Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-t7czq Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T09:06:36.297Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

THE CASH-IN-ADVANCE CONSTRAINT IN MONETARY GROWTH MODELS WITH LABOR MARKET SEARCH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  30 July 2013

Burkhard Heer*
Affiliation:
University of Augsburg and CESifo
Alfred Maußner
Affiliation:
University of Augsburg
*
Address correspondence to: Burkhard Heer, Department of Economics, University of Augsburg, Universitätsstraße 16, 86159 Augsburg, Germany; e-mail: [email protected].

Abstract

We study the sensitivity of the inflation–growth trade-off in monetary growth models to the introduction of search frictions in the labor market. We consider three types of endogenous growth models: (1) the AK model, (2) the Lucas supply-side model, and (3) the two-sector model of Jones and Manuelli. We show that the effects depend on the specification of the cash-in-advance constraint and the magnitude of the semi-interest elasticity of the income velocity. For the AK model, economic growth increases with higher inflation. For the other two models, growth declines for the case of the standard cash-in-advance constraint on consumption, whereas it either increases or decreases if money is introduced, as in the cash–credit good economy of Dotsey and Ireland, depending on the semi-interest elasticity of the income velocity. The welfare effects of inflation are shown to be economically significant in the presence of search unemployment.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 2013 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Avery, R.B., Elliehausen, G.E., Kennickell, A.B., and Spindt, P.A. (1987) Changes in the use of transaction accounts and cash from 1984 to 1986. Federal Reserve Bulletin 73, 179196.Google Scholar
Ball, L. (2001) Another look at long-run money demand. Journal of Monetary Economics 47, 3144.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R.J. (2013) Inflation and economic growth. Annals of Economics and Finance 14 (1), 121144.Google Scholar
Barro, R.J. (2001) Economic Growth in East Asia before and after the Financial Crisis. NBER working paper 8330.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bruno, M. and Easterly, W. (1998) Inflation crises and long-run growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 41, 326.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chari, V.V., Jones, L.E., and Manuelli, R. (1996) Inflation, growth, and financial intermediation. Federal Reserve Bank of St. Louis Review 78 (3), 4158.Google Scholar
Christiano, L.J., Eichenbaum, M., and Evans, C.L. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113, 145.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christoffel, K., Costain, J., de Walque, G., Kuester, K., Linzert, T., Millard, S., and Pierrard, O. (2009a) Inflation Dynamics with Labour Market Matching. European Central Bank working paper 1053.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christoffel, K., Kuester, K., and Linzert, T. (2009b) The role of labor markets for euro area monetary policy. European Economic Review 53 (8), 908936.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
De Gregorio, J. (1993) Inflation, taxation, and long-run growth. Journal of Monetary Economics 31 (3), 271298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dotsey, M. and Ireland, P. (1996) The welfare cost of inflation in general equilibrium. Journal of Monetary Economics 37, 2947.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillman, M. (1993) The welfare costs of inflation in a cash-in-advance economy with costly credit. Journal of Monetary Economics 31 (1), 97115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillman, M., Harris, M.N., and Matyas, L. (2004) Inflation and growth: Explaining a negative effect. Empirical Economics 29 (1), 149167.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gillman, M. and Kejak, M. (2005) Contrasting models of the effect of inflation on growth. Journal of Economics Surveys 19, 113136.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gomme, P. (1993) Money and growth revisited: Measuring the costs of inflation in an endogenous growth model. Journal of Monetary Economics 32, 5177.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grüner, H.P. and Heer, B. (2000) Optimal flat-rate taxes on capital—A re-examination of Lucas' supply side model. Oxford Economic Papers 52 (2), 289315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gylfason, T. and Herbertsson, T.T. (2001) Does inflation matter for growth? Japan and the World Economy 13, 405428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heer, B. and Maußner, A. (2010) Inflation and output dynamics in a model of labor market search and capital accumulation. Review of Economic Dynamics 13, 654686.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heer, B., Maußner, A., and McNelis, P.D. (2011) The money-age distribution: Empirical facts and the limits of three monetary models. Journal of Macroeconomics 33, 390405.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ireland, P.N. (1994) Money and growth: An alternative approach. American Economic Review 84 (1), 4765.Google Scholar
Jha, S.K., Wang, P., and Yip, C.K. (2002) Dynamics in transactions-based monetary growth model. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 26, 611635.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jones, L.E. and Manuelli, R.E. (1995) Growth and the effects of inflation. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 19, 14051428.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keynes, J.M. (1936) The General Theory of Employment, Interest, and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Kormendi, R. and Meguire, P. (1985) Macroeconomic determinants of growth: Cross-country evidence. Journal of Monetary Economics 16, 141163.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kydland, F.E. and Prescott, E.C. (1982) Time to build and aggregate fluctuations. Econometrica 50, 13451370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
López-Villavicencio, A. and Mignon, V. (2011) On the impact of inflation on output growth: Does the inflation matter? Journal of Macroeconomics 33, 455464.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (1987) Models of Business Cycles. Oxford, UK: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Lucas, R.E. (1990) Supply-side economics: An analytical review. Oxford Economic Papers 42, 293316.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Maußner, A. (2004) Endogenous growth with nominal frictions. Journal of Economics 83, 146.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McCandless, G. and Weber, W. (1995) Some monetary facts. Federal Reserve Bank of Minneapolis Quarterly Review 19 (3), 211.Google Scholar
Mortensen, D. and Pissarides, C. (1994) Job creation and job destruction in the theory of unemployment. Review of Economic Studies 61 (3), 397415.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peters, M. (1991) Ex ante price offers in matching games: Non-steady state. Econometrica 59, 14251454.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, A.W. (1958) The relation between unemployment and the rate of change of money wage rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957. Economica 25, 283299.Google Scholar
Romer, P.M. (1986) Increasing returns and long-run growth. Journal of Political Economy 94, 10021038.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schreft, S. (1992) Transaction costs and the use of cash and credit. Economic Theory 2, 283296.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shi, S. and Wen, Q. (1997) Labor market search and capital accumulation: Some analytical results. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 21 (10), 17471776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shi, S. and Wen, Q. (1999) Labor market search and the dynamic effects of taxes and subsidies. Journal of Monetary Economics 43, 457495.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trigari, A. (2006) The Role of Search Frictions and Bargaining for Inflation Dynamics. IGIER working paper 304.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Trigari, A. (2009) Equilibrium unemployment, job flows and inflation dynamics. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41 (1), 133.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walsh, C.E. (2005) Labor market search, sticky prices, and interest rate policies. Review of Economic Dynamics 8 (4), 829849.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Walsh, C.E. (2010) Monetary Theory and Policy, 3rd ed.Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Wu, Y. and Zhang, J. (1998) Endogenous growth and the welfare costs of inflation: A reconsideration. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 22, 465482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar