Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t8hqh Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T05:25:10.421Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

INCOME INEQUALITY, MOBILITY, AND THE ACCUMULATION OF CAPITAL

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  03 March 2014

Cecilia García-Peñalosa
Affiliation:
Aix-Marseille UniversityCNRS and EHESS
Stephen J. Turnovsky*
Affiliation:
University of Washington
*
Address correspondence to: Stephen Turnovsky, Department of Economics, University of Washington, Box 353330, Seattle, WA 98195, USA; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

We examine the determinants of income mobility and inequality in a Ramsey model with elastic labor supply and heterogeneous wealth and ability. Both agents with lower wealth and those with greater ability tend to supply more labor, implying that labor supply decisions may have an equalizing or unequalizing effect depending on the relative importance of the two sources of heterogeneity. Moreover, these decisions are central to the extent of mobility observed in an economy. The relationship between mobility and inequality is complex. For example, a reduction in the interest rate and an increase in the wage rate reduce capital income inequality and allow upward mobility of the ability-rich. However, the increase in the labor supply of high-ability agents in response to higher wages raises earnings dispersion and thus has an offsetting effect. As a result, high mobility can be associated with an increase or a decrease in overall income inequality.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2014 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Algan, Y., Cheron, A., Hairault, J-O., and Langot, F. (2003) Wealth effect on labor market transitions. Review of Economic Dynamics 6, 156178.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F. (1979) Decomposable income inequality measures. Econometrica 47, 901920.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burkhauser, R.V., Feng, S., Jenkins, S.P., and Larrimore, J. (2011) Estimating trends in US income inequality using the Current Population Survey: The importance of controlling for censoring. Journal of Economic Inequality 9, 393415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caselli, F. and Ventura, J. (2000) A representative consumer theory of distribution. American Economic Review 90, 909926.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castañeda, A., Díaz-Giménez, J., and Rios-Rull, V. (1998) Exploring the income distribution business cycle dynamics. Journal of Monetary Economics 42, 93130.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chamley, C. (1986) Optimal taxation of capital income in general equilibrium with infinite lives. Econometrica 54, 607622.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chatterjee, S. (1994) Transitional dynamics and the distribution of wealth in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Public Economics 54, 97119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Checchi, D., Ichino, A., and Rustichini, A. (1999) More equal but less mobile? Education financing and intergenerational mobility in Italy and in the US. Journal of Public Economics 74, 351393.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cheng, I-H. and French, E. (2000) The effect of the run-up in the stock market on labor supply. Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic Perspectives 24, 4865.Google Scholar
Cooley, T.F. (1995) Frontiers of Business Cycle Research. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coronado, J.L. and Perozek, M. (2003) Wealth Effects and the Consumption of Leisure: Retirement Decisions during the Stock Market Boom of the 1990s. Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System, Finance and Economics Discussion Series, 2003–20.Google Scholar
Díaz-Giménez, J., Glover, A., and Ríos-Rull, J.V. (2011) Facts on the distribution of earnings, income and wealth in the United States: 2007 update. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 34, 231.Google Scholar
Domeij, D. and Heathcote, J. (2004) On the distributional effects of reducing capital taxes. International Economic Review 45, 523554.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Peñalosa, C. and Orgiazzi, E. (2013) Factor components of inequality: A cross-country study. Review of Income and Wealth 59, 687727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Peñalosa, C. and Turnovsky, S.J. (2007) Growth, income inequality and fiscal policy: What are the relevant tradeoffs? Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 39, 369394.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Peñalosa, C. and Turnovsky, S.J. (2011) Taxation and income distribution dynamics in a neoclassical growth model. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 43, 15431577.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
García-Peñalosa, C. and Turnovsky, S.J. (2012) Income Inequality, Mobility, and the Accumulation of Capital: The Role of Heterogeneous Labor Productivity. AMSE working paper 2012–16.Google Scholar
Gorman, W. (1953) Community preference fields. Econometrica 21, 6380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guvenen, F. (2006) Reconciling conflicting evidence on the elasticity of intertemporal substitution: A macroeconomic perspective. Journal of Monetary Economics 53, 14511472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Holtz-Eakin, D., Joulfaian, D., and Rosen, H.S. (1993) The Carnegie conjecture: Some empirical evidence. Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 413435.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jenkins, S.P. (1995) Accounting for inequality trends: Decomposition analyses for the UK, 1971–86. Economica 62, 2963.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Krusell, P. and Smith, A. (1998) Income and wealth heterogeneity in the macroeconomy. Journal of Political Economy 106, 867896.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, C.I. and Solon, G. (2009) Trends in intergenerational income mobility. Review of Economics and Statistics 91, 766772.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maliar, L. and Maliar, S. (2001) Heterogeneity in capital and skills in a neoclassical stochastic growth model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 38, 635654.Google Scholar
Maliar, L. and Maliar, S. (2003) The representative consumer in the neoclassical growth model with idiosyncratic shocks. Review of Economic Dynamics 6, 362380.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maliar, L., Maliar, S., and Mora, J. (2005) Income and wealth distributions along the business cycle: Implications from the neoclassical growth model. Topics in Macroeconomics 5 (1), article 15.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McDaniel, C. (2007) Average Tax Rates on Consumption, Investment, Labor and Capital in the OECD 1953–2003. Mimeo, Arizona State University.Google Scholar
Piketty, T. (2000) Theories of persistent inequality and intergenerational mobility. In Atkinson, A.B. and Bourguignon, F. (eds.) Handbook of Income Distribution, pp. 429476Amsterdam: Elsevier.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. (2011) On the long-run evolution of inheritance: France 1820–2050. Quarterly Journal of Economics 61, 10711131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Piketty, T. and Zucman, G. (2013) Capital is back: Wealth–Income Ratios in Rich Countries 1700–2010. Mimeo, Paris School of Economics.Google Scholar
Roemer, J. (1998) Equality of Opportunity. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Solon, G. (1999) Intergenerational mobility in the labor market. In Ashenfelter, O., Layard, R., and Card, D. (eds.), Handbook of Labor Economics Vol. 3, pp. 17611800. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Turnovsky, S.J. and García-Peñalosa, C. (2008) Distributional dynamics in a neoclassical growth model: The role of elastic labor supply. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 32, 13991431.CrossRefGoogle Scholar