Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-m6dg7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T05:36:30.329Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Prospect Theory and the Disposition Effect

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 April 2010

Markku Kaustia*
Affiliation:
Aalto University, School of Economics, PO Box 21210, FI-00076 AALTO, Helsinki, Finland. [email protected]

Abstract

This paper shows that prospect theory is unlikely to explain the disposition effect. Prospect theory predicts that the propensity to sell a stock declines as its price moves away from the purchase price in either direction. Trading data, on the other hand, show that the propensity to sell jumps at zero return, but it is approximately constant over a wide range of losses and increasing or constant over a wide range of gains. Further, the pattern of realized returns does not seem to stem from optimal after-tax portfolio rebalancing, a belief in mean-reverting returns, or investors acting on target prices.

Type
Research Articles
Copyright
Copyright © Michael G. Foster School of Business, University of Washington 2010

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Andreassen, P. B. “Explaining the Price-Volume Relationship: The Difference between Price Changes and Changing Prices.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 41 (1988), 371389.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arkes, H. R., and Blumer, C.. “The Psychology of Sunk Cost.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 35 (1985), 124140.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arkes, H. R.; Hirshleifer, D.; Jiang, D.; and Lim, S.. “Reference Point Adaptation: Tests in the Domain of Security Trading.” Organizational Behavior and Human Decision Processes, 105 (2008), 6781.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N., and Huang, M.. “Mental Accounting, Loss Aversion, and Individual Stock Returns.” Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 12471292.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N.; Huang, M.; and Santos, T.. “Prospect Theory and Asset Prices.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (2001), 153.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barberis, N., and Xiong, W.. “What Drives the Disposition Effect? An Analysis of a Long-Standing Preference-Based Explanation.” Journal of Finance 64 (2009), 751784.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Benartzi, S., and Thaler, R. H.. “Myopic Loss Aversion and the Equity Premium Puzzle.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110 (1995), 7392.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berkelaar, A. B.; Kouwenberg, R.; and Post, T.. “Optimal Portfolio Choice under Loss Aversion.” Review of Economics and Statistics, 86 (2004), 973987.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brav, A., and Lehavy, R.. “An Empirical Analysis of Analysts’ Target Prices: Short-Term Informativeness and Long-Term Dynamics.” Journal of Finance, 58 (2003), 19331967.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Brockner, J. “The Escalation of Commitment to a Failing Course of Action: Toward Theoretical Progress.” Academy of Management Review, 17 (1992), 3961.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Constantinides, G. M. “Capital Market Equilibrium with Personal Tax.” Econometrica, 51 (1983), 611636.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dammon, R. M.; Spatt, C. S.; and Zhang, H. H.. “Optimal Consumption and Investment with Capital Gains Taxes.” Review of Financial Studies, 14 (2001), 583616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dhar, R., and Zhu, N.. “Up Close and Personal? An Individual Level Analysis of the Disposition Effect.” Management Science, 52 (2006), 726740.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Festinger, L. A Theory of Cognitive Dissonance. Stanford, CA: Stanford University Press (1957).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frino, A.; Johnstone, D.; and Zheng, H.. “The Propensity for Local Traders in Futures Markets to Ride Losses: Evidence of Irrational or Rational Behavior?Journal of Banking and Finance, 28 (2004), 353372.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Genesove, D., and Mayer, C.. “Loss Aversion and Seller Behavior: Evidence from the Housing Market.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116 (2001), 12331260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gomes, F. J. “Portfolio Choice and Trading Volume with Loss-Averse Investors.” Journal of Business, 78 (2005), 675706.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grinblatt, M., and Han, B.. “Prospect Theory, Mental Accounting, and Momentum.” Journal of Financial Economics, 78 (2005), 311339.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grinblatt, M., and Keloharju, M.. “The Investment Behavior and Performance of Various Investor Types: A Study of Finland’s Unique Data Set.” Journal of Financial Economics, 55 (2000), 4367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grinblatt, M., and Keloharju, M.. “What Makes Investors Trade?Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 589616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Grinblatt, M., and Keloharju, M.. “Tax-Loss Trading and Wash Sales.” Journal of Financial Economics, 71 (2004), 5176.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Harris, M., and Raviv, A.. “Differences of Opinion Make a Horse Race.” Review of Financial Studies, 6 (1993), 473506.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heisler, J. “Loss Aversion in a Futures Market: An Empirical Test.” Review of Futures Markets, 13 (1994), 793822.Google Scholar
Hens, T., and Vlcek, M.. “Does Prospect Theory Explain the Disposition Effect?” Discussion Paper No. 18, Norwegian School of Economics and Business Administration (2005).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hirshleifer, D. “Investor Psychology and Asset Pricing.” Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), 15331597.Google Scholar
Ivković, Z.; Poterba, J.; and Weisbenner, S.. “Tax-Motivated Trading by Individual Investors.” American Economic Review, 95 (2005), 16051630.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kahneman, D., and Tversky, A.. “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk.” Econometrica, 47 (1979), 263291.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lakonishok, J., and Smidt, S.. “Volume for Winners and Losers: Taxation and Other Motives for Stock Trading.” Journal of Finance, 41 (1986), 951974.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laury, S. K., and Holt, C. A.. “Further Reflections on the Reflection Effect.” In Risk Aversion in Experiments, Research in Experimental Economics, Vol. 12, Cox, J. C. and Harrison, G. W., eds. Bingley, UK: Emerald (2008), 405440.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Locke, P. R., and Mann, S. C.. “Professional Trader Discipline and Trade Disposition.” Journal of Financial Economics, 76 (2005), 401444.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Myagkov, M., and Plott, C. R.. “Exchange Economies and Loss Exposure: Experiments Exploring Prospect Theory and Competitive Equilibria in Market Environments.” American Economic Review, 87 (1997), 801828.Google Scholar
Odean, T. “Are Investors Reluctant to Realize Their Losses?Journal of Finance, 53 (1998), 17751798.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odean, T. “Do Investors Trade Too Much?American Economic Review, 89 (1999), 12791298.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rubin, J. Z., and Brockner, J.. “Factors Affecting Entrapment in Waiting Situations: The Rosencrantz and Guildenstern Effect.” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 31 (1975), 10541063.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schlarbaum, G. G.; Lewellen, W. G.; and Lease, R. C.. “Realized Returns on Common Stock Investments: The Experience of Individual Investors.” Journal of Business, 51 (1978), 299325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapira, Z., and Venezia, I.. “Patterns of Behavior of Professionally Managed and Independent Investors.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 25 (2001), 15731587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shefrin, H., and Statman, M.. “The Disposition to Sell Winners Too Early and Ride Losers Too Long: Theory and Evidence.” Journal of Finance, 40 (1985), 777790.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Staw, B. M. “The Escalation of Commitment to a Course of Action.” Academy of Management Review, 6 (1981), 577587.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. “Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 1 (1980), 3960.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H. “Mental Accounting Matters.” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making, 12 (1999), 183206.3.0.CO;2-F>CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thaler, R. H., and Johnson, E. J.. “Gambling with the House Money and Trying to Break Even: The Effects of Prior Outcomes on Risky Choice.” Management Science, 36 (1990), 643660.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D.. “The Framing of Decisions and the Psychology of Choice.” Science, 211 (1981), 453458.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Tversky, A., and Kahneman, D.. “Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5 (1992), 297323.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M., and Camerer, C. F.. “The Disposition Effect in Securities Trading: An Experimental Analysis.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, 33 (1998), 167184.CrossRefGoogle Scholar