benefit schemes, while American courts effectively prohibited strikes and boycotts through anti-trust injunctions and the infrastructure of voluntary arbitration, sanctioned the growth of fraternal benefit societies, and outlawed compulsory employer’s insurance. Thanks to their participation in party politics and position in crucial legislative developments, the countries’ major railway unions were decisive in promoting these shifts.

These findings bear implications for research on trade union strategies, which overwhelmingly centers on management practices, sectoral development, and labor market structure in explaining trade union orientation toward public benefits (Haydu Reference Haydu1991; Marks Reference Marks2014). They point to the importance of organizational environment in shaping the strategic reasoning of trade unions. Additionally, the findings build on existing analyses of law and labor that emphasize the legal constraints to trade union organizing (Ernst Reference Ernst1995; Forbath Reference Forbath1991; Hattam Reference Hattam1993; Orren Reference Orren1991; Tomlins Reference Tomlins1985). To understand the form trade union organizing took, I contribute an account of the legal opportunities put before trade union leaders. Finally, the findings engage a longstanding literature on class formation, which emphasizes the importance of early democratization, ethnic and racial discrimination, patterns of industrialization, and the political evolution of the USA (Bridges Reference Bridges, Katznelson and Zolberg1986; Davis Reference Davis1980; Dawley Reference Dawley2000; Katznelson and Zolberg Reference Katznelson and Zolberg1986; Roediger Reference Roediger1999). These factors certainly contributed toward the emergence of a deeply conservative, racist, and patriarchal tradition within the American labor movement, embodied most clearly in the culture and practices of nineteenth-century craft unions. But viewing the evolution of this tradition through the lens of organizational forms suggests that the victory of this craft tradition, complete with its commitment to insurance over state benefits, was not inevitable during the Progressive Era. Though alternative forms of class sentiment emerged across the US labor movement, they were not granted organizational legitimacy. As a result, the research indicates that trade union strategies are not only a reflection of class sentiments held by workers or industrial conditions. Rather, trade unions are influenced by organizational logics of legitimacy that lead them to embrace organizational forms advocated by governing elites. The state, then, is directly implicated in the form that trade union politics take.

Footnotes

1 An employer memo from 1813 warned: “benefit societies [have] created, cherished, and given effect to the most dangerous combinations among the several journeymen in [their] district…If there is not shortly some regulation adopted…absolute ruin will overtake the master manufacturers of the empire, and the journeymen will assume an overbearing, oppressive, and mischievous character that will be alike dangerous to the prosperity and tranquillity of the country” (Gosden Reference Gosden1961: 156–57).

2 See accounts of 1815, 1827, 1829, and 1835 in Commons and Sumner (Reference Commons and Sumner1910).

3 Incorporated under the same legislation, fraternal societies ultimately came to be regarded much like insurance companies. Courts began to assert: “the object of a mutual benefit society is insurance, not benevolence…the payment of the benefit fund by a mutual benefit society to the beneficiary…is not voluntary, and in the nature of a gift, but is the fulfilment of a contract of insurance entered into by the member and the society” (cited in Niblack Reference Niblack1894: 7). Niblack also notes that “by-laws of a society which forbid a member to work at his trade at such prices as he chooses to accept, and compel him to join a strike by punishing him for refusing to do so, are void as against public policy. It is not illegal for workingmen to form and act as an association for the purpose of protecting themselves…all combinations and associations designed to coerce workmen to become members, or to interfere with, obstruct, vex, or annoy them in working or in obtaining work because they are not members….and all associations designed to interfere with the perfect freedom of employers in the proper management and control of their lawful business…are pro tanto illegal combinations or associations” (Footnote ibid.: 36).

References

Adams, W. G. S. (1902) “The incorporation of trade unions: The position in England.” Journal of Political Economy 11 (1): 8992.10.1086/250898CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amalgamated Society of Engineers (ASE) (c. 1851–1920) Monthly Reports. MSS.259. Coventry: Modern Records Centre, University of Warwick.Google Scholar
Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants (ASRS) (c. 1876–1913) Annual Reports and Proceedings. MSS.127. Coventry: Modern Records Centre, University of Warwick.Google Scholar
Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants (ASRS) (c. 1880–1915) Railway Review. MSS.127. Coventry: Modern Records Centre, University of Warwick.Google Scholar
American Federation of Labor (c. 1905) “Report of the proceedings of the…annual convention of the American Federation of Labor.” HathiTrust, https://hdl.handle.net/2027/njp.32101065131037 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Archer, Robin (2008) Why Is There No Labor Party in the United States? Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bacon, Frederick Hampden (c. 1917) A Treatise on the Law of Life and Accident Insurance: Including Benefit Societies, and Voluntary Associations. Vol. 1. St. Louis: F.H. Thomas Law Book Company.Google Scholar
Beito, David T. (1997) “The ‘lodge practice evil’ reconsidered: Medical care through fraternal societies, 1900–1930.” Journal of Urban History 23 (5): 569600.10.1177/009614429702300502CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beito, David T. (2000) From Mutual Aid to the Welfare State: Fraternal Societies and Social Services, 1890–1967. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Bernard Gibaud, Jan Lucassen, van der Lindon, Marcel, and Dreyfus, Michel (2003) British Friendly Societies, 1750–1914. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bloch, Ruth H., and Lamoreaux, Naomi R. (2015) “Voluntary associations, corporate rights, and the state: Legal constraints on the development of American civil society, 1750–1900.” Working Paper Series 21153. National Bureau of Economic Research, doi: 10.3386/w21153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boxall, Peter (2008) “Trade union strategy,” in Blyton, Paul, Heery, Edmund, Bacon, Nicolas, and Fiorito, Jack (eds.) The SAGE Handbook of Industrial Relations. London: SAGE Publications Ltd: 209–24.10.4135/9781849200431.n11CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bridges, Amy (1986) “Becoming American: The working class in the US before the Civil War,” in Katznelson, Ira and Zolberg, Aristide R. (eds.) Working Class Formation: Patterns in Nineteenth Century United States and Europe. Princeton: Princeton University Press: 157–96.Google Scholar
Brodie, Marc (2014) “‘You could not get any person to be trusted except the state’: Poorer workers’ loss of faith in voluntarism in late 19th century Britain.” Journal of Social History 47 (4): 1071–95.10.1093/jsh/shu021CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brotherhood of Locomotive Firemen and Enginemen (BLF) (c. 1873–1915) “Locomotive firemen’s magazine.” HathiTrust. Brotherhood of Locomotive Firemen and Enginemen, https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/000675974 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Brotherhood of Locomotive Firemen and Enginemen (BLF) (1874–1915) “Proceedings.” HathiTrust, https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/010007101?type%5B%5D=all&lookfor%5B%5D=brotherhood%20of%20locomotive%20firemen%20proceedings&ft= (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Clawson, Mary Ann (1985) “Fraternal orders and class formation in the nineteenth-century United States.” Comparative Studies in Society and History 27 (4): 672–95.10.1017/S0010417500011713CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clemens, Elisabeth S. (2020) Civic Gifts: Voluntarism and the Making of the American Nation-State. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.10.7208/chicago/9780226670973.001.0001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, John Rogers, and Sumner, Helen L., eds. (1910) A Documentary History of American Industrial Society. Vol. 4. Cleveland: A. H. Clarke Co.10.2307/1922565CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cordery, Simon (1995) “Friendly societies and the discourse of respectability in Britain, 1825–1875.” Journal of British Studies 34 (1): 3558.10.1086/386066CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cordery, Simon (1996) “Fraternal orders in the United States: A quest for protection and identity,” in Gibaud, Bernard, Lucassen, Jan, van der Lindon, Marcel, and Dreyfus, Michel (eds.) Social Security Mutualism: The Comparative History of Mutual Benefit Societies. Lausanne: Peter Lang: 83109.Google Scholar
Crompton, Gerald (2009) “Lines of division: Railway unions and labour, 1900−39,” in Worley, Mattew (ed.) The Foundations of the British Labour Party. London: Routledge: 3757.Google Scholar
Davies, Stephen (1997) “Two conceptions of welfare: Voluntarism and incorporationism.” Social Philosophy and Policy 14 (2): 3968.10.1017/S0265052500001813CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davis, Henry Frederick Alexander (c. 1876) The Law and Practice of Friendly Societies and Trade Unions: Under the Friendly Societies Act, 1875, the Trade Unions Act, 1871, and the Conspiracy and Protection of Property Act, 1875; with Official Regulations and Rules and Forms. London: H. Sweet.Google Scholar
Davis, Mike (1980) “Why the US working class is different.” New Left Review 1 (123): 344.Google Scholar
Dawley, Alan (2000) Class and Community. Boston: Harvard University Press.10.4159/9780674030282CrossRefGoogle Scholar
DiMaggio, Paul J., and Powell, Walter W. (1983) “The iron cage revisited: Institutional isomorphism and collective rationality in organizational fields.” American Sociological Review 48 (2): 147–60.10.2307/2095101CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dobbin, Frank (1995) “The origins of economic laws: Railway entrepreneurs and public policy in nineteenth-century America,” in Scott, Richard and Moller Christensen, Soren (eds.) The Institutional Construction of Organization: International and Longitudinal Studies. Thousand Oaks, CA: SAGE Publications, Inc.: 277301.Google Scholar
Du Bois, W. E. B. (2022 [1906]) L’ouvrier negre en amérique [The negro worker in America], Revue Économique Internationale. Critical Sociology 3: 298–348, https://doi.org/10.1177/08969205221138011.Google Scholar
Dubofsky, Melvyn, and Dulles, Foster Rhea (2010) Labor in America: A History. 8th edition. Wheeling: Wiley-Blackwell.Google Scholar
Eden, Frederick Morton (2011 [1797]) The State of the Poor: Or, an History of the Labouring Classes in England, from the Conquest to the Present Period. Vol. 1. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ernst, Daniel R (1992) “Free labor, the consumer interest, and the law of industrial disputes, 1885–1900.” American Journal of Legal History 36 (1): 1937.10.2307/845451CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ernst, Daniel R. (1995) Lawyers Against Labor: From Individual Rights to Corporate Liberalism. Champaign: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Fisher, Clyde Olin (c. 1922) Use of Federal Power in Settlement of Railway Labor Disputes. Washington: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Forbath, William E (1991) “Courts, constitutions, and labor politics in England and America: A study of the constitutive power of law.” Law & Social Inquiry 16 (1): 134.10.1111/j.1747-4469.1991.tb00282.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedman, Gerald (1988) “The state and the making of the working class: France and the United States, 1880–1914.” Theory and Society 17 (3): 403–30.10.1007/BF00160845CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gilbert, Bentley (1965) “The decay of nineteenth-century provident institutions and the coming of old age pensions in Great Britain.” Economic History Review 17 (3): 551–63.10.2307/2592628CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glenn, Brian J. (2001) “Understanding mutual benefit societies, 1860–1960.” Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 26 (3): 638–51.10.1215/03616878-26-3-638CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Gompers, Samuel (c. 1916) “Labor vs. its barnacles.” The American Federationist 23 (4): 268–74.Google Scholar
Gosden, P. H. J. H. (1961) The Friendly Societies in England, 1815–1875. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Greenberg, Brian (1985) Worker and Community: Response to Industrialization in a Nineteenth Century American City, Albany New York 1850–1884. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Greene, Julie (2006) Pure and Simple Politics: The American Federation of Labor and Political Activism, 1881–1917. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gupta, P. S. (1960) “The history of the Amalgamated Society of Railway Servants, 1871–1913.” PhD diss., Oxford University, https://ora.ox.ac.uk/objects/uuid:1ec7b57a-7997-4705-b563-c5a06851d108.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S. (1998) “The historical logic of national health insurance: Structure and sequence in the development of British, Canadian, and U.S. medical policy.” Studies in American Political Development 12 (1): 57130.10.1017/S0898588X98001308CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardy, Carlos S. (c. 1908) Fraternal Society Law Embracing the Statute Law and a Digest of the Decisions of the Court of Last Resort of the Several States Concerning Fraternal Beneficiary Societies. Los Angeles: Chicago Star Bindery.Google Scholar
Hattam, Victoria (1993) Labor Visions and State Power. Princeton: Princeton University Press.10.1515/9781400863082CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haveman, Heather A. (1992) “Between a rock and a hard place: Organizational change and performance under conditions of fundamental environmental transformation.” Administrative Science Quarterly 37 (1): 4875.10.2307/2393533CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haydu, Jeffrey (1991) Between Craft and Class: Skilled Workers and Factory Politics in the United States and Britain, 1890–1922. Los Angeles: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Hostler, Stanley (1955) “The Brotherhood of Locomotive Firemen: Benevolent Era, 1873–1887.” PhD diss., The Pennsylvania State University.Google Scholar
House of Commons (c. 1793) “A bill for the encouragement and relief of friendly societies.” House of Commons Sessional Papers of the Eighteenth Century (1715–1800), House of Commons Papers. Parliamentary Archives Online, https://archives.parliament.uk/collections/getrecord/GB61_HL_PO_PU_1_1793_33G3n282 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
House of Commons (c. 1824) “Select committee on state of law in United Kingdom respecting artisans leaving kingdom, and exportation of tools and machinery, and combination of workmen to raise wages: Report, minutes of evidence.” Nineteenth Century House of Commons Sessional Papers, House of Commons Papers. UK Parliamentary Archives, https://parlipapers-proquest-com.gate3.library.lse.ac.uk/parlipapers/docview/t70.d75.1824-008876?accountid=9630 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
House of Commons (c. 1868) “Royal commission to inquire into organization and rules of trades unions and other associations eleventh and final report.” Command Papers, Nineteenth Century House of Commons Sessional Papers, House of Commons Papers. UK Parliamentary Archives, https://parlipapers-proquest-com.gate3.library.lse.ac.uk/parlipapers/docview/t70.d75.1867-044275?accountid=9630 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
House of Commons (c. 1886) “Select committee on national provident insurance report, proceedings, minutes of evidence, appendix, index.” Nineteenth Century House of Commons Sessional Papers, House of Commons Papers. UK Parliamentary Archives, https://parlipapers-proquest-com.gate3.library.lse.ac.uk/parlipapers/docview/t70.d75.1886-062334?accountid=9630 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
House of Commons (c. 1909) “Royal commission on the poor laws and relief of distress.” Command Papers, Twentieth Century House of Commons Sessional Papers, House of Commons Papers. UK Parliamentary Archives, https://parlipapers-proquest-com.gate3.library.lse.ac.uk/parlipapers/docview/t70.d75.1909-011072?accountid=9630 (Accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Hyman, Richard (2001) Understanding European Trade Unionism: Between Market, Class and Society. London: SAGE Publications.10.4135/9781446217139CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenks, Leland H. (1944) “Railroads as an economic force in American development.” Journal of Economic History 4 (1): 120.10.1017/S002205070008400XCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Joseph, Antoine (2000) Skilled Workers’ Solidarity: The American Experience in Comparative Perspective. New York: Garland Publishing.Google Scholar
Katznelson, Ira, and Zolberg, Aristide R., eds. (1986) Working-Class Formation: Nineteenth-Century Patterns in Western Europe and the United States. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kirk, Neville (1994) Labour and Society in Britain and the USA: Challenge and Accommodation, 1850–1939. Aldershot: Scolar Press.Google Scholar
Landis, Abb (c. 1900) Friendly Societies and Fraternal Orders: A History of the Legislation, Supervision, Mortality Experience, Management, Reforms, Rates of Assessment and Present and Past Financial Condition of the English Friendly Societies. Winchester, Tennessee: Self Published.Google Scholar
Lloyd, Thomas (c. 1806) The Trial of the Boot & Shoemakers of Philadelphia, on an Indictment for a Combination and Conspiracy to Raise Their Wages. Philadelphia: B. Graves.Google Scholar
MacDonald, James Ramsay (1903) The Law and Trade Union Funds. A Plea for Ante-Taff Vale. London: Independent Labour Party.Google Scholar
March, James G., and Olsen, Johan P. (1989) Rediscovering Institutions: The Organizational Basis of Politics. New York: The Free Press.Google Scholar
Marks, Gary Wolfe (2014) Unions in Politics: Britain, Germany, and the United States in the Nineteenth and Early Twentieth Centuries. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Massachusetts Supreme Judicial Court (1866) Report of Cases Argued and Determined in the Supreme Judicial Court of Massachusetts. Vol. 3. Boston: Little Brown and Company.Google Scholar
McCartin, Joseph A. (2023) “The Railway Labor Act: Exhibit A in our outmoded system of labor law.” New Labor Forum 32 (3): 3441.10.1177/10957960231194023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Melling, Joseph Leslie (1980) “British employers and the development of industrial welfare, c. 1880-1920: An industrial and regional comparison.” PhD thesis, University of Glasgow.Google Scholar
Meyer, B. H. (c. 1901) “Fraternal beneficiary societies in the United States.” American Journal of Sociology 6 (5): 646–61.10.1086/211000CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meyer, John W., and Rowan, Brian (1977) “Institutionalized organizations: Formal structure as myth and ceremony.” American Journal of Sociology 83 (2): 340–63.10.1086/226550CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mitchell, B. R. (1964) “The coming of the railway and United Kingdom economic growth.” The Journal of Economic History 24 (3): 315–36.10.1017/S0022050700060873CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, David (2014) “Labor in the industrial era,” in Morris, Richard B. (ed.) A History of the American Worker. Princeton: Princeton University Press: 79114.Google Scholar
National Fraternal Congress (NFC) (c. 1886–96) “Proceedings of the annual meeting of the National Fraternal Congress.” HathiTrust, National Fraternal Congress. Online, https://catalog.hathitrust.org/Record/009997328 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Niblack, William Caldwell (c. 1894) The Law of Voluntary Societies, Mutual Benefit Insurance and Accident Insurance. Chicago: Callaghan & Co.Google Scholar
Novak, William J. (2001) “The American law of association: The legal-political construction of civil society.” Studies in American Political Development 15: 163–88.10.1017/S0898588X01000037CrossRefGoogle Scholar
O’Brien, Ruth (1998) Workers’ Paradox: The Republican Origins of New Deal Labor Policy, 1886–1935. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Orren, Karen (1991) Belated Feudalism: Labor, the Law, and Liberal Development in the United States. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pelling, Henry (1992) A History of British Trade Unionism. London: Palgrave Macmillan.10.1007/978-1-349-12968-3CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pennsylvania General Assembly (1869) “An act to authorize mechanics, journeymen, tradesmen and laborers to form societies and associations for their mutual aid, benefit and protection.” P. L. 1260, No. 1242.Google Scholar
Revill, George (1999) “Liberalism and paternalism: Politics and corporate culture in ‘Railway Derby,’ 1865–75.” Social History 24 (2): 196214.10.1080/03071029908568062CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, M. Fothergill (c. 1913) The Spirit of Association, Being Some Account of the Gilds, Friendly Societies, Co-Operative Movement, and Trade Unions of Great Britain. London: Legare Street Press.Google Scholar
Roediger, David R. (1999) The Wages of Whiteness: Race and the Making of the American Working Class. New York: Verso Books.Google Scholar
Rosenweig, Roy (1977) “Boston masons, 1900–1935: The lower middle class in a divided society.” Journal of Voluntary Action Research 6 (304): 119–26.10.1177/089976407700600303CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schloesser, Henry Herman, and Clark, William Smith (c. 1912) The Legal Position of Trade Unions. London: P. S. King & son.Google Scholar
Shefter, Martin (1994) Political Parties and the State: The American Historical Experience. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Skocpol, Theda, and Amenta, Edwin (1986) “States and social policies.” Annual Review of Sociology 12 (1): 131–57.10.1146/annurev.so.12.080186.001023CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skowronek, Stephen (1982) Building a New American State: The Expansion of National Administrative Capacities, 1877–1920. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.10.1017/CBO9780511665080CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smiles, Samuel (c. 1862) Self-Help: With Illustrations of Character, Conduct and Perseverance. London: A. L. Burt.Google Scholar
Spry, James (c. 1867) The History of Odd-Fellowship. London: Fred Pitman.Google Scholar
Stevens, Albert Clark (c. 1907) The Cyclopædia of Fraternities. New York: E.B. Treat and Company.Google Scholar
Stryker, Robin (2000) “Legitimacy processes as institutional politics: implications for theory and research in the sociology of organizations,” in Lounsbury, Michael (ed.) Research in the Sociology of Organizations. Vol. 17. Leeds: Emerald Group Publishing Limited: 179223.10.1016/S0733-558X(00)17006-5CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taft, Philip (1963) “On the origins of business unionism.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 17 (1): 2038.10.1177/001979396301700102CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taillon, Paul Michel (1997) Culture, Politics, and the Making of the Railroad Brotherhoods, 1863–1916. Madison: University of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Tomlins, Christopher L. (1985) The State and the Unions. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Trades Union Congress (c. 1899) Parliamentary Committee Reports. HD 6661, Special Collections TUC Publications. London: London Metropolitan University.Google Scholar
Treble, James H. (1970) “The attitudes of friendly societies towards the movement in Great Britain for state pensions, 1878–1908.” International Review of Social History 15 (2): 266–99.10.1017/S0020859000003849CrossRefGoogle Scholar
UK Parliament (c. 1828) “Bill to consolidate and amend law relating to friendly and other societies.” Bills and Acts, Nineteenth Century House of Commons Sessional Papers, UK Parliamentary Archives Online, https://parlipapers-proquest-com.gate3.library.lse.ac.uk/parlipapers/docview/t70.d75.1828-010791?accountid=9630 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
UK Parliament (c. 1874) “Bill to consolidate and amend law relating to friendly and other societies: (As Amended in Committee).” Bills and Acts, Nineteenth Century House of Commons Sessional Papers, UK Parliamentary Archives Online, https://parlipapers-proquest-com.gate3.library.lse.ac.uk/parlipapers/docview/t70.d75.1874-049878?accountid=9630 (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
UK Parliament (c. 1902) “Trade disputes—legal position of trade unions.” Hansard Online. UK Parliamentary Archives, https://hansard.parliament.uk/Commons/1902-05-14/debates/9b599b9f-3470-4420-8d7f-fbccf9bf4069/TradeDisputes%E2%80%94LegalPositionOfTradeUnions (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
UK Parliament (c. 1906) “Trade dispute bill, second reading.” Hansard Online. UK Parliamentary Archives, https://hansard.parliament.uk/commons/1906-12-17/debates/3ced4a9e-75a8-46aa-a2b6-217e4c921ac7/TradeDisputesBill (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Upchurch, John Jorden (c. 1887) The Life, Labors and Travels of Father J. J. Upchurch: Founder of the Ancient Order of United Workmen. San Francisco: A. T. Dewey.Google Scholar
US Congress (c. 1897) “Congressional record February 26, Vol. 29 part 3 (bound edition).” Congressional Record, https://www.congress.gov/bound-congressional-record/1897/02/26/house-section (accessed May 30, 2024).Google Scholar
Vondracek, Felix John (1972) “The rise of fraternal organizations in the United States, 1868–1900.” Social Science 47 (1): 2633.Google Scholar
Voss, Kim (1993) The Making of American Exceptionalism: The Knights of Labor and Class Formation in the Nineteenth Century. Ithaca: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Weir, Robert E. (1952) Beyond Labor’s Veil: The Culture of the Knights of Labor. University Park: The Pennsylvania State University Press.Google Scholar
White, Arnold (c. 1901) Efficiency and Empire. London: Methuen & Company.Google Scholar
Witt, John Fabian (2009) The Accidental Republic: Crippled Workingmen, Destitute Widows, and the Remaking of American Law. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.10.2307/j.ctv1pncrrzCrossRefGoogle Scholar