Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-19T06:28:41.203Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

FRIEDMAN’S NOBEL LECTURE AND THE PHILLIPS CURVE MYTH

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 August 2010

Abstract

In his Nobel lecture, Friedman built on his earlier argument for a “natural rate of unemployment” by painting a picture of an economics profession which, as a result of foolish mistakes, had accepted the Phillips curve as offering a lasting trade-off between inflation and unemployment, and was thereby led to advocate a policy of inflation. It is argued here that, in fact, the orthodox economists of the time often did not accept Phillips’ analysis; almost no one made the mistakes in question; and very few advocated inflation on bases vulnerable to Friedman’s theoretical criticisms. The Phillips curve was put to various uses, but advocating inflation was hardly amongst them. It is suggested that one lasting result of the uncritical acceptance of Friedman’s history is to limit what appears to be within the reasonable range of views about macroeconomic policy.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © The History of Economics Society 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

REFERENCES

Akerlof, George, Dickens, William, and Perry, George L. 1996. “The Macroeconomics of Low Inflation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 27 (1): 1–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balogh, Thomas. 1958. “Productivity and Inflation.” Oxford Economic Papers 10 (2): 220–245.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baumol, William J. 1978. “On the Stochastic Unemployment Distribution Model and the Long-run Phillips Curve.” In Bergstrom, A., Catt, A., Peston, M., and Silverstone, B., eds., Stability and inflation. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, pp. 3–21.Google Scholar
Beckerman, Wilfred. 1972. The Labor Government’s Economic Record. London: Duckworth.Google Scholar
Bhatia, Rattan J. 1961. “Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Earnings in the United States, 1900–1958.” Economica XXVIII (August): 285–196.Google Scholar
Bodkin, Ronald G. 1966. The Wage-Price Productivity Nexus. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowen, William G. 1960. Wage Behavior in the Post-war Period. Princeton NJ: Industrial Relations Section, Department of Economics, Princeton University.Google Scholar
Bowen, William G. and Albert Berry, R. 1963. “Unemployment Conditions and Movements of the Money Wage Level.” Review of Economic Studies 45: 163–172.Google Scholar
Brechling, Frank. 1968. “The Trade Off between Inflation and Unemployment.” Journal of Political Economy 76 (4, 2): 712–737.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brechling, Frank. 1969. “Discussion.” American Economic Review 59 (2): 161–162.Google Scholar
Caves, Richard and Krause, Lawrence B., eds. 1968. Britain’s Economic Prospects. London: Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Clark, John Maurice, Smithies, Arthur, Kaldor, Nicholas, Uri, Pierre, and Ronald Walker, E. 1949. National and International Measures for Full Employment. Lake Success, New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
Desai, Meghnad. 1975. “The Phillips Curve: A Revisionist Interpretation.” Economica 42: 2–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dicks-Mireaux, L. A. 1961. “The Interrelationship between Cost and Price Changes, 1964–1959. A Study of Inflation in Post-war Britain.” Oxford Economic Papers 13 (3): 267–292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dicks-Mireaux, L. A. and Dow, J. C. R. 1959. “The Determinants of Wage Inflation: United Kingdom, 1946–1956.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 122 (2): 146–174.Google Scholar
Dow, J. C. R. 1964. The Management of the British Economy 1945–60. Cambridge: NIESR.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eckstein, Otto and Wilson, Thomas A. 1962. “The Determination of Money Wages in American Industry.” Quarterly Journal of Economics LXXVI (August): 379–414.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fisher, Irving. 1926. “A Statistical Relation between Unemployment and Price Changes.” International Labour Review (June): 785–792.Google Scholar
Forder, James. 2010. “The Historical Place of the ‘Friedman-Phelps’ Expectations Critique.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 17: 493–511.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Forder, James. Forthcoming 2011. “The L-shaped aggregate supply curve and the future of macroeconomics.” In Harcourt, G. C. ed., Handbook of Post Keynesian Economics, volume 2. Oxford: OUP.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1958. “The Supply of Money and Changes in Prices and Output.” In The Relationship of Prices to Economic Stability and Growth. Compendium of papers submitted by panelists appearing before the JEC 85th Congress, 2d Sess, March 31 1958.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1966. “What Price Guideposts?” In Schultz, G. P. and Aliber, R. Z., eds., Guidelines, Informal Controls, and the Market Place. Chicago: Chicago University Press, pp. 17–40.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1968. “The Role of Monetary Policy.” American Economic Review 58: 1–17.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1975. Unemployment Versus Inflation? London: Institute of Economic Affairs.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1977. “Nobel Lecture: Inflation and Unemployment.” Journal of Political Economy 85: 451–472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fromm, Gary and Taubman, Paul. 1968. Policy Simulations with an Econometric Model. Washington DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Gilbert, Christopher L. 1976. “The Original Phillips Curve Estimates.” Economica 43 (169): 51–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Robert A. 1967. The Goal of Full Employment. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. 1970. “The Recent Acceleration of Inflation and Its Iessons for the Future.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 8–41.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. 1971a. “Inflation in Recession and Recovery.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 1: 105–158.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gordon, Robert J. 1971b. “Steady Anticipated Inflation: Mirage or Oasis?Brookings Papers on Economic Activity (2): 499–510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Griffin, Keith. 1962. “A Note on Wages, Prices and Unemployment.” Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics 24 (3): 379–385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hansen, Bent. 1951. A Study in the Theory of Inflation. London: George Allen and Unwin.Google Scholar
Harcourt, Geoffrey C. 2000. “A Left Keynesian View of the Phillips Curve Trade Off.” In Leeson, R. ed., A W H Phillips: Collected Works in Contemporary Perspective. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 304–307.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hendry, David and Wallis, Kenneth F, eds. 1984. Econometrics and Quantitative Economics. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Hines, A. G. 1964. “Trade Unions and Wage Inflation in the United Kingdom, 1893–1966.” Review of Economic Studies XXXI: 221–252.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1957. “A Model of Economic Growth.” Economic Journal 67 (268): 591–624.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1959a. “Economic Growth and the Problem of Inflation, Part 2.” Economica 26 (November): 287–298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kaldor, Nicholas. 1959b. “Evidence to the Radcliffe Committee.” London: HMSO.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1936. The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. M. 1940. How to Pay for the War. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Klein, Lawrence R. and Ball, R. J. 1959. “Some Econometrics of the Determination of Absolute Prices and Wages.” Economic Journal LXIX (Sept): 465–482.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Klein, Lawrence R. and Bodkin, Ronald G. 1964. “Empirical Aspects of the Trade-offs among Three Goals: High Level Employment, Price Stability, and Economic Growth.” In Fox, Bertrand, ed., Inflation, Growth and Employment. Studies Prepared for the Commission on Money and Credit. Englewood Cliffs, New Jersey: Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Klein, Lawrence R. and Goldberger, Arthur S. 1955. An Econometric Model of the United States, 1929–1952. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Knowles, K. G. J. C. and Winsten, C. B. 1959. “Can the Level of Unemployment Explain Changes in Wages?Bulletin of the Oxford University Institute of Economics and Statistics 21 (2): 113–120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuh, Edwin. 1967. “A Productivity Theory of Wage Levels—An Alternative to the Phillips Curve.” Review of Economic Studies 34: 333–360.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, David E. W. 1971. “The Phillips Curve, Expectations and Incomes Policy.” In Johnson, H. G. and Nobay, A. R., eds., The Current Inflation. London: Macmillan, pp. 75–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laidler, David E. W. 1997. “The Emergence of the Phillips Curve as a Policy Menu.” In Eaton, B. C. and Harris, R. G., eds., Trade, Technology and Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar, pp. 88–106.Google Scholar
Laidler, David E. W. 2003. “The role of the history of economic thought in modern macroeconomics.” In Mizen, P., ed., Monetary history, exchange rates and financial markets. Cheltenham: Elgar, pp. 12–29Google Scholar
Leeson, Robert. 1997a. “The Trade Off Interpretation of Phillips’s Dynamic Stabilization Exercise.” Economica 64 (253): 155–171.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Robert. 1997b. “The Political Economy of the Inflation–Unemployment Trade-off.” History of Political Economy 29 (1): 117–156.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeson, Robert. 1998. “Early Doubts about the Phillips Curve Trade-off.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 20 (1): 83–102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lerner, Abba. 1960. “Discussion.” American Economic Review 50 (2): 215–218.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1965. “Structural and Deficient-Demand Unemployment Reconsidered.” In Ross, A. M., ed., Employment Policy and the Labor Market. Berkeley and Los Angeles: University of California Press, pp. 210–255.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1960. “The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1882–1957: A Further Analysis.” Economica 27: 1–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1978. “The Place of the Phillips Curve in Macroeconomic Models.” In Bergstrom, A., Catt, A., Peston, M., and Silverstone, B., eds., Stability and Inflation. Chichester: John Wiley & Sons, pp. 49–76.Google Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. 1981. “The Understanding and Control of Inflation: Is There a Crisis in Macro-economics?Canadian Journal of Economics 14 (4): 545–576.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lipsey, Richard G. and Steuer, M. D. 1961. “The Relation between Profits and Wage Rates.” Economica (May): 137–155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lucas, Robert E. 1972. “Econometric Testing of the Natural Rate Hypothesis.” In Eckstein, O., ed., The Econometrics of Price Determination Conference. Washington: Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System and Social Science Research Council.Google Scholar
Modigliani, Franco and Tarantelli, Ezio. 1973. “A Generalization of the Phillips Curve for a Developing Country.” Review of Economic Studies 40 (2): 203–223.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Netherlands Central Statistical Office. 1933. “De wisselwesking tusschen loon en werkgelegenheid.” De Nederlandsche Conjunctuur: 10.Google Scholar
Okun, Arthur M. 1971. “The Mirage of Steady Inflation.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity. 1: 458–498.Google Scholar
Paish, Frank W. [1958] 1966. “Inflation in the UK.” Economica 25 (98): 19–105.Google Scholar
Paish, Frank W. [1962] 1966. Studies in an Inflationary Economy. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Peacock, Alan. 1972. “Fiscal Means and Political Ends.” In Peston, M. H. and Corry, B., eds., Essays in honour of Lord Robbins. London: Weidenfeld and Nicolson, pp. 82–98.Google Scholar
Peston, Maurice. 1971. “The Microeconomics of the Phillips Curve.” In Johnson, H. G. and Nobay, A. R., eds., The Current Inflation. London: Macmillan, pp. 125–142.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Peston, Maurice. 1974. Theory of Macroeconomic Policy. Deddington: Philip Allen.Google Scholar
Phelps, Edmund S. 1967. “Phillips Curves, Expectations of Inflation and Optimal Unemployment over Time.” Economica 34 (August): 254–281.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Phillips, A. W. H. 1958. “The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates in the United Kingdom, 1861–1957.” Economica 25 (November): 283–299.Google Scholar
Phillips, A. W. H. 1962. “Employment, Inflation and Growth.” Economica 29 (February): 1–16.Google Scholar
Pigou, A. C. 1933. Theory of Unemployment. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Porter, Dana. 1964. Royal Commission on Banking and Finance (The Porter Report). Ottawa: The Queen’s Printer.Google Scholar
Rees, Albert. 1970. “The Phillips Curve as a Menu for Policy Choice.” Economica 37 (August): 227–238.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Reuber, Grant L. 1962. The Objectives of Monetary Policy. Working paper prepared for the Royal Commission on Banking and Finance. Ottawa: Queen’s Printer.Google Scholar
Reuber, Grant L. 1964. “The Objectives of Canadian Monetary Policy, 1949–1961: Empirical ’Trade-offs’ and the Reaction Function of the Authorities.” Journal of Political Economy 72 (109–132).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Robinson, Joan. 1937. Essays in the Theory of Employment. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robinson, Joan. 1973. “What Has Become of the Keynesian Revolution?” In Robinson, J. V., ed., After Keynes. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Routh, Guy. 1959. “The Relation between Unemployment and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Rates: A Comment.” Economica 26 (104): 299–315.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1961. Economics. New York: McGraw Hill.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1967. Full Employment, Guideposts, and Economic Stability. A Debate between Paul Samuelson and Arthur Burns. Washington DC: American Enterprise Institute.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. and Solow, Robert M. 1960. “Analytical Aspects of Anti-inflation Policy.” American Economic Review 50 (2): 177–194.Google Scholar
Santomero, Anthony M. and Seater, John. J. 1978. “The Inflation–Unemployment Trade-off: A Critique of the Literature.” Journal of Economic Literature: 16: 499–544.Google Scholar
Sargan, J. Dennis. 1964. “Wages and Prices in the United Kingdom: A Study in Econometric Methodology.” In Hart, P., Mills, G. and Whitaker, J., eds., Econometric Analysis for National Economic Planning. London: Butterworths.Google Scholar
Sawyer, Malcolm C. 1985. “On the Nature of the Phillips Curve.” British Review of Economic Issues 7 (16): 63–86.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1948. The American Economy. New York: Alfred Knopf.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1952. “How Bad Is Inflation?Harper’s Magazine (205): 53–57.Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1954. “Do the Wage Fixing Arrangements in the American Labor Market Have an Inflationary Bias?American Economic Review XLIV (May).Google Scholar
Slichter, Sumner H. 1957. “Thinking Ahead.” Harvard Business Review (Sept/Oct): 15–169.Google Scholar
Smith, David C. 1968. “Incomes Policy.” In Caves, R. and Krause, L. B., eds., Britain’s Economic Prospects. Washington DC: Brookings, pp. 104–146.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1968. “Recent Controversy on the Theory of Inflation: An Eclectic View.” In Rousseas, S. W., ed., Inflation: Its Causes, Consequences, and Control. Wilton, Connecticut: Calvin K Kazanjian Economics Foundation.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1969. Price Expectations and the Behaviour of the Price Level. Manchester: Manchester University Press.Google Scholar
Stein, Herbert. 1969. The Fiscal Revolution in America. Chicago: University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Stewart, Michael. 1977. The Jekyll and Hyde Years. Oxford: Pergamon.Google Scholar
Sultan, Paul E. 1957. Labor Economics. New York: Holt.Google Scholar
Sumner, Michael T. 1984. “The History and Significance of the Phillips Curve.” In Demery, D., ed., Surveys in Economics: Macroeconomics. London: Longman, pp. 169–225.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, Jan. 1937. An Econometric Approach to Business Cycle Problems. Paris: Hermann.Google Scholar
Tinbergen, Jan. 1951. Business Cycles in the United Kingdom, 1870–1914. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1972a. “Friedman’s Theoretical Framework.” Journal of Political Economy 80 (5): 1–18.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tobin, James. 1972b. “Inflation and Unemployment.” American Economic Review 62: 1–18.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1972c. The New Economics One Decade Older. Princeton NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. [1985] 2005. “My Evolution as an Economist. A Lecture Delivered at Trinity University, San Antonio, Texas.” In Breit, William and Hirsch, Barry T., eds. Lives of the Laureates, Boston: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Tobin, James. 1995. “The Natural Rate as New Classical Macroeconomics.” In Cross, R., ed., The Natural Rate of Unemployment. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, pp. 32–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tobin, James and Ross, Leonard. 1971. “Living with Inflation.” New York Review of Books 16 (8): 23–26.Google Scholar
Vanderkamp, John. 1966. “Wage and Price Level Determinants: An Empirical Model for Canada.” Economica 33 (May): 194–218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vickrey, William S. 1955. “Stability through Inflation.” In Kurihara, K.K., ed., Post-Keynesian Economics. London: Macmillan, pp. 89–122.Google Scholar
Watanabe, Tsunehiko. 1966. “Price Changes and the Rate of Change of Money Wage Earnings in Japan 1955–1962.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 31–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wulwick, Nancy J. 1987. “The Phillips Curve: Which? Whose? To Do What? How?Southern Economic Journal 53 (4): 834–857.CrossRefGoogle Scholar