Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-29T11:01:26.993Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

The Market as a Matter of Money: Denaturalizing Economic Currency in American Constitutional History

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 December 2018

Abstract

Histories of the early American political economy present that world in fractured form, dividing political and constitutional dimensions from economic aspects. The fragmented approach reflects an old, oft-denigrated, but still powerful imagery, one that naturalizes economic activity as a set of myriad spontaneous and individuated exchanges, conducted with a conventional medium, money, and predictably composing a market sphere. The motif and its underlying assumptions in turn dissuade exploration of money and markets as territories of public decision, insulating by neglect the structural power of determinations made there. This essay traces the naturalization motif through a historiography of macroeconomic models of money. It then considers how money, recognized as a dynamics of value, would look if the law structuring it were approached as a complex set of relations that expressed, reiterated, and revised the distribution of authority in society. The early American political economy appears in a different light: money becomes a matter of value and governance at once, and therefore a crucial area of constitutional debate. Through that medium, the political economy of early America is transformed not once but repeatedly, from a mercantilist to a domestic paper to a liberal capitalist form.

Type
Articles
Copyright
Copyright © American Bar Foundation, 2005 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Adams, J. [1780] 1889. J. Adams to Vergennes, June 22, 1780. In The Revolutionary Diplomatic Correspondence of the United States, ed. Francis, Wharton. Washington: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Anonymous, . 1734. Essay on Currency. Charleston, S. C: Printed and Sold by Lewis Timothy, in Church Street.Google Scholar
Appleby, Joyce Oldham. 1992. Liberalism and Republicanism in the Historical Imagination. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Bailyn, Bernard. 1967. The Ideological Origins of the American Revolution. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Baker, C. Edwin. 1975. The Ideology of the Economic Analysis of Law. Journal of Philosophy and Public Affairs 5:348.Google Scholar
Barnes, Viola Florence. 1923. The Dominion of New England: A Study in British Colonial Policy. New Haven, Conn.:Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Beard, Charles A. 1913. An Economic Interpretation of the Constitution of the United States. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Bell, Stephanie. 2001. The Role of the State and the Hierarchy of Money. Cambridge Journal of Economics 25:149–63.Google Scholar
Bernholz, Peter. 1988. Inflation, Monetary Regime, and the Financial Asset Theory of Money. Kyklos: International Review for Social Sciences 41:534.Google Scholar
Bernstein, Michael A. 2001. A Perilous Progress: Economists and Public Purpose in Twentieth-Century America. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Blackwell, Captain John. [1687] 1910. A Discourse in Explanation of the Bank of Credit. In Davis 1910.Google Scholar
Blaug, Mark. 1996. Economic Theory in Retrospect. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Brewer, John. 1990. The Sinews of Power: War, Money, and the English. State. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Brock, Leslie V. 1975. The Currency of the American Colonies 1700–1764: A Study in Colonial Finance and Imperial Relations. New York: Arno Press.Google Scholar
Brown, Roger H. 1993. Redeeming the Republic: Federalists, Taxation, and the Origins of the Constitution. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Calomiris, Charles W. 1988. Institutional Failure, Monetary Scarcity, and the Depreciation of the Continental. Journal of Economic History 48:4768.Google Scholar
Callon, Michel, ed. 1998. The Laws of the Market. Oxford, U.K.: Blackwell Publishers; Sociological Review.Google Scholar
Carruthers, Bruce G. 1996. City of Capital: Politics and Markets in the English Financial Revolution. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Continental Congress. 1779. Circular Letter from the Continental Congress to their Constituents. Journal of the Continental Congress 25:1051–62.Google Scholar
Clark, Christopher. 1990. The Roots of Rural Capitalism: Western Massachusetts 1780–1860. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Clarke, Mary Patterson. 1943. Parliamentary Privilege in the American Colonies. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Colonial Lauws of New York. 1894. Albany, New York: James and Lyon, printer.Google Scholar
Commons, John R. [1924] 1995. Legal Foundations of Capitalism. New Brunswick, N.J.: Transaction. Cornbury, Lord. [1704] 1764- Lord Cornbury to the New York House of Representatives, June 1, 1704. Journal of the Votes and Proceedings of the General Assembly of the Colony of New York. New York: Printed by Hugh Gaines.Google Scholar
Crowley, J. E. 1974. This Sheba, SELF: The Conceptualization of Economic Life in Eighteenth-Century America. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Davis, Andrew McFarland, ed. 1910. Colonial Currency Reprints, 16821751. Vol. 1. Boston: Prince Society.Google Scholar
De Roover, Raymond. 1955. Scholastic Economics: Survival and Lasting Influence from the Sixteenth Century to Adam Smith. Quarterly Journal of Economics 69:161–90.Google Scholar
Desan, Christine A. 1998a. Remaking Constitutional Tradition at the Margin of the Empire: The Creation of Legislative Adjudication in Colonial New York. Law and History Review 16:291309.Google Scholar
Desan, Christine A. 1998b. The Constitutional Commitment to Legislative Adjudication in the Early American Tradition. Harvard Law Review 111:1381–503.Google Scholar
Desan, Christine A. 1998c. Writing Constitutional History beyond the Institutional/Ideological Divide. Law and History Review 16:391–96.Google Scholar
Desan, Christine A. 2003. The Many Laws of the Market: The Contrasting Constitutions of Capitalism and Early American Localism. Manuscript on file with author.Google Scholar
Dickson, P. G. M. 1967. The Financial Revolution in England: A Study in the Development of Public Credit, 16881756. London: MacMillan.Google Scholar
Dudley, Paul. [1714] 1910. Objections to the Bank of Credit. In Davis 1910.Google Scholar
Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, and Peter, Newman, eds. 1989. The New Palgrave: Money. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Einhorn, Robin. 2003. American Taxation, American Slavery. Paper presented at the Warren Center for American History, Cambridge, Mass., December.Google Scholar
Elkins, Stanley, and Eric, McKitrick. 1993. The Age of Federalism. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Ernst, Joseph Albert. 1973. Money and Politics in America, 1755–1775: A Study in the Currency Act of 1764 and the Political Economy of Revolution. Chapel Hill: Institute of Early American History and Culture; University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Farmer, Dick [pseud.]. 1741. Whereas Great Quantities of English Copper Halfpence…. Philadelphia: Printed by William Bradford.Google Scholar
Ferguson, James E. 1961. The Power of the Purse: A History of American Public Finance, 1776–1790. Chapel Hill: Institute of Early American History and Culture; University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Ferguson, Niall. 2001. The Cash Nexus: Money and Power in the Modern World, 1700–2000. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Flaherty, Martin Stephen. 1987. The Empire Strikes Back: Annesley v. Sherlock and the Triumph of Imperial Parliamentary Supremacy. Columbia Law Review 87:593622.Google Scholar
Foucault, Michel. 1990. The History of Sexuality. Vol. 1: An Introduction, trans. Robert, Hurley. London: Penguin.Google Scholar
Frank, Jerome. 1970. Law and the Modern Mind. Gloucester, Mass.: P. Smith.Google Scholar
Franklin, Benjamin. [1729] 1907. A Modest Enquiry into the Nature and Necessity of a Paper Currency. In Smyth 1907.Google Scholar
Franklin, Benjamin. [1784] 1907. Of the Paper Money of the United States of America. In Smyth 1907.Google Scholar
Fried, Barbara H. 1998. The Progressive Assault on Laissez-Faire: Robert Hale and the First Law and Economics Movement. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1989. Quantity Theory of Money. In Eatwell, Milgate, and Newman 1989.Google Scholar
Frug, Gerald E. 1999. City Making: Building Communities without Building Walls. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Goodhart, Charles A. E. 1998. The Two Concepts of Money: Implications for the Analysis of Optimal Currency Areas. European Journal of Political Economy 14:407–32.Google Scholar
Greene, Jack P. 1963. The Quest for Power: The Lower Houses of Assembly in the Southern Royal Colonies, 1689–1776. Chapel Hill: Institute of Early American History and Culture; University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert W. 1984. Critical Legal Histories. Stanford Law Review 36:57125.Google Scholar
Grey, Thomas C. 1983. Langdell's Orthodoxy. University of Pittsburgh Law Review 45:153.Google Scholar
Grubb, Farley. 2003a. Creating the U.S. Dollar Currency Union, 1748–1811: A Quest for Monetary Stability or a Usurpation of State Sovereignty for Personal Gain American Economic Review 93:1778–98.Google Scholar
Grubb, Farley. 2003b. Two Theories of Money Reconciled: The Colonial Puzzle Revisited with New Evidence. Versions of papers presented at the University of Delaware and at the 2001 National Bureau of Economic Research—Development of the American Economy Summer Institute. Draft on file with author.Google Scholar
Guyer, Jane I. ed. 1995. Money Matters: Instability, Values, and Social Payments in the Modem History of West African Communities. Portsmouth, N.H.: Heinemann.Google Scholar
Hale, Robert L. 1923. Coercion and Distribution in a Supposedly Non-Coercive State. Political Science Quarterly 38:470–94.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander. 1961. Report on the Public Credit. In The Papers of Alexander Hamilton, ed. Harold, C. Syrett and Jacob, E. Cooke. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander. [1790] 1986. Report of the Secretary of the Treasury on the Public Credit, Jan. 14, 1790. In vol. 5, Documentary History of the First Federal Congress of the United States of America, March 4, 1789-March 3, 1791, ed. Linda, Grant De Pauw. Baltimore, Md.: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Hare, R. M. 1981. Moral Thinking: Its Levels, Method, and Point. Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Henretta, James A. 1978. Families and Farms: Mentalité in Pre-Industrial America. William and Mary Quarterly 35:332.Google Scholar
Henretta, James A. 1991. The Weber Thesis Revisited: The Protestant Ethic or the Reality of Capitalism in Early America. In The Origins of American Capitalism: Collected Essays, ed. James, A. Henretta. 1991. Boston: Northeastern University Press.Google Scholar
Hill, Christopher. 1991. The World Turned Upside Down: Radical Ideas during the English Revolution. London: Penguin Books.Google Scholar
Hirschman, Albert O. 1997. The Passions and the Interests: Political Arguments for Capitalism before Its Triumph. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Hohfeld, Wesley Newcomb. 1913. Some Fundamental Legal Conceptions as Applied in Judicial Reasoning. Yale Law Journal 23:1659.Google Scholar
Holmes, O. W. 1897. The Path of the Law. Harvard Law Review 10:457–78.Google Scholar
Horkheimer, Max. [1935] 1978. On the Problem of Truth. In The Essential Frankfurt School Reader, ed. Andrew, Arato and Eike, Gebhardt. New York: Urizen Books.Google Scholar
Horwitz, Morton J. 1992. The Transformation of American Law, 1870–1960: The Crisis of Legal Orthodoxy. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hutchinson, Thomas. [1765] 1936. The History of the Colony and Province of Massachusetts-Bay. Vol. 1. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Innes, Stephen. 1995. Creating the Commonwealth: The Economic Culture of Puritan New England. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Johnson, Walter. 1999. Soul by Soul: Life Inside the Antebellum Slave Market. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kelman, Mark. 1983. Misunderstanding Social Life: A Critique of the Core Premises of “Law and Economics. Journal of Legal Education 33:274–84.Google Scholar
Kelman, Mark. 1987. A Guide to Critical Legal Studies. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1976. Form and Substance in Private Law Adjudication. Harvard Law Review 89:1685–778.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1985. The Role of Law in Economic Thought: Essays on the Fetishism of Commodities. American University Law Review 34:9391001.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1986. Freedom and Constraint in Adjudication: A Critical Phenomenology. Journal of Legal Education 36:518–62.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 1991. The Stakes of Law, or Hale and Foucault Legal Studies Forum 15:327–65.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan. 2001. The Political Stakes in “Merely Technical” Issues of Contract Law. European Review of Private Law 1:7.Google Scholar
Kennedy, Duncan, and Frank, I. Michelman. 1980. Are Property and Contract Efficient Hofstra Law Review 8:711–70.Google Scholar
Kulikoff, Allan. 1992. The Agrarian Origins of American Capitalism. Charlottesville: University Press of Virginia.Google Scholar
Labaree, Leonard Woods. 1930. Royal Government in America: A Study of the British Colonial System before 1783. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lamoreaux, Naomi. 2003. Rethinking the Transition to Capitalism in the Early American Northeast. Journal of American History 90:437–61.Google Scholar
Lester, Richard. 1938. Currency Issues to Overcome Depressions in Pennsylvania, 1723 and 1729. Journal of Political Economy 46:324–75.Google Scholar
Lester, Richard. 1939. Currency Issues to Overcome Depressions in Delaware, New Jersey, New York, and Maryland. Journal of Political Economy 47:182217.Google Scholar
Levine, Ross M. 1997. Financial Development and Economic Growth. Journal of Eco-nomic Literature 35:690703.Google Scholar
Llewellyn, Karl N. 1930. A Realistic Jurisprudence: The Next Step. Columbia Law Review 30:431–65.Google Scholar
Macaulay, Stewart. 1966. Private Legislation and the Duty to Read—Business Run by IBM Machine, the Law of Contracts, and Credit Cards. Vanderbilt Law Review 19:1051–122.Google Scholar
MacDonald, James. 2003. A Free Nation Deep in Debt: The Financial Roots of Democracy. New York: Farrar, Strauss, and Giroux.Google Scholar
Macpherson, C. B. 1964. The Political Theory of Possessive Individualism: Hobbes to Locke. Oxford, U.K.: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Main, Jackson Turner. 1961. The Antifederalists: Critics of the Constitution, 1781–1788. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Mankiw, N. Gregory. 2000. Macroeconomics. New York: Worth.Google Scholar
Mann, Bruce H. 1987. Neighbors and Strangers: Law and Community in Early Connecticut. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Mather, Cotton. [1690 1910. Some Considerations on the Bills of Credit Now Passing in New England. In Davis 1910.Google Scholar
McCallum, Bennett T., and Marvin, S. Goodfriend. 1989. Demand for Money: Theoretical Studies. In Eatwell, Milgate, and Newman 1989.Google Scholar
McConnell, Michael W. 1985. Accommodation of Religion. Supreme Court Review 157.Google Scholar
McKinnon, Ronald 1973. Money and Capital in Economic Development. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Merrill, Michael. 1990. The Anticapitalist Origins of the United States. Review: J. Femand Braudel Center 13:465–97.Google Scholar
Michener, Ronald. 1987. Fixed Exchange Rates and the Quantity Theory in Colonial America. In Empirical Studies of Velocity, Real Exchange Rates, Unemployment and Productivity, ed. Karl, Brunner and Allan, H. Meltzer. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Morgan, Edmund S. 1988. Inventing the People: The Rise of Popular Sovereignty in England and America. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Morris, Robert. [1782 1984. Robert Morris to the President of Congress, July 29, 1782. In The Papers of Robert Morris: 1781–1784, vol. 6, ed. Ferguson, E. James. Pittsburgh: University of Pittsburgh Press.Google Scholar
Mun, Thomas. 1664. England's Treasure by Forraign Trade, or, the Balance of our Forraign Trade is the Rule of our Treasure. London: Printed by J. G. for Thomas Clark.Google Scholar
Nettels, Curtis Putnam. 1934. The Money Supply of the American Colonies before 1720. Madison: University of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Newman, Eric P. 1967. The Early Paper Money of America. Racine, Wis.: Whitman Publishing.Google Scholar
Newton, Scott. 2003. The Dialectics of Law and Development. Paper presented at European Law Research Center Conference on Law in Economic Development, April 13.Google Scholar
North, Douglass Cecil. 1981. Structure and Change in Economic History. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C, and Barry, R. Weingast. 1989. Constitutions and Commitment: The Evolution of Institutions Governing Public Choice in Seventeenth-Century England. Journal of Economic History 49:803–32.Google Scholar
Nussbaum, Arthur. 1939. Money in the Law. Chicago: Foundation Press.Google Scholar
O'Callaghan, E. B., ed. 1855. Documents Relative to the Colonial History of the State of New York. Vol. 5. Albany, N.Y.: Weed, Parsons.Google Scholar
Osgood, Herbert L. 1924. The American Colonies in the Eighteenth Century. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Parker, Richard Davies. 1981. The Past of Constitutional Theory—and Its Future. Ohio State Law Journal 42:223–59.Google Scholar
Perkins, Edwin. 1991. Conflicting Views on Fiat Currency: Britain and Its North American Colonies in the Eighteenth Century. Business History 33:830.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl. [1944 2001. The Great Transformation: The Political and Economic Origins of our Time. Boston: Beacon.Google Scholar
Poovey, Mary. 1998. A History of the Modem Fact: Problems of Knowledge in the Sciences of Wealth and Society. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Priest, Claire. 2001. Currency Policies and Legal Development in Colonial New England. Yal Law Journal 110:1303–405.Google Scholar
Purcell, Edward A. Jr. 1973. The Crisis of Democratic Theory: Scientific Naturalism and the Problem of Value. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky.Google Scholar
[Randolph, Peyton. 1759. A Letter to a Gentleman in London, from Virginia. Williamsburg, Va.: Printed by William Hunter.Google Scholar
Rawle, Francis [A Lover of this Country, pseud.]. 1721. Some Remedies Proposed, for Restoring the Sunk Credit of the Province of Pennsylvania. Philadelphia: Printed by Andrew Bradford.Google Scholar
Rawle, Francis. 1725. Ways and Means for the Inhabitants of Delaware to Become Rich. Philadelphia: Printed by S. Keimer.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas J. 1982. The Ends of Four Big Inflations. In Inflation: Causes and Effects, ed. Robert, E. Hall. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Sargent, Thomas J., and Neil, Wallace. 1976. Rational Expectations and the Theory of Economic Policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 2:169–83.Google Scholar
Scheiber, Harry N. 1984. Public Rights and the Rule of Law in American Legal History. California Law Review 72:217–51.Google Scholar
Shavell, Steven. 2004. Foundations of Economic Analysis of Law. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Singer, Joseph William. 1982. The Legal Rights Debate in Analytical Jurisprudence from Bentham to Hohfeld. Wisconsin Law Review 1982:9751059.Google Scholar
Singer, Joseph William. 1988. The Reliance Interest in Property. Stanford Law Review 40:611751.Google Scholar
Sklansky, Jeffrey. 2002. The Soul's Economy: Market Society and Selfhood in American Thought, 1820–1920. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1776 1999. The Wealth of Nations. London: Penguin Classics.Google Scholar
Smith, Bruce D. 1984. Money and Inflation in Colonial Massachusetts. Federal Reserve Bank Minnesota Quarterly Review 8:114.Google Scholar
Smith, Bruce D. 1985a. American Colonial Monetary Regimes: The Failure of the Quantity Theory and Some Evidence in Favour of an Alternate View. Canadian Journal of Economics 18:531–65.Google Scholar
Smith, Bruce D. 1985b. Some Colonial Evidence on Two Theories of Money: Maryland and the Carolinas. Journal of Political Economy 93:1178–211.Google Scholar
Smith, Bruce D. 1987. Money and Inflation in the American Colonies: Further Evidence on the Failure of the Quantity Theory. Appendix. Working Paper 8715c, Department of Economics, University of Western Ontario.Google Scholar
Smyth, Albert Henry, ed. 1907. The Writings of Benjamin Franklin. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Snowiss, Sylvia. 1990. Judicial Review and the Law of the Constitution. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Spencer, Henry Russell. 1905. Constitutional Conflict in Provincial Massachusetts. Columbus, Ohio: Press of Fred J. Heer.Google Scholar
Stanley, Amy Dru. 1998. From Bondage to Contract: Wage Labor, Marriage, and the Market in the Age of Slave Emancipation. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sullivan, Kathleen M. 1992. Foreword: The Justices of Rules and Standards. Harvard Law Review 106:22123.Google Scholar
Sumner, Scott. 1993. Colonial Currency and the Quantity Theory of Money: A Critique of Smith's Interpretation. Journal of Economic History 53:139–45.Google Scholar
Sussman, Nathan, and Yishay, Yafeh. 2002. Constitutions and Commitment: Evidence on the Relation Between Constitutions and the Cost of Capital. Working paper on file with author.Google Scholar
Sylla, Richard. 1982. Monetary Innovation and Crises in American Economic History. In Crises in the Economic and Financial Structure, ed. Paul, Wachtel. Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books.Google Scholar
Sylla, Richard. 1999. Shaping the U.S. Financial System, 1690–1913: The Dominant Role of Public Finance. In The State, the Financial System, and Economic Modernization, ed. Richard, Sylla, Richard Tilly, and Gabriel Tortella. Cambridge, U.K.: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Tushnet, Mark. 1980. Dia-Tribe. Michigan Law Review 78:694710.Google Scholar
Warren, Samuel D., and Louis, D. Brandeis. 1890. The Right to Privacy. Harvard Law Review 4:193220.Google Scholar
Weber, Max. [1930 1992. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, trans. Talcott, Parsons. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Wicker, Elmus. 1985. Colonial Monetary Standards Contrasted: Evidence from the Seven Years' War. Journal of Economic History 45:869–84.Google Scholar
Woeste, Victoria Saker. 1998. The Farmer's Benevolent Trust: Law and Agricultural Cooperation in Industrial America, 1865–1945. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Wood, Gordon S. 1969. The Creation of the American Republic, 1776–1787. Chapel Hill: Institute of Early American History and Culture; University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Woodruff, David. 1999. Money Unmade: Barter and the Fate of Russian Capitalism. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Wray, L. Randall, ed. 2004. Credit and State Theories of Money: The Contributions of A. Mitchell Innes. Cheltenham, U.K.: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar