Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-24T20:18:01.147Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Effect of Education on Support for International Trade: Evidence from Compulsory-Education Reforms

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 November 2024

Omer Solodoch*
Affiliation:
Department of International Relations, Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Israel

Abstract

Across countries and over time, support for economic globalization is strongest among individuals with the highest levels of education. Yet despite long-lasting debates on the sources of this correlation, reliable evidence that isolates the causal effect of education from the nonrandom selection of individuals into education is lacking. To address this fundamental issue, I exploit compulsory-schooling reforms that increased the minimum school-leaving age in eighteen countries. Employing a fuzzy regression discontinuity design, I find that the reform-induced added years of education substantially and durably increased support for trade liberalization. And using new data on the content of school curricula, I find that the effect of schooling largely stems from instilling tolerance and pluralism in citizens and reducing the perceived cultural threat of globalization. In contrast, there is little evidence that the effect of schooling reflects the distributive consequences of international trade, separating globalization winners and losers.

Type
Research Note
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BY
This is an Open Access article, distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence (https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted re-use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.
Copyright
Copyright © The Author(s), 2024. Published by Cambridge University Press on behalf of The IO Foundation

The re-emergence of international trade and investment after World War II produced remarkable economic growth in many regions of the globe and facilitated political cooperation between past rival states.Footnote 1 Yet recent decades have seen a rising backlash against globalization. Voters have increasingly voted for protectionist political candidates who promised to limit foreign trade.Footnote 2 These campaign promises were eventually translated into significant policy changes, bringing about a steep increase in worldwide protectionism that was most clearly manifested by, but went beyond, the US–China trade war.Footnote 3

Much of the electoral force driving the rise of antiglobalization parties and candidates and the recent return to protectionism is composed of voters with less formal education.Footnote 4 Education has also emerged as one of the most important predictors of public support for international trade.Footnote 5 Yet no study to date has provided reliable evidence on the causal impact of education on attitudes toward economic globalization. Is education a causal factor in trade policy preferences or a sorting variable that divides essentially different individuals into different levels of education based on other determinants of trade preferences?

Initially, the robust correlation between education and trade attitudes across various developed countries and time periods was interpreted as supporting prominent models of political economy which suggest that individuals’ preferences reflect their material self-interest in light of the distributional outcomes of free trade.Footnote 6 The personal-interest-based perspective has been challenged by subsequent research, which showed that the effect of education likely stems from two potential sources of influence: an ideational mechanism, by which exposure to economic ideas and information in college increases support for trade; and a cultural mechanism, according to which education socializes students to have more tolerant values and a cosmopolitan worldview.Footnote 7

However, another possibility, which has not been directly tested, is that the correlation between education and trade preferences is spurious: individuals who acquire more education are also more likely to support economic globalization to begin with. Education might be the outcome of various unobserved characteristics, such as cognitive skills, labor-market potential, personality traits, or family background.Footnote 8 And these characteristics might also explain variation in trade preferences. For example, higher cognitive skills are associated with both educational attainment and labor-market outcomes among high-school dropouts.Footnote 9 Similarly, individuals with greater openness to experience are more intellectually curious and motivated to acquire knowledge and education, but they also tend to be more open to different cultures and lifestyles and more socially liberal.Footnote 10 Given the centrality and predictive power of formal education in explaining trade attitudes, addressing this puzzle has important implications for understanding the broader causes of the rise of public opposition to economic globalization.

To assess the causal effect of education, I leverage the implementation of compulsory-schooling reforms since World War II. I collect information from multiple sources to identify such reforms in countries that participated in at least two of the three National Identity modules of the International Social Survey Programme (ISSP): 1995, 2003, and 2013. Using these data, I compile a list that encompasses twenty compulsory-schooling reforms implemented over four decades (the 1940s to the 1970s) in eighteen countries spanning Western Europe, Eastern Europe, and East Asia. Those reforms increased the minimum school-leaving age by one to three years (or 1.6 years, on average).

Using a fuzzy regression discontinuity (RD) design in which respondents from the first cohorts affected by the reforms are compared to those from slightly older, unaffected cohorts, I show that these reforms successfully increased the treatment take-up (compulsory-schooling completion) by approximately ten percentage points. The central finding of the analysis is that the added years of education substantially and durably increased support for trade liberalization. An additional year of schooling, induced by the reforms, increases support for overseas commerce by three percentage points in the overall population and by ten points for compliers in the first affected cohorts. This set of results shows that the relationship between education and popular support for trade is causal and not entirely or even mostly driven by other characteristics that affect both education and trade preferences.

The second part of the analysis tests the observable implications of prominent explanations for the effect of education on support for free trade. Since the reforms under study here affect trade attitudes by increasing secondary education, the potential influence of the ideational mechanism—according to which exposure to economic ideas and knowledge in college produces the effect of education—is largely neutralized.Footnote 11 Instead, the analysis reveals that the additional years of secondary education made individuals more open to foreign cultures and influences more broadly, even when such openness is not directly associated with international trade. The increase in education due to the reforms did not sort individuals into occupations that are less vulnerable to foreign economic competition. Moreover, the effect of education on support for trade liberalization remains similar across starkly different economic circumstances and degrees of exposure to import competition or offshoring. Whether or not individuals actively participate in the labor force or work in the manufacturing sector or in offshorable occupations, more reform-based schooling leads to less opposition to overseas commerce.

Finally, to further assess the mechanism underlying the effect of secondary education, I use a new cross-national data set on the politicization of education and the content of teaching curricula. Constructing cohort-specific measures of pluralism, patriotism, and nationalism in the curricula, I find that the effect of schooling is strongly moderated by the extent to which cosmopolitan worldviews are embedded in education. Individuals who acquire more pluralistic education grow significantly more supportive of trade, but the treatment effect is significantly weaker in cohorts exposed to more patriotic or nationalist education. The strength and consistency of these empirical results suggest that individuals with more education tend to assess international trade more positively, primarily due to their stronger consmopolitanism, even when there is no significant change in the distributional consequences of trade for their own economic standing.

The findings contribute to research on the political economy of international integration. This literature has long been occupied with the interpretation of the robust and strong association between formal education and support for trade and its implications for the broader question of what explains variation in mass opinion on trade. Yet both data and design limitations have left important uncertainties about the question of causality. By leveraging compulsory-schooling reforms in a fuzzy RD design, the analysis presented here makes headway in identifying the causal effect of education on support for trade. Moreover, the study advances this body of research by employing new data on the content of school curricula individuals were exposed to as youngsters. Coupled with the exogenous variation in schooling based on the implementation of compulsory-education reforms, these novel data and measures offer a means to assess how the quantity and quality of formal education interact in shaping public attitudes. Consequently, the analysis provides direct evidence on the causal mechanism underlying the effect of education, elucidating specific components in education that are particularly important in driving popular support for trade liberalization.

Beyond international political economy, the study's findings resonate with a growing literature that has conceptualized or employed a normative approach to explain or criticize cosmopolitanism as an educational response to the challenges of globalization.Footnote 12 I provide empirical evidence that this educational strategy is not only a response to globalization but also a source of popular support for economic integration. The research note also connects the international political economy and political socialization literatures by focusing on the effect of secondary, pre-adult education on attitudes toward international economic policy.Footnote 13 Previous studies mainly focused on college education and portrayed it as the key line dividing losers and winners, as well as opponents and proponents, of globalization. The new findings demonstrate that secondary education also affects public support for trade liberalization, and they shed light on the enduring consequences of adolescent socialization in school for economic policy preferences and how citizens think about globalization more broadly.

Why Do the Educated Support Economic Globalization?

Theories based on material self-interest suggest that those who benefit from international trade support trade liberalization, and those who lose from its economic implications support protectionism. In this view, education promotes pro-trade attitudes primarily by improving individuals’ labor-market standing or by changing the trade-related circumstances workers are exposed to in their specific industry or occupation.

The economic-self-interest approach can be divided into three more specific models. The Heckscher–Ohlin or factor proportions model assumes that factors of production are mobile across sectors, and predicts that trade liberalization will benefit owners of factors of production that are abundant relative to the rest of the world. In developed economies such as the ones included in the sample of countries I study here, highly skilled workers will therefore be the primary distributional winners from trade liberalization.

The Ricardo–Viner or specific factors model assumes that workers cannot easily move from one sector to another. This assumption implies that, at least in the short term, the primary losers from overseas commerce in developed economies would be workers in import-competing industries—primarily in manufacturing.Footnote 14 A third, material-based model is centered on the extent to which workers’ occupations are offshorable (can be outsourced to another country).Footnote 15 In developed countries, low-to-medium-skilled workers in routine-task-intensive occupations are vulnerable to offshoring and job displacement from international economic integration.Footnote 16

The observable implications of these material-based models are that education might affect trade preferences by reducing employment in low-skilled jobs, import-competing sectors, or offshorable and routine-task-intensive occupations, respectively. Also, education is expected to increase support for trade among individuals currently in the active labor force, and primarily among those in offshorable occupations.

Rather than changing economic circumstances and interests, an alternative, cultural explanation sees education primarily as a socializing agent that shapes attitudes, norms, and perceptions. According to this perspective, education fosters cultural openness and a cosmopolitan worldview, promotes humanitarian values, and gives people the capacity to override anti-foreigner sentiments and ethnocentrism.Footnote 17 Since international economic integration exposes countries to various foreign cultures, arts, people, goods, and firms, such cultural dispositions play a key role in shaping individuals’ responses to economic globalization. Many people do not disentangle the broad and complex effects of globalization and separately assess the material effects of trade. Instead, they often view the material effects of trade liberalization as part of an “openness package,” which also includes the nonmaterial aspects of globalization.Footnote 18 In surveys across the world, people say they are worried about the proliferation of foreign fast-food chains, music, and fashion trends, and about exposure to foreign goods eroding traditional values, cultural customs, and national uniqueness.Footnote 19 To the extent that a cosmopolitan view of the world reduces such cultural concerns, it should also increase popular support for international trade.

Moreover, according to theories of pre-adult socialization, exposure to civic values and democratic norms in secondary school, when individuals are more malleable, should have a particularly profound and long-lasting impact on political attitudes and policy preferences.Footnote 20 After this critical period of openness, political attitudes remain relatively stable and resistant to change even in the face of meaningful events.

Beyond its effect on trade preferences, the first observable implication of this cultural mechanism is that education will also increase tolerance of various foreign influences, such as films, books, and artworks. The second implication is that the effect of education will be moderated by the content of the curricula students are exposed to. Specifically, the effect of education on pro-trade attitudes should be stronger when curricula more strongly emphasize liberal-democratic norms such as tolerance and pluralism, and weaker when they more strongly promote the values of patriotism and nationalism.

Finally, economic knowledge of the virtues of trade openness might also be a key influence.Footnote 21 However, since most students are not exposed to such economic knowledge before college—and even then, only when taking an economics class or related courses in the social sciences—this mechanism should be largely muted in this study, which focuses on the effect of secondary education.Footnote 22 Instead, secondary education can develop students’ professional skills through either vocational or general programs. Vocational programs prepare students to work in specific occupations by providing specific job-related skills. General programs develop broader knowledge and cognitive skills like numeracy, literacy, and abstract thinking, which are also useful for further skill acquisition through on-the-job learning and training.Footnote 23 Secondary schools can also develop an orientation of openness to foreign cultures through the study of foreign languages, civics, history, and social studies. Indeed, since World War II, cosmopolitan perspectives have been developed in the philosophy of education, effectively promoting a vision of the world that sees all humanity as belonging to the same community.Footnote 24 Table E-1 (in the online supplement) summarizes these competing theories of the effect of education on trade preferences.

Research Design

To identify the causal effect of education on public support for international trade, I leverage compulsory-education reforms in eighteen countries as a source of exogenous variation. This setup creates a rare opportunity to isolate the effect of education from the nonrandom selection of individuals into education.

Data

I use repeated cross-sectional surveys from the ISSP's National Identity modules of 1995, 2003, and 2013.Footnote 25 Using various single- and multi-country reports and studies on compulsory-education reforms, I assemble a data set on eighteen countries that implemented twenty such reforms since World War II and participated in at least two of the three relevant waves of the ISSP (Table 1). For the main sources used to code the reforms, and more details on each reform, see Section A of the online supplement.

Table 1. Compulsory-education reforms

Notes: For respondents living in Scotland, the pivotal cohort in UK's 1972 reform is 1959. In Germany, 1954 is the pivotal cohort in four states: Nordrhein-Westphalia, Hessen, Rheinland-Pfalz, and Baden-Wurtenberg. Respondents living elsewhere are treated based on their state-specific year of reform. In Sweden, the reform was implemented gradually across municipalities, I follow Mocan and Pogorelova Reference Mocan and Pogorelova2017 and code respondents born in 1952 as the first fully affected cohort.

I follow Cavaille and Marshall and measure schooling as the number of completed years of education, with a limit of thirteen, since the reforms did not affect postsecondary education.Footnote 26 In some specifications, I also use the variable compulsory education, which is coded 1 if the respondent had completed the years of schooling eventually required by law following the reform, and 0 otherwise.

The key dependent variable measures support for international trade. Respondents were asked whether they agreed or disagreed that their country should limit the import of foreign products to protect its national economy (using a scale from 1 to 5). In the main analysis, I use a pro-trade dummy variable that is coded 1 for individuals who disagree with the statement, and 0 otherwise. In section D of the online supplement, I show that using the original five-point measure does not change the results.

Another set of variables I use to test the observable implications of competing explanations of the effect of education are related to respondents’ occupation and cultural protectionism. To sort respondents by their professional skills, I rely on Oesch's classification of four-digit International Standard Classification of Occupations (ISCO-08) codes.Footnote 27 High-skilled is a dummy variable for respondents in highly skilled occupations, including higher-grade managers, skilled service or manual workers, sociocultural professionals, and technical experts. Occupation-specific measures of working in manufacturing, job routineness, and offshorability are taken from Owen and Johnston and are based on their classification of industry occupation shares, a routine-task-intensity index, and an index of offshorability, respectively.Footnote 28 Owen and Johnston provide binary indicators for occupational offshorability and manufacturing occupations. I also construct a variable for offshorable routine-task-intensive occupation by interacting the offshorability indicator and the continuous routine-task-intensity index. Respondents in non-offshorable occupations get a score of 0 on this measure, while individuals working in offshorable occupations are rated according to their occupation's routine-task-intensity index, where higher values indicate that occupations are more intensive in routine tasks.

As for cultural openness, the ISSP collected data on respondents’ agreement or disagreement (on a scale from 1 to 5) with two items: cultural protectionism, measured by “[Country's] television should give preference to [Country] films and programmes” and available in all three waves; and cultural threat, measured by “Increased exposure to foreign films, music and books is damaging our national and local cultures” and available only in the 2003 wave. These measures capture an important part of the theoretical concept of cultural openness without explicitly mentioning the economic aspects of globalization.

Finally, I use a new global data set on the politicization of education: Varieties of Indoctrination (V-Indoc).Footnote 29 It covers 160 countries since World War II (1945–2021) and draws on information provided by 760 country experts about indoctrination in education and the content of school curricula. Neundorf and colleagues show that V-Indoc measures have high face, convergent, and construct validity.Footnote 30 For each item, the experts were asked a question about the content of school curricula, followed by a clarification with specific examples. Responses to each country-year observation were provided by multiple country experts on an ordinal scale.Footnote 31 V-Indoc uses a measurement model that aggregates the multiple ratings, takes disagreement and measurement error into account, and produces a probability distribution over country-year scores on a standardized interval scale that typically varies between –5 and 5, with 0 approximately representing the sample mean.Footnote 32 The point estimates are the median values of these distributions for each country-year.

I use three V-Indoc variables. Pluralism in the curriculum measures the extent to which students are exposed to diverse views and interpretations when historical events are taught. Patriotic education in the curriculum measures the extent to which the language-studies curriculum promotes feelings of love, pride, loyalty, and commitment to one's country. And Nationalist ideology character in the curriculum captures the degree to which nationalism is promoted by the history curriculum as the dominant societal model or ideology. Detailed information on these measures is provided in section B of the online supplement.

I use these country-year point estimates to calculate a series of birth-cohort-level measures, each of which is a twelve-year (ages six to eighteen in most countries) moving average of the relevant interval variable for each cohort. For example, for ISSP respondents who were born in 1945 in France, the cohort-level measure is the (standardized) mean value of the original V-Indoc variable from 1951 to 1963. These measures are meant to capture potential cohort-level exposure to values or knowledge ingrained in school curricula. Summary statistics for each measure are presented in Table A-2 in the online supplement.

Identification Strategy

To capture the causal effect of education on public support for international trade, I use a fuzzy RD design in which respondents just young enough to be included in the reforms are compared to respondents who are just too old to be included. Accordingly, respondents’ birth cohort relative to the year when the reform came into force is used as the running variable that determines assignment to the treatment. The cutoff point represents the first cohort to be affected.

Importantly, receiving the treatment—education—is not perfectly determined by the compulsory-schooling reforms. For various unobserved reasons, students can drop out early even after such laws are enacted, and they can decide to remain in school even when it is not required. Thus, compulsory-education reforms produce a fuzzy discontinuity in the treatment take-up: though the decision whether to remain in school is not perfectly determined by the reform, the probability of remaining in school still jumps due to the reform (Figure 1).Footnote 33 Accordingly, exposure to compulsory-education reforms is used as an instrumental variable (IV) that discontinuously increases the probability of receiving additional years of education.

Figure 1. Compulsory-schooling completion around education reforms

Like the sharp RD design, the fuzzy RD design relies on the assumption that individuals’ potential outcomes are continuous at the threshold.Footnote 34 This assumption would be violated if individuals (or their parents) were able to foresee the timing of the reform and precisely manipulate respondents’ year of birth accordingly, but this is highly implausible because it requires parents to know about those reforms years before they are even proposed. Around the cutoff, therefore, the variation in the treatment is as good as randomized: the pre-reform and post-reform cohorts should be comparable to each other in all relevant aspects, except for their exposure to the new legal requirements regarding compulsory education.Footnote 35

To validate the continuity assumption, I use density and balance tests. The density test indicates that respondents were not able to sort around the threshold (Figure A-4 in the online supplement). If respondents or their parents had precise control over their birth cohort, then an unusually large proportion of them should have been observed either below or above the threshold (depending on whether they perceive compulsory education positively or negatively). Instead, the manipulation test fails to reject the hypothesis that the density of the score changes discontinuously at the cutoff point. In addition, the control and treatment groups are similar across all pretreatment characteristics available in the ISSP data, consistent with the proposition that treatment assignment is as good as randomly assigned for sequential birth cohorts around the cutoff (Figure A-5).Footnote 36

I estimate local linear regressions using the optimal bandwidth recommended by Calonico, Cattaneo, and Titiunik.Footnote 37 This continuity-based RD framework focuses on the treatment effect at the cutoff. In other parts of the analysis, I use an IV design that estimates the treatment effect not at the cutoff but rather in a small window around it. To determine the size of this window, I use Cattaneo, Idrobo, and Titiunik's procedure, which considers a sequence of nested windows, starting with the smallest, and in each one conducts balance tests for each of the pretreatment covariates. The optimal window is the smallest window with covariate balance.Footnote 38

The IV estimation relies solely on the exogenous variation in education that comes from whether individuals’ birth cohort is included in or excluded from the schooling reform. Compulsory-education reforms can be viewed as an exogenous encouragement, where individuals just young enough to be included in the reform are “encouraged” to remain in school for several more years, while individuals just too old to be under the mandate of the new law are not.

The causal identification of the local average treatment effect—that is, the effect of education for compliers who remain in school only if required to do so by compulsory-education laws—requires two additional assumptions: monotonicity, which rules out the possibility that some students drop out if and only if they are subject to compulsory-education reforms; and exclusion restriction, by which the effect of the reforms on trade attitudes runs exclusively through the education treatment.Footnote 39 Both assumptions are plausible in this context: students are unlikely to respond to the reforms by completing less education, and the proximity of the reforms to students’ choice to stay in school or drop out early makes potential violations of the exclusion restrictions highly unlikely.Footnote 40

Education Increases Support for International Trade

Column 1 of Table 2 provides the first-stage estimate of the effect of compulsory-schooling reforms on completing compulsory education: a substantial 9.7 percentage-point increase. Similarly, compulsory-education reforms increase educational attainment by 0.31 schooling years, on average (column 2). The F-statistic for the relevance of the reform instrument for completing compulsory education (schooling years) is 270 (201), far past the conventional threshold of 10 and indicating a strong first stage.

Table 2. Effect of Secondary Education on Support for International Trade

Notes: Entries are local linear regression estimates with a triangular kernel using the Calonico, Cattaneo, and Titiunik Reference Calonico, Cattaneo and Titiunik2014 optimal bandwidth (±12 birth cohort years). The F-statistic is drawn from a baseline first-stage regression. Pre-treatment covariates include respondents’ sex, ethnicity, and parents’ immigrant status. Robust standard errors in parentheses, clustered by subnational region. ITT = intention to treat. LATE = local average treatment effect. *p < .05; **p < .01.

Column 3 shows the reduced-form or intention-to-treat estimate: exposure to the compulsory-schooling reforms caused an average increase in support for international trade of three percentage points, even before accounting for imperfect compliance. Since 21 percent of the pre-reform cohorts take a pro-trade stance, this estimate implies that affected cohorts are over 14 percent more supportive of trade due to the implementation of compulsory-education reforms.

Yet the intention-to-treat effect underestimates the actual effect of education. Many students are always-takers who acquire the compulsory level of education regardless of whether they are required by law to do so. And a few are never-takers who drop out early either way. In column 4, I correct for this noncompliance by scaling the intention-to-treat effect by the compliance ratio. The local average treatment effect is substantial, increasing support for overseas commerce by thirty-two percentage points.

Marshall shows that coarsening a multivalued treatment (for example, treating a continuous endogenous variable as binary) can upwardly bias IV estimates. Conversely, when the treatment is coded as a multivalued variable, the IV estimation produces a consistent causal estimate.Footnote 41 Column 5 addresses this concern by using the multivalued schooling variable. The effect of education remains large: one additional reform-induced year of education increases support for overseas commerce by ten percentage points.

Here and in section D of the online supplement, I present additional checks that underscore the robustness of these findings. First, the results are statistically similar when I use a local-randomization RD approach—that is, estimating the effect of the reform-induced schooling not at the cutoff but in a neighborhood around the cutoff (Figure 2). This analysis also further demonstrates that pre-adult education has a long-lasting impact on how people think of economic globalization, as the three percentage-point treatment effect (or 14 percent above the baseline rate of support) is stable across all three survey waves, which span over two decades.

Figure 2. Effect of education across survey waves

A second set of tests shows the results from IV models on either a subset of near-cutoff observations within the optimal window of ±11 birth cohort years or any other window between ±1 and ±20 cohorts (Figure A-7 in the online supplement). Not only are the point estimates remarkably stable across bandwidths, their precision remains high even at the smaller bandwidths, with fewer observations than optimal. Third, the results (in Figure A-7) remain similar in a minimal specification without controlling for covariates, which corroborates the identification strategy and suggests that, as in a randomized experiment, the covariates are controlled for by design. Fourth, using a higher-order polynomial yields similar estimates of the effect of reform-induced education (Table A-6). Fifth, the results are robust to leaving out of the analysis any of the eighteen countries originally included (Figure A-8). Finally, I conduct placebo cutoff tests and find no significant change around placebo reforms either before or after the timing of real reforms (Table A-5).

Overall, in contrast to the view that education is merely a proxy for various personality traits and socioeconomic or cultural characteristics, we see that education has a sizable causal effect on support for international economic integration. Compared to individuals from cohorts unaffected by the new compulsory-education reform, otherwise similar individuals from affected cohorts became considerably more supportive of economic globalization. Not only is this attitudinal difference significant and substantively meaningful, it lasts decades after students have finished their school years and reached adulthood.

Education, Economic Circumstances, and Cultural Threat

Why does secondary education increase public support for trade openness? As outlined in the theory section, two competing but not mutually exclusive explanations are material self-interest and cultural openness. According to the former, education shapes individuals’ economic interests by affecting their position in the labor market and improving their employment and wage prospects in the global economy—making them more highly skilled workers, less likely to work in import-competing industries, and less vulnerable to offshoring. According to the latter, education reduces the perceived cultural threat of globalization by fostering a cosmopolitan view of the world and tolerance of foreign cultures and lifestyles.

The results provide little evidence for the material-self-interest account (Table 3). Specifically, the added, reform-induced years of education did not significantly change the probability that respondents would find employment in high-skilled jobs, in the manufacturing sector, or in offshorable routine-task-intensive occupations. Of course, exposure to offshoring or import competition might generally account for some of the variation in public support for trade more broadly,Footnote 42 but I find no evidence that they could have more specifically generated the effect of education on support for trade.Footnote 43

Table 3. Compulsory education, economic outcomes, and cultural protectionism

Notes: Entries are IV estimates with robust standard errors in parentheses, using the ±11 optimal bandwidth. Data on cultural threat are available only in the 2003 ISSP wave. RTI = routine-task-intensity. *p < .05; **p < .01.

Importantly, the limited overall support for the material-based explanations does not seem to be the result of a weak treatment in terms of labor-market outcomes and income mobility. Treated individuals were able to take advantage of their extra schooling years and find better-paying jobs (column 5). One additional year of schooling increased respondents’ position on their countries’ income distribution by more than half a decile. However, these better-paying jobs seem to be mostly within respondents’ broader level of skill, and they did not reduce individuals’ exposure to import competition or offshoring. In other words, while education significantly affected workers’ economic fortunes, it did not dramatically change their potential benefits from, and material self-interest in regard to, international trade and globalization.

In contrast, education had a large effect on cultural protectionism (last two columns of Table 3). Specifically, one additional year of schooling decreased individuals’ support for giving preference to national films and programs in their country's television by ten percentage points. It also decreased individuals’ belief that exposure to foreign films, music, and books is damaging their national and local cultures by nine points. Taken together, these findings suggest that in the eighteen countries surveyed here, education strongly reduced perceived cultural threat from globalization, while its potential to change economic interests was limited.

An important limitation in exploring the mechanisms of the effect of education is that most individual characteristics, such as employment status, income, occupation, or partisanship, are post-treatment variables that may themselves be affected by pre-adult exposure to education. Controlling for these post-treatment variables or subsetting the data based on them may introduce severe bias, because estimating the treatment effect “holding all other variables constant” becomes impossible.Footnote 44 That said, it is worth subsetting the data based on employment status to test one important observable implication of the material-based account. If education increases support for trade because it shapes workers’ expectations about the impact of international trade on their real wages, then the pro-trade effect of education should be large and significant among respondents who either actively participate in the labor market or work in offshorable occupations, but much weaker among their counterparts.Footnote 45

I find that more years of education, induced by the compulsory-schooling reforms, increase public support for international trade regardless of whether respondents are currently in paid work, working in the manufacturing sector, or in offshorable occupations (Figure 3). Despite the stark differences in exposure to trade shocks or vulnerability to offshoring across these groups of respondents, and in their material self-interests derived from these different circumstances, the impact of education on how individuals think about international economic integration remains statistically and substantively similar across all subsamples. While these results should be taken with caution given the mentioned potential post-treatment bias, they provide no evidence that the effect of education on trade is driven by material circumstances or self-interest.

Figure 3. Effect of years of schooling, by labor-market characteristics

The Effect of Education by Curriculum Content

Another way to assess the mechanisms of the effect of education on pro-trade preferences is to examine how the treatment effect interacts with the curriculum content individuals were exposed to as students. Previous research was unable to do this due to data availability limitations. Here, I use V-Indoc, a new cross-national data set on indoctrination in education and school curricula since 1945.Footnote 46

In Figure 4, I create subsamples of the full ISSP sample, dividing respondents by the median value of three curriculum measures: pluralism, nationalism, and patriotism. Comparing the results across the three subsamples, I find a significant, systematic difference in the estimated effects of education on pro-trade preferences. One more year of schooling, induced by the compulsory-schooling reforms, increases support for trade by nearly six percentage points (p < 0.001) for respondents from cohorts exposed to more pluralism in education, while this effect is only 0.5 points (p < 0.59) among those exposed to less pluralism. The difference between the two effects is statistically significant (p < 0.01). Similarly, another year of schooling for respondents from cohorts exposed to less nationalism as a dominant societal model in the school curriculum brings about a 4.6-point (p < 0.001) increase in support for trade, while the effect is smaller than 0.1 points for those exposed to more nationalism; and the difference between these two effects is also statistically significant (p < 0.01). The differential effect of schooling across exposure to different levels of patriotism in the curriculum is more subtle, but is also statistically significant (p < 0.01).

Figure 4. Effect of years of schooling, by the content of education

Thus, the extent to which the curriculum promotes and celebrates feelings of love, pride, and loyalty toward the nation, and the extent to which it exposes students to diverse views of the world and alternative interpretations of history, clearly and durably matter to the formation of citizens’ attitudes toward international trade and globalization. The findings also highlight the significance of secondary education and the role of the state in shaping citizens’ political attitudes. Compared to universities, secondary schools offer governments not only broader access to the population but also greater influence over the content of education, which may be used for either patriotic or democratic indoctrination purposes.

In section D.8 of the online supplement, I present robustness tests that use a different coding of the treatment or a different threshold for splitting the sample based on the school curriculum measures. The results are robust to these different coding decisions and alternative measures. Furthermore, interacting schooling and continuous measures of school curricula using the full sample yields similar results (Table A-9). This analysis also demonstrates that a more intense focus on subjects related to the development of labor-market skills does little to change the pro-trade effect of schooling.Footnote 47

Taken together, the findings show that education—even at the secondary level—durably increases public support for international trade. Material circumstances and interests play little role in driving this effect. Instead, the evidence is very much consistent with the argument that education heightens public support for international trade by instilling tolerance and pluralism in students and reducing perceived cultural threat from economic globalization.Footnote 48

Discussion

Education has emerged as one of the clearest lines dividing supporters and opponents of globalization and international trade.Footnote 49 However, whether this robust correlation stems from nonrandom selection of individuals into education or represents a causal effect of education itself has yet to be established. This research note presents the first evidence of a causal effect of education on public support for trade liberalization. I find that more years of education, instrumented by compulsory-schooling reforms, brings about a sizable and long-lasting rise in public support for international trade. Several decades after these reforms came into force, treated individuals were still not only significantly more supportive of free trade but also markedly more tolerant of foreign cultures and influences. Furthermore, the effect is most pronounced when individuals are exposed to more pluralistic and less nationalist education. In contrast, I find that neither the extent to which school curricula focus on professional skill-building subjects nor the vulnerability of individuals to the distributional consequences of trade later in life moderate the effect. These patterns are most consistent with a cultural channel through which education fosters a cosmopolitan outlook and reduces the perceived cultural threat of economic globalization.

In evaluating these findings, several issues must be considered. First, although I find that the effect of secondary education primarily operates through a cultural channel, other explanations I have mentioned, including material self-interest and economic knowledge, might still account for the effect of college education, as well as other determinants of public opposition to trade.Footnote 50 Second, while the compulsory-education reforms studied here successfully increased levels of education, they have not transformed globalization losers into winners. Instead, the economic profile of treated individuals remained similar in terms of employment in low-skilled jobs, import-competing sectors, and offshorable occupations. The balance in these labor-market circumstances provides a rare opportunity to isolate the often-overlapping economic and cultural mechanisms underlying the effect of education on public support for international trade. However, this also leaves an open question about the role of economic factors—and their interaction with non-material factorsFootnote 51—in cases where education substantially improves labor-market circumstances, a question future research should seek to answer.

Although the evidence is mixed, several studies find that education correlates with support for trade in skill-abundant countries, and opposition to trade in skill-scarce ones, in line with the factor-endowment model.Footnote 52 While relative factor endowment might be important, this study raises an additional possibility: low-income, skill-scarce countries, often governed by autocratic regimes, may use patriotic indoctrination in education to a much larger degree than skill-abundant countries, which are more likely to be consolidated democracies.Footnote 53 Understanding these dynamics is a promising avenue for future research.

From a policy perspective, these findings speak to a growing trend in cases where right-wing populist parties and leaders have come to power. After World War II, nation-states increasingly incorporated a global perspective into their educational curricula.Footnote 54 More recently, however, right-wing populist parties, as well as conservative lawmakers, have increasingly attempted to change teaching curricula, textbooks, and education practices in several countries, with varying success.Footnote 55 The evidence presented here suggests that making school curricula more nationalist and less pluralistic might plant the seeds for an even stronger protectionist shift by the next generation of political leaders and supported by a broader coalition of antiglobalization voters. While voters sometimes punish incumbent leaders for promoting protectionist policies,Footnote 56 the gradual, slowly evolving nature of potential protectionist shifts driven by education reforms and generational replacement is likely to be more hidden from the public eye and less susceptible to democratic accountability.

Data Availability Statement

Replication files for this research note may be found at <https://dataverse.harvard.edu/dataset.xhtml?persistentId=doi:10.7910/DVN/AMEPS5&faces-redirect=true>.

Supplementary Material

Supplementary material for this research note is available at <https://doi.org/10.1017/S0020818324000262>.

Acknowledgments

I am grateful for valuable comments and suggestions from Yotam Margalit, Gary Winslett, the reviewers and editors of IO, and participants in the 2024 annual convention of the International Studies Association. Any errors remain my own.

Funding

I thank the Israel Science Foundation (grant no. 929/24) for support for this research.

Footnotes

1. Hegre, Oneal, and Russett Reference Hegre, Oneal and Russett2010; Helpman Reference Helpman2009; Wacziarg and Welch Reference Wacziarg and Welch2008.

3. Colantone, Ottaviano, and Stanig Reference Colantone, Ottaviano, Stanig, Gopinath, Helpman and Rogoff2022. The number of new protectionist measures announced by G20 economies has risen steadily since the 2007–08 financial crisis (Evenett and Fritz Reference Evenett and Fritz2019). Not all of them are “headline-attracting across-the-board” increases in tariff rates (Evenett Reference Evenett2011, 44).

4. Margalit, Raviv, and Solodoch, Reference Margalit, Raviv and Solodochforthcoming; Rooduijn and Burgoon Reference Rooduijn and Burgoon2018; Swank and Betz Reference Swank and Betz2003.

5. Baker Reference Baker2003; Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006; Kaltenthaler, Gelleny, and Ceccoli Reference Kaltenthaler, Gelleny and Ceccoli2004; Mansfield and Mutz Reference Mansfield and Mutz2009; Margalit Reference Margalit2012.

6. Mayda and Rodrik Reference Mayda and Rodrik2005; O'Rourke and Sinnott Reference O'Rourke and Sinnott2001; Scheve and Slaughter Reference Scheve and Slaughter2001.

9. Foley, Gallipoli, and Green Reference Foley, Gallipoli and Green2014; Tyler, Murnane, and Willett Reference Tyler, Murnane and Willett1999.

11. Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006. However, this does not mean that economic ideas and knowledge are not an important factor in and of itself or a key mechanism underlying the effect of college education on support for trade.

13. Alwin and Krosnick Reference Alwin and Krosnick1991; Osborne, Sears, and Valentino Reference Osborne, Sears and Valentino2011.

15. Owen and Johnston Reference Owen and Johnston2017.

16. Acemoglu and Autor Reference Acemoglu and Autor2011.

19. Gordon and Meunier Reference Gordon and Meunier2001; Kohut and Wike Reference Kohut and Wike2008.

20. Osborne, Sears, and Valentino Reference Osborne, Sears and Valentino2011; Willeck and Mendelberg Reference Willeck and Mendelberg2022. For example, Rekker et al. Reference Rekker, Keijsers, Branje and Meeus2017 show that voters acquire core cultural attitudes during adolescence, rather than early adulthood.

21. Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006.

22. Section E of the online supplement addresses the low prevalence of economic education in secondary schools.

25. ISSP 2020.

26. Cavaille and Marshall Reference Cavaille and Marshall2019. Table A-3 shows that the reforms did not affect postsecondary education. Section D.6 of the online supplement shows that the effect of education on trade preferences is robust to using various alternative measures of schooling.

28. Owen and Johnston Reference Owen and Johnston2017; see also Autor and Dorn Reference Autor and Dorn2013; Blinder et al. Reference Blinder2009; Goos, Manning, and Salomons Reference Goos, Manning and Salomons2014.

31. 93–96% of country-year observations are based on at least two coders, depending on the specific measure, with a median of six coders per observation. Using multiple experts per country minimizes bias in expert-coded data.

33. Figure A-3 shows the first-stage effect for each reform separately.

35. Lee and Lemieux Reference Lee and Lemieux2010.

36. The fact that respondents are exposed to the treatment as youngsters leaves only a few pretreatment covariates—those that are determined at respondents’ birth or before that.

37. Calonico, Cattaneo, and Titiunik Reference Calonico, Cattaneo and Titiunik2014.

38. Cattaneo, Idrobo, and Titiunik Reference Cattaneo, Idrobo and Titiunik2023.

39. Angrist, Imbens, and Rubin Reference Angrist, Imbens and Rubin1996.

42. Owen and Johnston Reference Owen and Johnston2017.

43. The effect of education on support for trade remains statistically and substantively similar after removing respondents who could be exposed to economic knowledge about the virtues of international trade in secondary school (see Section E in the online appendix).

44. King and Zeng Reference King and Zeng2007; Montgomery, Nyhan, and Torres Reference Montgomery, Nyhan and Torres2018.

45. Hainmueller and Hiscox Reference Hainmueller and Hiscox2006; Owen and Johnston Reference Owen and Johnston2017.

47. The effect of education on support for trade is also similar across cohorts with different levels of de facto education quality and achievements in math, reading, and science (Table A-10).

50. Owen and Johnston Reference Owen and Johnston2017; Rho and Tomz Reference Rho and Tomz2017.

51. Baccini and Weymouth Reference Baccini and Weymouth2021; Bisbee and Rosendorff, Reference Bisbee and Peter Rosendorffforthcoming; Hopkins, Margalit, and Solodoch Reference Hopkins, Margalit and Solodoch2024.

52. Dolan and Milner Reference Dolan and Milner2023; Mayda and Rodrik Reference Mayda and Rodrik2005.

53. See Neundorf et al. Reference Neundorf, Nazrullaeva, Northmore-Ball, Tertytchnaya and Kim2024 on the relationship between regime type and patriotic indoctrination.

55. Berg, Jungblut, and Jupskås Reference Berg, Jungblut and Jupskås2023; Norris Reference Norris2023. For example, the 2016 Polish education reform introduced new, more conservative-nationalist history and language curricula. Neumann and Rudnicki Reference Neumann and Rudnicki2023; Wiśniewski and Zahorska Reference Wiśniewski, Zahorska and Reimers2020.

56. Chyzh and Urbatsch Reference Chyzh and Urbatsch2021; Kim and Margalit Reference Kim and Margalit2021; Mansfield and Solodoch Reference Mansfield and Solodoch2024.

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Autor, David. 2011. Chapter 12—Skills, Tasks and Technologies: Implications for Employment and Earnings. In Handbook of Labor Economics, edited by David Card and Orley Ashenfelter, 4:1043–1171. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, Daron, Autor, David, Dorn, David, Hanson, Gordon H., and Price, Brendan. 2016. Import Competition and the Great US Employment Sag of the 2000s. Journal of Labor Economics 34 (S1): S141S198.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Agnew, Melanie, and Fox, Robin. 2014. The Role of Education in a Globalized World: Internationalizing the Curriculum. Journal of Emerging Trends in Educational Research and Policy Studies 5 (8):134–37.Google Scholar
Alwin, Duane F., and Krosnick, Jon A.. 1991. Aging, Cohorts, and the Stability of Sociopolitical Orientations over the Life Span. American Journal of Sociology 97 (1):169–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angrist, Joshua D., Imbens, Guido W., and Rubin, Donald B.. 1996. Identification of Causal Effects Using Instrumental Variables. Journal of the American Statistical Association 91 (434):444–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Autor, David H., and Dorn, David. 2013. The Growth of Low-Skill Service Jobs and the Polarization of the US Labor Market. American Economic Review 103 (5):1553–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baccini, Leonardo, and Weymouth, Stephen. 2021. Gone for Good: Deindustrialization, White Voter Backlash, and US Presidential Voting. American Political Science Review 115 (2):550–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baker, Andy. 2003. Why Is Trade Reform So Popular in Latin America? A Consumption-Based Theory of Trade Policy Preferences. World Politics 55 (3):423–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berg, Anne Espeland, Jungblut, Jens, and Jupskås, Anders Ravik. 2023. We Don't Need No Education? Education Policies of Western European Populist Radical Right Parties. West European Politics 46 (7):13121342.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bisbee, James, and Peter Rosendorff, B.. Forthcoming. Antiglobalization Sentiment: Exposure and Immobility. American Journal of Political Science. <https://doi.org/https://doi.org/10.1111/ajps.12872>.Google Scholar
Blinder, Alan S. 2009. How Many US Jobs Might be Offshorable? World Economics 10 (2):41–78.Google Scholar
Bromley, Patricia. 2009. Cosmopolitanism in Civic Education: Exploring Cross-National Trends, 1970-2008. Current Issues in Comparative Education 12 (1):3344.Google Scholar
Buckner, Elizabeth, and Russell, Susan Garnett. 2013. Portraying the Global: Cross-National Trends in Textbooks’ Portrayal of Globalization and Global Citizenship. International Studies Quarterly 57 (4):738–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Calonico, Sebastian, Cattaneo, Matias D., and Titiunik, Rocio. 2014. Robust Data-Driven Inference in the Regression-Discontinuity Design. Stata Journal 14 (4):909946.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cattaneo, Matias D., Idrobo, Nicolás, and Titiunik, Rocio. 2023. A Practical Introduction to Regression Discontinuity Designs: Extensions. ArXiv preprint 2301.08958.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cavaille, Charlotte, and Marshall, John. 2019. Education and Anti-immigration Attitudes: Evidence from Compulsory Schooling Reforms Across Western Europe. American Political Science Review 113 (1):254–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chyzh, Olga V., and Urbatsch, Robert. 2021. Bean Counters: The Effect of Soy Tariffs on Change in Republican Vote Share Between the 2016 and 2018 Elections. Journal of Politics 83 (1):415–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Colantone, Italo, Ottaviano, Gianmarco, and Stanig, Piero. 2022. Chapter 7—The Backlash of Globalization. In Handbook of International Economics: International Trade, Volume 5, edited by Gopinath, Gita, Helpman, Elhanan, and Rogoff, Kenneth, 405477. Elsevier.Google Scholar
Dolan, Lindsay R., and Milner, Helen V.. 2023. Low-Skilled Liberalizers: Support for Free Trade in Africa. International Organization 77 (4):848–70.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Evenett, Simon J. 2011. Trade Tensions Mount: The 10th GTA Report. Centre for Economic Policy Research.Google Scholar
Evenett, Simon, and Fritz, Johannes. 2019. Going It Alone? Trade Policy After Three Years of Populism. 25th Global Trade Alert Report. CEPR Press.Google Scholar
Foley, Kelly, Gallipoli, Giovanni, and Green, David A.. 2014. Ability, Parental Valuation of Education, and the High School Dropout Decision. Journal of Human Resources 49 (4):906–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Furnham, Adrian, and Chamorro-Premuzic, Tomas. 2006. Personality, Intelligence and General Knowledge. Learning and Individual Differences 16 (1):7990.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., Huber, Gregory A., Doherty, David, Dowling, Conor M., and Ha, Shang E.. 2010. Personality and Political Attitudes: Relationships Across Issue Domains and Political Contexts. American Political Science Review 104 (1):111–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Goos, Maarten, Manning, Alan, and Salomons, Anna. 2014. Explaining Job Polarization: Routine-Biased Technological Change and Offshoring. American Economic Review 104 (8):25092526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Philip H., and Meunier, Sophie. 2001. Globalization and French Cultural Identity. French Politics, Culture and Society 19 (1):2241.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hahn, Jinyong, Todd, Petra, and van der Klauuw, Wilbert. 2001. Identification and Estimation of Treatment Effects with a Regression-Discontinuity Design. Econometrica 69 (1):201–09.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hainmueller, Jens, and Hiscox, Michael J.. 2006. Learning to Love Globalization: Education and Individual Attitudes Toward International Trade. International Organization 60 (2):469–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hanushek, Eric A., Schwerdt, Guido, Woessmann, Ludger, and Zhang, Lei. 2017. General Education, Vocational Education, and Labor-Market Outcomes over the Lifecycle. Journal of Human Resources 52 (1):4887.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hegre, Håvard, Oneal, John R., and Russett, Bruce. 2010. Trade Does Promote Peace: New Simultaneous Estimates of the Reciprocal Effects of Rrade and Conflict. Journal of Peace Research 47 (6):763–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Helpman, Elhanan. 2009. The Mystery of Economic Growth. Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hopkins, Daniel J., Margalit, Yotam, and Solodoch, Omer. 2024. Personal Economic Shocks and Public Opposition to Unauthorized Immigration. British Journal of Political Science 54 (3):928–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hyman, Herbert H., and Wright, Charles R.. 1979. Education's Lasting Influence on Values. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Igarashi, Hiroki, and Saito, Hiro. 2014. Cosmopolitanism as Cultural Capital: Exploring the Intersection of Globalization, Education and Stratification. Cultural Sociology 8 (3):222–39.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
ISSP. 2020. International Social Survey Programme: National Identity I-III: ISSP 1995-2003-2013. GESIS Data Archive, Cologne. ZA5960 Data File Version 1.0.0. <https://doi.org/10.4232/1.13471>.CrossRef.>Google Scholar
Kaltenthaler, Karl C., Gelleny, Ronald D., and Ceccoli, Stephen J.. 2004. Explaining Citizen Support for Trade Liberalization. International Studies Quarterly 48 (4):829–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kam, Cindy D., and Palmer, Carl L.. 2008. Reconsidering the Effects of Education on Political Participation. Journal of Politics 70 (3):612–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, Sung Eun, and Margalit, Yotam. 2021. Tariffs as Electoral Weapons: The Political Geography of the US–China Trade War. International Organization 75 (1):138.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kinder, Donald R., and Kam, Cindy D.. 2010. Us Against Them: Ethnocentric Foundations of American Opinion. University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
King, Gary, and Zeng, Langche. 2007. When Can History Be Our Guide? The Pitfalls of Counterfactual Inference. International Studies Quarterly 51 (1):183210.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kohut, Andrew, and Wike, Richard. 2008. Assessing Globalization: Benefits and Drawbacks of Trade and Integration. Harvard International Review 30 (1):7074.Google Scholar
Lee, David S., and Lemieux, Thomas. 2010. Regression Discontinuity Designs in Economics. Journal of Economic Literature 48 (2):281355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipset, Seymour Martin. 1959. Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy. American Political Science Review 53 (1):69105.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Mutz, Diana C.. 2009. Support for Free Trade: Self-Interest, Sociotropic Politics, and Out-Group Anxiety. International Organization 63 (3):425–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mansfield, Edward D., and Solodoch, Omer. 2024. Political Costs of Trade War Tariffs. Journal of Politics 86 (3):10981103.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margalit, Yotam. 2012. Lost in Globalization: International Economic Integration and the Sources of Popular Discontent. International Studies Quarterly 56 (3):484500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Margalit, Yotam, Raviv, Shir, and Solodoch, Omer. Forthcoming. The Cultural Origins of Populism. Journal of Politics. <https://doi.org/10.1086/732985>.Google Scholar
Marshall, John. 2016a. Coarsening Bias: How Coarse Treatment Measurement Upwardly Biases Instrumental Variable Estimates. Political Analysis 24 (2):157–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, John. 2016b. Education and Voting Conservative: Evidence from a Major Schooling Reform in Great Britain. Journal of Politics 78 (2):382–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Matthews, Julie, and Sidhu, Ravinder. 2005. Desperately Seeking the Global Subject: International Education, Citizenship and Cosmopolitanism. Globalisation, Societies and Education 3 (1):4966.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayda, Anna Maria, and Rodrik, Dani. 2005. Why Are Some People (and Countries) More Protectionist than Others? European Economic Review 49 (6):13931430.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milner, Helen V. 2018. Globalization and Its Political Consequences: The Effects on Party Politics in the West. Annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Boston, August.Google Scholar
Mocan, Naci, and Pogorelova, Luiza. 2017. Compulsory Schooling Laws and Formation of Beliefs: Education, Religion and Superstition. Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 142:509539.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Montgomery, Jacob M., Nyhan, Brendan, and Torres, Michelle. 2018. How Conditioning on Posttreatment Variables Can Ruin Your Experiment and What to Do About It. American Journal of Political Science 62 (3):760–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neumann, Eszter, and Rudnicki, Paweł. 2023. Populist Radical-Right Governments in Central-Eastern Europe and Education Policy-Making: A Comparison of Hungary and Poland. Journal of Contemporary European Studies, 114. <https://doi.org/10.1080/14782804.2023.2211935>.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Neundorf, Anja, Nazrullaeva, Eugenia, Northmore-Ball, Ksenia, et al. 2023. Varieties of Political Indoctrination in Education and the Media (V-Indoc) Dataset V1. DEMED Project. <https://papers.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=4387521>.CrossRef.>Google Scholar
Neundorf, Anja, Nazrullaeva, Eugenia, Northmore-Ball, Ksenia, Tertytchnaya, Katerina, and Kim, Wooseok. 2024. Varieties of Indoctrination: The Politicization of Education and the Media Around the World. Perspectives on Politics 22 (3):771–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Norris, Pippa. 2023. Cancel Culture: Myth or Reality? Political Studies 71 (1):145–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Oesch, Daniel. 2006. Coming to Grips with a Changing Class Structure: An Analysis of Employment Stratification in Britain, Germany, Sweden and Switzerland. International Sociology 21 (2):263–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, Danny, Sears, David O., and Valentino, Nicholas A.. 2011. The End of the Solidly Democratic South: The Impressionable-Years Hypothesis. Political Psychology 32 (1):81108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Owen, Erica, and Johnston, Noel P.. 2017. Occupation and the Political Economy of Trade: Job Routineness, Offshorability, and Protectionist Sentiment. International Organization 71 (4):665–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pemstein, Daniel, Marquardt, Kyle L., Tzelgov, Eitan, Wang, Yi-ting, Krusell, Joshua, and Miri, Farhad. 2018. The V-Dem Measurement Model: Latent Variable Analysis for Cross-National and Cross-Temporal Expert-Coded Data. V-Dem Working Paper 21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rekker, Roderik, Keijsers, Loes, Branje, Susan, and Meeus, Wim. 2017. The Dynamics of Political Identity and Issue Attitudes in Adolescence and Early Adulthood. Electoral Studies 46:101111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rho, Sungmin, and Tomz, Michael. 2017. Why Don't Trade Preferences Reflect Economic Self-Interest? International Organization 71 (S1):S85S108.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rooduijn, Matthijs, and Burgoon, Brian. 2018. The Paradox of Well-Being: Do Unfavorable Socioeconomic and Sociocultural Contexts Deepen or Dampen Radical Left and Right Voting Among the Less Well-Off? Comparative Political Studies 51 (13):1720–53.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Scheve, Kenneth F., and Slaughter, Matthew J.. 2001. What Determines Individual Trade-Policy Preferences? Journal of International Economics 54 (2):267–92.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumann, Claudia. 2018. Cosmopolitanism and Globalization in Education. In International Handbook of Philosophy of Education, edited by Smeyers, Paul, 821–31. Springer International Handbooks of Education. Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Spence, Michael. 1978. Chapter 18 – Job Market Signaling. In Uncertainty in Economics, edited by Diamond, Peter and Rothschild, Michael, 281306. Academic Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swank, Duane, and Betz, Hans-Georg. 2003. Globalization, the Welfare State and Right-Wing Populism in Western Europe. Socio-Economic Review 1 (2):215–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tyler, John H., Murnane, Richard, and Willett, John B.. 1999. Do the Cognitive Skills of School Dropouts Matter in the Labor Market? Working paper WP7101, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vinokur, Eli. 2018. Cosmopolitan Education in Local Settings: Toward a New Civics Education for the 21st Century. Policy Futures in Education 16 (8):964–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wacziarg, Romain, and Welch, Karen Horn. 2008. Trade Liberalization and Growth: New Evidence. World Bank Economic Review 22 (2):187231.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walter, Stefanie. 2021. The Backlash Against Globalization. Annual Review of Political Science 24:421–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Willeck, Claire, and Mendelberg, Tali. 2022. Education and Political Participation. Annual Review of Political Science 25:89110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wiśniewski, Jerzy, and Zahorska, Marta. 2020. Reforming Education in Poland. In Audacious Education Purposes: How Governments Transform the Goals of Education Systems, edited by Reimers, Fernando M., 181208. Springer International.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Compulsory-education reforms

Figure 1

Figure 1. Compulsory-schooling completion around education reforms

Figure 2

Table 2. Effect of Secondary Education on Support for International Trade

Figure 3

Figure 2. Effect of education across survey waves

Figure 4

Table 3. Compulsory education, economic outcomes, and cultural protectionism

Figure 5

Figure 3. Effect of years of schooling, by labor-market characteristics

Figure 6

Figure 4. Effect of years of schooling, by the content of education

Supplementary material: File

Solodoch supplementary material

Solodoch supplementary material
Download Solodoch supplementary material(File)
File 1.3 MB