Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jn8rn Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-24T01:15:18.126Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

A bold strategy is not always optimal in the presence of inflation

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  14 July 2016

Robert W. Chen*
Affiliation:
University of Miami
Larry A. Shepp*
Affiliation:
Rutgers University
Alan Zame*
Affiliation:
University of Miami
*
Postal address: Department of Mathematics, University of Miami, Coral Gables, FL 33124-4250, USA.
∗∗∗ Postal address: Department of Statistics, Rutgers University, 110 Frelinghuysen Road, Piscataway, NJ 08854, USA.
Postal address: Department of Mathematics, University of Miami, Coral Gables, FL 33124-4250, USA.

Abstract

A gambler, with an initial fortune less than 1, wants to buy a house which sells today for 1. Due to inflation, the price of the house tomorrow will be 1 + α, where α is a nonnegative constant, and will continue to go up at this rate, becoming (1 + α) n on the nth day. Once each day, he can stake any amount of fortune in his possession, but no more than he possesses, on a primitive casino. It is well known that, in a subfair primitive casino without the presence of inflation, the gambler should play boldly. The presence of inflation would motivate the gambler to recognize the time value of his fortune and to try to reach his goal as quickly as possible; intuitively, we would conjecture that the gambler should again play boldly. However, in this note we will show that, unexpectedly, bold play is not necessarily optimal.

Type
Short Communications
Copyright
Copyright © Applied Probability Trust 2004 

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Berry, D. A., Heath, D. C., and Sudderth, W. D. (1974). Red-and-black with unknown win probability. Ann. Statist. 2, 602608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chen, R. (1977). Subfair primitive casino with a discount factor. Z. Wahrscheinlichkeitsth. 39, 167174.Google Scholar
Chen, R. (1978). Subfair ‘red-and-black’ in the presence of inflation. Z. Wahrscheinlichkeitsth. 42, 293301.Google Scholar
Chen, R., and Zame, A. (1979). On discounted subfair primitive casino. Z. Wahrscheinlichkeitsth. 49, 257266.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coolidge, J. L. (1909). The gambler's ruin. Ann. Math. (2) 10, 181192.Google Scholar
Dubins, L. E., and Savage, L. J. (1965). How To Gamble If You Must, Inequalities for Stochastic Processes. McGraw-Hill, New York.Google Scholar
Dubins, L. E., and Teicher, H. (1967). Optimal stopping when the future is discounted. Ann. Math. Statist. 38, 601605.Google Scholar
Heath, D. C., Pruitt, W. E., and Sudderth, W. D. (1972). Subfair red-and-black with a limit. Proc. Amer. Math. Soc. 35, 555560.Google Scholar
Klugman, S. (1977). Discounted and rapid subfair red-and-black. Ann. Statist. 5, 734745.CrossRefGoogle Scholar