No CrossRef data available.
Article contents
Timing is everything: Evaluating behavioural causal theories of Britain's industrialisation
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 20 November 2019
Abstract
Baumard's thesis that the English Industrial Revolution can be explained by Life History Theory's predictions for psychological development is a progression of much literature in economic and social history. However, the theory suffers from its reliance on increasingly fragile data indicators for “wealth” and its focus on “innovation” as new research begins to explore sectoral dynamics in long run growth.
- Type
- Open Peer Commentary
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2019
References
Allen, R. C. (2009b) The British industrial revolution in global perspective. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Cannadine, D. (1984) The present and the past in the English Industrial Revolution 1880–1980. Past and Present (103):131–72.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. (2010) Explaining the first industrial revolution: Two views. CAGE Online Working Paper Series, No.10/2010. Available at: http://wrap.warwick.ac.uk/44710/1/WRAP_Carfts_10.2010_craftsindustrial.pdf.Google Scholar
Crafts, N. & Mills, T. C. (2017) Six centuries of British economic growth: A time-series perspective. European Review of Economic History 21:141–58.Google Scholar
de Vries, J. (2008) The industrious revolution: Consumer behavior and the household economy, 1650 to the present. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hewitt, R. (2017) A revolution of feeling: The decade that forged the modern mind. Granta BooksGoogle Scholar
Humphries, J. & Schneider, B. (2019) Spinning the Industrial Revolution. The Economic History Review 72(1):126–55.Google Scholar
López Losa, E. (2016) Spanish real wages in the northern-western European mirror, 1500–1800. On the timings and magnitude of the Little Divergence in Europe. Asociacion Espã nola de Historia Economica Working Paper, No. 1607.Google Scholar
Mocarelli, L. (2019) What is wrong with the history of wages: Or the divide in economic history—A reappraisal suggested by eighteenth-century Milan. In: Seven centuries of unreal wages, ed. Hatcher, J. & Stephenson, J., pp. 95–116. Palgrave Studies in Economic History. Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Reddy, W. (2001) The navigation of feeling: A framework for the history of emotions. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stephenson, J. Z. (2018) Looking for work? Or looking for workers? Days and hours of work in London construction in the eighteenth century (January 22, 2018). Available at: SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=3128189 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.3128189.Google Scholar
Stephenson, J. Z. (2019) The pay of labourers and unskilled men in London 1660–1770. forthcoming in: Seven centuries of unreal wages (2019), ed. Hatcher, J. & Stephenson, J. Z.. Palgrave.Google Scholar
Styles, J. (2016) Fashion, textiles and the origins of Industrial Revolution. East Asian Journal of British History 5:161–90.Google Scholar
Target article
Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution
Related commentaries (24)
A claim for cognitive history
A needed amendment that explains too much and resolves little
Affluence boosted intelligence? How the interaction between cognition and environment may have produced an eighteenth-century Flynn effect during the Industrial Revolution
Are both necessity and opportunity the mothers of innovations?
Cultural interconnectedness and in-group cooperation as sources of innovation
Energy, transport, and consumption in the Industrial Revolution
England first, America second: The ecological predictors of life history and innovation
Environmental unpredictability, economic inequality, and dynamic nature of life history before, during, and after the Industrial Revolution
Explaining historical change in terms of LHT: A pluralistic causal framework is needed
Interrelationships of factors of social development are more complex than Life History Theory predicts
Life History Theory and economic modernity
Life History Theory and the Industrial Revolution
Many causes, not one
Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution: Why we need causal methods and historians
Psychology and the economics of invention
Slowing life history (K) can account for increasing micro-innovation rates and GDP growth, but not macro-innovation rates, which declined following the end of the Industrial Revolution
The affective origins of the Industrial Revolution
The other angle of Maslow's pyramid: How scarce environments trigger low-opportunity-cost innovations
The wealth→life history→innovation account of the Industrial Revolution is largely inconsistent with empirical time series data
There is little evidence that the Industrial Revolution was caused by a preference shift
Timing is everything: Evaluating behavioural causal theories of Britain's industrialisation
Using big data to map the relationship between time perspectives and economic outputs
What came first, the chicken or the egg?
What motivated the Industrial Revolution: England's libertarian culture or affluence per se?
Author response
Psychological origins of the Industrial Revolution: More work is needed!