Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dlnhk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T05:47:03.743Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Veto Players and the Choice of Monetary Institutions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 July 2003

Get access

Abstract

I argue that two types of veto players matter in the choice of monetary institutions: party veto players and subnational governments, which are strong in federal systems but weak in unitary systems. A crucial issue is whether voters can readily identify the manipulation of the economy with party players. A second issue concerns the national party veto player's ability to control either fiscal or monetary policy. In one-party unitary governments identification and control are clear; parties where such governments are common prefer flexible exchange rates and dependent central banks. In multiparty coalition governments in unitary systems, identification is traditionally difficult, and the ability to target benefits to specific constituencies under fiscal policy makes fiscal policy autonomy more attractive for coalition governments. Such governments prefer central banks that are politically independent but that finance government debt. Under federalism, parties that constitute the central government have less control over fiscal policy and they prefer flexible exchange rates. Subnational governments do not support a dependent central bank that gives more power to the central government.

Type
Research Article
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 2002

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, Alberto, Roubini, Nouriel and Cohen, Gerald D.. 1997. Political Cycles and the Macroeconomy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, Alberto, and Summers, Lawrence. 1993. Central Bank Independence and Macroeconomic Performance: Some Comparative Evidence. Journal of Money, Credit, and Banking 25 (2):151–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andrews, David M. 1994. Capital Mobility and State Autonomy: Toward a Structural Theory of International Monetary Relations. International Studies Quarterly 38 (2):193218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bearce, David H. 2002. Monetary Divergence: Domestic Political Institutions and the Monetary Autonomy-Exchange Rate Stability Trade-Off. Comparative Political Studies 35 (2):194220.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berger, Helge, de Haan, Jakob, and Eijffinger, Sylvester C.W.. 2001. Central Bank Independence: An Update of Theory and Evidence. Journal of Economic Surveys 15 (1):340.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, William. 1998. A Political Explanation of Variations in Central Bank Independence. American Political Science Review. 92 (2):311–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, William, and Leblang, David. 1999. Democratic Institutions and Exchange-Rate Commitments. International Organization. 53 (1):7197.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bernhard, William, and Leblang, David. 2002. Political Parties and Monetary Commitments. International Organization 56 (4):803–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birchfield, Vicki, and Crepaz, Markus M. L.. 1998. The Impact of Constitutional Structures and Collective and Competitive Veto Points on Income Inequality in Industrialized Democracies. European Journal of Political Research. 34 (2):175200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broz, Lawrence. 2002. Political System Transparency and Monetary Commitment Regimes. International Organization 56 (4):863–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, William Roberts. Partisan and Electoral Motivations and the Choice of Monetary Institutions Under Fully Mobile Capital. International Organization 56 (4):725–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, William Roberts, and Hallerberg, Mark. 2000. Strategic Interaction between Monetary and Fiscal Actors Under Full Capital Mobility. American Political Science Review 94 (2):323–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Clark, William Roberts, and Hallerberg, Mark. Forthcoming 2003. Structuring Strategies: Capital Mobility, Central Bank Independence, and the Political Control of the Economy. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Benjamin. 1998. The Geography of Money. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Benjamin. Forthcoming 2003. Governance in a Global Economy. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Crepaz, Markus M.L. 2002. Global, Constitutional, and Partisan Determinants of Redistribution in 15 OECD Countries. Comparative Politics. 34 (2):169–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cukierman, Alex. 1992. Central Bank Strategy, Credibility, and Independence: Theory and Evidence. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Duverger, Maurice. 1954. Political Parties. Their Organization and Activity in the Modern State. New York: Wiley.Google Scholar
Edwards, Sebastian. 1999. The Choice of Exchange Rate Regime in Developing and Middle Income Countries. In Changes in Exchange Rates in Rapidly Developing Countries, edited by Ito, Takatoshi and Krueger, Anne O., 927. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Eijffinger, Sylvester and van Keulen, Martijn. 1995. Central Bank Independence in Another Eleven Countries. Banca Nazionale del Lavoro Quarterly Review. 192:3983.Google Scholar
Fleming, J. Marcus. 1962. Domestic Financial Policies Under Fixed And Floating Exchange Rates. IMF Staff Papers 9 (3):369–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. 1999. Partially Independent Central Banks, Politically Responsive Governments, and Inflation. American Journal of Political Science. 43 (3):681706.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. 2000. Multiple Hands on the Wheel: Exchange-Rate Regimes, International Financial Exposure, Central Bank Autonomy and Inflation in the Open Economy. Paper presented at the 97th American Political Science Association Meetings, Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
Frieden, Jeffry A. 1991. Invested Interests: The Politics of National Economic Policies in a World of Global Finance. International Organization 45 (4):425–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. 1994. Exchange Rate Politics: Contemporary Lessons from American History. Review of International Political Economy. 1 (1):81103.Google Scholar
Goodhart, Lucy. 2000. Political Institutions and Monetary Policy. Unpublished manuscript, Harvard University, Cambridge, Mass.Google Scholar
Grilli, Vitorio, Masciandaro, Donato, and Tabellini, Guido. 1991. Political and Monetary Institutions and Public Financial Policies in the Industrial Countries. Economic Policy 13:342–92.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, Mark. 2000. Electoral Laws, Government Formation, and the Organization of Parliament: The Centrality of Common Pool Resource Problems. Paper presented at The Meeting of European and American Legislative Specialists Parliamentary Organisation and Legislative Outcomes in Western Europe, 20–24 October 2000, Potsdam, Germany.Google Scholar
Hallerberg, Mark, and Clark, William Roberts. 1997. How Should Political Scientists Measure Capital Mobility? Paper presented at the 94th Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.Google Scholar
Hansen, Susan B. 1999. “Life Is Not Fair:” Governors' Job Performance Ratings and State Economies. Political Research Quarterly 52 (1):167–88.Google Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas A. 1977. Political Parties and Macroeconomic Policy. American Political Science Review 71 (4):1467–87.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Independent Commission on the Voting System. 1998. Report of the Independent Commission on the Voting System. Presented to Parliament by the Secretary of State for the Home Department by Command of her Majesty (October). Available from ⟨http://www.official-documents.co.uk/document/cm40/4090/contents.htm⟩. Accessed 2 February 2001.Google Scholar
Keefer, Philip, and Stasavage, David. 2002. Checks and Balances, Asymmetric Information, and the Credibility of Monetary Commitments. International Organization 56 (4):751–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiewiet, D. Roderick, and McCubbins, Mathew D.. 1988. Presidential Influence on Congressional Appropriations Decisions. American Journal of Political Science. 32 (3):713–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1999. Patterns of Democracy: Government Forms and Performance in Thirty-Six Countries. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1998a. Federalism and Central Bank Independence: The Politics of German Monetary Policy, 1957–92. World Politics 50 (3):401–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lohmann, Susanne. 1998b. Institutional Checks and Balances and the Political Control of the Money Supply. Oxford Economic Papers 50 (3):360–77.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, David R. 1974. Congress: The Electoral Connection. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McNamara, Kathleen R. 1998. The Currency of Ideas: Monetary Politics in the European Union. Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Milesi-Ferretti, Gian Maria, Perotti, Roberto, and Rostagno, Massimo. 1999. Electoral Systems and the Composition of Public Spending. Paper presented at the Conference on the Impact of Increased Economic Integration on Italy and the Rest of Europe, 30 April–2 May, Georgetown University, Washington D.C.Google Scholar
Moser, Peter. 1999. Checks and Balances, and the Supply of Central Bank Independence. European Economic Review 43 (8):1569–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moser, Peter. 2000. The Political Economy of Democratic Institutions. Northampton, Mass.: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Moser, Peter. 1963. Capital Mobility and Stabilization Policy Under Fixed and Flexible Exchange Rates. Canadian Journal of Economics and Political Science 29 (4):475–85.Google Scholar
Newman, Gerard. 1999. Federal Election Results 1949–1998. Parliament of Australia Research Paper 8. Available from ⟨http://www.aph.gov.au⟩. Accessed February 2, 2001.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Posen, Adam. 1993. Why Central Bank Independence Does Not Cause Low Inflation: There Is No Institutional Fix for Politics. In Finance and the International Economy, Vol. 7, edited by O'Brien, Richard, 4165. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Simmons, Beth A. 1994. Who Adjusts? Domestic Sources of Foreign Economic Policy During the Interwar Years, 1924–1939. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taagepera, Rein, and Shugart, Matthew Soberg. 1989. Seats and Votes: The Effects and Determinants of Electoral Systems. New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Tabellini, Guido. 2000. Constitutional Determinants of Government Spending. Unpublished manuscript, Department of Economics, Bocconi University, Milan, Italy.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 1995. Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism and Multipartyism. British Journal of Political Science 25 (3):289325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 1999. Veto Players and Law Production in Parliamentary Democracies: An Empirical Analysis. American Political Science Review 93 (3):591608.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 2001. Veto Players: How Political Institutions Work and Why. Unpublished manuscript, University of California, Los Angeles.Google Scholar
Tsebelis, George, and Money, Jeanette. 1997. Bicameralism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Whitten, Guy B., and Powell, G. Bingham. 1993. A Cross-National Analysis of Economic Voting: Taking Account of the Political Context. American Journal of Political Science. 37 (2):391414.Google Scholar
Woldendorp, Jaap, Keman, Hans, and Budge, Ian. 1998. Party Government in 20 Democracies: An Update (1990–1995). European Journal of Political Research 33 (1):125–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar