Article contents
Discounting the free ride: alliances and security in the postwar world
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 22 May 2009
Extract
The collective goods theory of alliances and neorealist theory yield conflicting expectations about the security policies of states. The former emphasizes the temptation to “ride free” on the efforts of others, while the latter emphasizes the incentives for self-help. In the cases of Britain, China, and France during the early cold war, the constraints identified by neorealist theory, reinforced by the advent of nuclear weapons, prevailed. Each discounted the value of the security benefits superpower partners could provide. The second-ranking powers' decisions to shoulder the burden of developing independent nuclear forces are at odds with collective goods arguments that portray especially strong temptations to ride free in the circumstances that prevailed at that time—an international system dominated by two superpowers, each possessing large nuclear deterrent arsenals that could easily be employed on behalf of allies. This analysis suggests that present efforts to discourage additional states from acquiring nuclear weapons by offering them international security guarantees are unlikely to succeed.
- Type
- Articles
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © The IO Foundation 1995
References
I thank Jean-Marc Blanchard, Tom Christensen, Joanne Gowa, Ed Mansfield, Norrin Ripsman, and several anonymous reviewers for their comments on various drafts of this article. A University of Pennsylvania Research Foundation grant supported my research and travel. I also thank the following host institutions in China for their hospitality in facilitating twenty-six hours of discussions with Chinese military officers, researchers, and academics during April and May 1991: the National Defense University, the Academy of Military Sciences, the Beijing Institute for International Strategic Studies, the Foundation for International and Strategic Studies, the Institute of American Studies at the Chinese Academy of Social Sciences, the China Institute of International Studies, the China Institute of Contemporary International Relations, the China World Watch Institute (formerly Institute of International Strategy in the Future), and the China National Association of Peaceful Utilization for Military Technology.
1. Olson, Mancur and Zeckhauser, Richard, “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” Review of Economics and Statistics 48 (08 1966), pp. 266–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
2. See Boyer, Mark A., International Cooperation and Public Goods (Baltimore, Md.: The Johns Hopkins University Press, 1993)Google Scholar; Gates, William R. and Terasawa, Katsuaki L., “Commitment, Threat Perceptions, and Expenditures in a Defense Alliance,” International Studies Quarterly 36 (03 1992), pp. 101–18CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Hildebrandt, Gregory G., Measuring the Burden of Alliance Activities, Rand Note, doc. N-3048-PCT (Santa Monica, Calif.: Rand Corp., 09 1990)Google Scholar; Murdoch, James C. and Sandler, Todd, “A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of NATO,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 26 (06 1982), pp. 237–63CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Oneal, John R., “The Theory of Collective Action and Burden Sharing in NATO,” International Organization 44 (Summer 1990), pp. 379–402CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Oneal, John R. and Elrod, Mark A., “NATO Burden Sharing and the Forces of Change,” International Studies Quarterly 33 (12 1989), pp. 435–56CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Russett, Bruce M., at Price Vigilance (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1970)Google Scholar; Sandler, Todd, “Impurity of Defense: An Application to the Economics of Alliances,” Kyklos vol. 30, no. 3, 1977, pp. 443–60CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sandler, Todd and Cauley, Jon, “On the Economic Theory of Alliances,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 19 (06 1975), pp. 330–48CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Sandler, Todd and Forbes, John F., “Burden Sharing, Strategy, and the Design of NATO,” Economic Inquiry 18 (07 1980), pp. 425–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Thies, Wallace J., “Alliances and Collective Goods,” Journal of Conflict Resolution 31 (06 1987), pp. 298–322CrossRefGoogle Scholar; van, JacquesStrihou, Ypserle de, “Sharing the Defense Burden Among Western Allies,” Review of Economics and Statistics 49 (11 1967), pp. 527–36Google Scholar; and Strihou, Jacques van Ypserle de, “Comment,” in McKean, Roland N., ed., Issues in Defense Economics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1967), pp. 58–63.Google Scholar
3. Olson and Zeckhauser, “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” pp. 272–73. The theory of collective action itself, on which Olson and Zeckhauser's collective goods theory of alliances is based, acknowledges that few goods meet the strictest definition of a public good. Referring to Paul Samuelson's classic work and Richard Musgrave's and John G. Head's discussions of it, Olson noted that the twin defining characteristics of a public good, nonexcludability and jointness of supply (nonrival consumption), are rarely exhibited in the real world. He emphasizes infeasibility of exclusion as the key defining feature of collective goods, though many also exhibit “a large measure of jointness.” Indeed, with regard to the cases under examination in this essay, in which the collective good of alliance security is supplied by nuclear deterrent forces, the requirement of jointness of supply or nonrival consumption poses few problems, as noted below. On the real-world appearance of public goods, see Olson, Mancur, The Logic of Collective Action, rev. ed. (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1971), pp. 14Google Scholar, n. 21; 28, n. 44; and 40, n. 61. Also see Buchanan, James M., “An Economic Theory of Clubs,” in Russett, Bruce M., ed., Economic Theories of International Politics (Chicago: Markham Publishing Company, 1968), pp. 51–63.Google Scholar On the infeasibility of exclusion, see Olson, , The Logic of Collective Action, pp. 14–15 n. 21.Google Scholar
4. See van Ypserle de Strihou, “Sharing the Defense Burden Among Western Allies,” p. 530; Oneal and Elrod, “NATO Burden Sharing and the Forces of Change,” pp. 445–47; Murdoch and Sandler, “A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of NATO”; and Oneal, “The Theory of Collective Action and Burden Sharing in NATO.”
5. Cf. van Ypserle de Strihou, “Sharing the Defense Burden Among Western Allies,” pp. 535–36.
6. See van Ypserle de Strihou, “Comment”; Sandler and Cauley, “On the Economic Theory of Alliances,” p. 334; and Sandler, “Impurity of Defense,” pp. 447–48. This expectation of greater free riding in the 1950s seems to hold even for Mark Boyer, who includes allies' nonmilitary contributions. See Boyer, , International Cooperation and Public Goods, pp. 84–85.Google Scholar
7. A few participants in this scholarly debate briefly noted the problematic assumption of nonexclusiveness even with regard to deterrence-based alliance strategies, but the implications of this observation for the usefulness of the public goods theory of alliances were not fully explored. See especially van Ypserle de Strihou, “Comment,” pp. 60–62; but also Sandler and Cauley, “On the Economic Theory of Alliances,” p. 335, n. 6; Russett, , What Price Vigilance, p. 95Google Scholar; Sandler and Forbes, “Burden Sharing, Strategy, and the Design of NATO,” p. 427; Oneal and Elrod, “NATO Burden Sharing and the Forces of Change,” p. 440; and Oneal, “The Theory of Collective Action and Burden Sharing in NATO,” p. 384. For an argument linking the purity of the public good to the substitutability of allies' forces rather than the distinction between deterrent and defensive strategies, see Thies, “Alliances and Collective Goods,” pp. 328–29.
8. Murdoch and Sandler and to some extent Oneal and Elrod emphasize the changing military strategy. See Murdoch and Sandler, “A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis of NATO”; and Oneal and Elrod, “NATO Burden Sharing and the Forces of Change.” Oneal and Elrod, however, defended the central assertions of Olson and Zeckhauser's theory by noting that disproportionality in burden sharing persisted after the mid-1960s even if the extent of free riding did lessen somewhat. Gates and Terasawa, focusing not on weapons systems or strategy per se but on the extent to which levels of commitment affect the public good character of security benefits supplied by allies, explored doubts about U.S. commitment to NATO that developed only after 1970. See Gates and Terasawa, “Commitment, Threat Perceptions, and Expenditures in a Defense Alliance.”
9. Oneal, “The Theory of Collective Action and Burden Sharing in NATO,” pp. 381–82 and 387–88.
10. For an extreme example of the difficulties in estimating expenditures by China, see Goldstein, Avery, “Robust and Affordable Security: Some Lessons from the Second-ranking Powers During the Cold War,” The Journal of Strategic Studies 15 (12 1992), pp. 475–527CrossRefGoogle Scholar and p. 507 n. 8 in particular.
11. Moreover, a definition of burden sharing that restricts itself to military spending ignores the nonmilitary contributions allies may make to comprehensive security. See Boyer, International Cooperation and Public Goods.
12. Olson and Zeckhauser, “An Economic Theory of Alliances,” p. 266. For exceptions to the almost exclusive focus on NATO in the debate about the collective goods theory of alliances, see Thies, “Alliances and Collective Goods”; and Morrow, James D., “Alliances and Asymmetry: An Alternative to the Capability Aggregation Model of Alliances,” American Journal of Political Science 35 (11 1991), pp. 904–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
13. Some argue that significantly outgunned nuclear powers cannot credibly deter their adversary. For consideration of these arguments, as well as the British, Chinese, and French belief that relatively small nuclear deterrents did enable them to dissuade a superpower adversary, see Goldstein, “Robust and Affordable Security.”
14. On the nonsecurity motives for developing nuclear weapons, see Ibid., p. 506 n. 1; and Goldstein, Avery, “Understanding Nuclear Proliferation: Theoretical Explanation and China's National Experience,” Security Studies 2 (Spring/Summer 1993), pp. 218–19Google Scholar and 233–34.
15. Two traditional great powers, Britain and France, continued their interwar relative decline. The one anointed great power, China, failed to fulfill its promise. At first, China was represented in the UN by the Kuomintang regime, which was then presiding over a civil war torn country. Later, it was represented by the Kuomintang government in exile on Taiwan. After 1971, the effective rulers of the mainland, the Communists, assumed their international role as representatives of China, but the country's weak economic foundation limited its international clout, despite ample territory and a large population. Ironically, the two defeated great powers, Germany and Japan, would reemerge phoenix-like from the ashes of their wartime destruction. See Organski, A. F. K. and Kugler, Jacek, The War Ledger (Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1980)Google Scholar, chap. 3. But through the late 1980s, at least, international and domestic political constraints prevented them from translating their economic capabilities into international political influence.
16. I use the term “bipolarity” to signify the distribution of capabilities in the international system, not the extent of ideological polarization associated with the cold war or the tightness of security alignments in which less powerful actors associated themselves with one of the superpowers. Bipolarity is used here simply to indicate that despite variations in the ability to manage their respective alliance partners and impose solutions on regional actors, in the postwar world the Soviet Union and the United States were set apart by their capacity to influence, though not control, events around the globe.
17. Snyder, Glenn H., “The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics,” World Politics 36 (07 1984), pp. 461–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Also see Christensen, Thomas J. and Snyder, Jack, “Chain Gangs and Passed Bucks: Predicting Alliance Patterns in Multipolarity,” International Organization 44 (Spring 1990), pp. 137–68.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
18. See Morgenthau, Hans, Politics Among Nations, 5th ed. (New York: Knopf, 1973)Google Scholar, chaps. 11–14; and Waltz, Kenneth M., Theory of International Politics (Menlo Park, Calif.: Addison-Wesley, 1979), chap. 6.Google Scholar
19. On the distinction between intrinsic military value and reputational value, see Snyder, Glenn H., Deterrence and Defense (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1961), pp. 30–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar On the interdependence of commitments, see Schelling, Thomas C., Arms and Influence (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1966), pp. 55–59Google Scholar and 116–25. On the complexity of manipulating perceptions of a state's reputation, see the discussion of Robert Jervis's reputational paradox in Nalebuff, Barry, “Rational Deterrence in an Imperfect World,” World Politics 43 (04 1991), pp. 313–35.CrossRefGoogle Scholar The reputational stakes are raised not only by the strategic effects of the nuclear revolution but also by bipolarity that enhances the apparent zero-sumness of international political competition between the duopolists. See Waltz, , Theory of International Politics, pp. 170–72.Google Scholar
20. With the outbreak of the Korean War, the U.S. Seventh Fleet positioned itself in the Taiwan Straits and General MacArthur advanced toward the Yalu. This began a sequence of events during the decade that clarified the seriousness of the military threat the United States posed to Chinese national interests. For a recent review of the Chinese perception of the U.S. threat in the early 1950s, see Hao, Y. F. and Zhai, Z. H., “China's Decision to Enter the Korean War: History Revisited,” China Quarterly 121 (03 1990), pp. 94–115.Google Scholar See also Christensen, Thomas J., “Threats, Assurances, and the Last Chance for Peace: The Lessons of Mao's Korean War Telegrams,” International Security 17 (Summer 1992), pp. 122–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
21. U.S. nuclear threats were reflected both in declaratory policy in the Truman and Eisenhower administrations and in the deployment of nuclear-capable forces to the East Asian theater. See Lewis, John W. and Xue, Litai, China Builds the Bomb (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1988), p. 229Google Scholar; Lin, Chong-pin, China Nuclear Weapons Strategy (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1988), p. 77Google Scholar; Betts, Richard K., Nuclear Blackmail and Nuclear Balance (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1987)Google Scholar, chaps. 1 and 2; Trachtenberg, Marc, “A ‘Wasting Asset’: American Strategy and the Shifting Nuclear Balance, 1949–1954,” International Security 13 (Winter 1988/1989), pp. 5–49CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Dingman, Roger, “Atomic Diplomacy During the Korean War,” International Security 13 (Winter 1988/1989), pp. 50–91CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Foot, Rosemary J., “Nuclear Coercion and the Ending of the Korean Conflict,” International Security 13 (Winter, 1988/1989), pp. 92–112.CrossRefGoogle Scholar China's threat perceptions were also based on the U.S. rhetoric about rolling back the postwar gains of communism and by the U.S. signing of a security treaty with and arming a regime on Taiwan dedicated to reversing the outcome of the Chinese Civil War. For a detailed survey of Sino—American threat perceptions during this period, see Zhang, Shu Guang, Deterrence and Strategic Culture: Chinese-American Confrontations, 1949–1958 (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1992)Google Scholar; and Li, Yuanchao, “The Politics of Artillery Shelling: A Study of the Taiwan Strait Crises,” Beijing Review, 7 09 1992, pp. 32–38.Google Scholar Chinese attempts at a conciliatory approach represented by the spirit of Bandung bore no fruit in terms of dealing with the U.S. threat. See Nelsen, Harvey W., Power and Insecurity: Beijing, Moscow, and Washington, 1949–1988 (Boulder, Colo.: Lynne Rienner, 1989), pp. 38–40.Google Scholar
22. Thus, the ride was never completely free. Political, rather than economic, side-payments were required. I am indebted to Norrin Ripsman for reminding me of this subtlety. See also Boyer, International Cooperation and Public Goods.
23. See Nelsen, , Power and Insecurity, pp. 7 and 11Google Scholar; Christensen, Thomas J., “Domestic Mobilization and International Conflict: Sino-American Relations in the 1950s,” (Ph.D. Diss., Columbia University, New York, 1993), p. 453, n. 10.Google Scholar
24. See Zagoria, Donald, The Sino-Soviet Conflict, 1956–1961 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1962)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, chaps. 1–2 and 4; and Nelsen, , Power and Insecurity, p. 11.Google Scholar
25. See Jencks, Harlan, “People's War Under Modern Conditions: Wishful Thinking, National Suicide, or Effective Deterrent?” China Quarterly 98 (06 1984), pp. 307–8CrossRefGoogle Scholar, 309, and 316.
26. The limits on Chinese delivery capability before the 1980s are described in Lewis, John W. and Di, Hua, “China's Ballistic Missile Programs: Technologies, Strategies, Goals,” International Security 17 (Fall 1992), pp. 5–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar Chinese fears notwithstanding, if the American experience with nuclear superiority from the 1950s and early 1960s is a guide, even with a good chance at a successful first strike, Soviet leaders probably worried mainly about what might go wrong. See Betts, Nuclear Blackmail and Nuclear Balance; and Kaplan, Fred, The Wizards of Armageddon (New York: Simon and Schuster, 1983).Google Scholar
27. See Wang, Robert S., “China's Evolving Strategic Doctrine,” Asian Survey 24 (10 1984), pp. 1043–44CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Dittmer, Lowell, “The Strategic Triangle: An Elementary Game Theoretical Analysis,” World Politics 33 (07 1981), pp. 485–515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
28. See Harding, Harry, “The Domestic Politics of China's Global Posture,” in Fingar, Thomas, ed., China's Quest for Independence: Policy Evolution in the 1970s (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1980), pp. 97–102.Google Scholar
29. Ross, Robert S., “From Lin Biao to Deng Xiaoping: Elite Instability and China's U.S. Policy,” China Quarterly 118 (06 1989), pp. 280 and 276.CrossRefGoogle Scholar A similar emphasis was also evident in comments by Chinese leaders meeting with another U.S. congressional delegation in late 1976. See Ibid., p. 287. For a view that sees the Chinese as sticking to its nationalist principles, see Nelsen, , Power and Insecurity, pp. 101–2.Google Scholar
30. As one critical Chinese analyst put it, “although we have established strategic relations with the United States, our views are still divergent.… The United States has formulated the so-called ‘Taiwan Relations Act’ and violated the principle of the establishment of Sino–American diplomatic relations, and reneged on its commitment.” See Li, Dai, “Independence and China's External Relations,” Shijie Zhishi 19 (1 10 1981), p. A4Google Scholar, in Foreign Broadcast Information Service, China Daily Report (hereafter, FBIS), 19 11 1981Google Scholar.
31. See Ross, “From Lin Biao to Deng Xiaoping,” p. 291; and Nelsen, , Power and Insecurity, p. 134.Google Scholar
32. As Gallois noted, after World War II France's situation “precluded independence” and as a consequence, France's “Military Command progressively learned to rely on others for the defense of the country.” See Gallois, Pierre M., “French Defense Planning—The Future in the Past,” International Security 1 (Fall 1976), pp. 15–16.CrossRefGoogle Scholar See also Mendl, Wolf, Deterrence and Persuasion (New York: Praeger Publishers, 1970), pp. 19Google Scholar, 20, and 49.
33. On the economic and political frictions in Anglo–American relations in the early postwar period, see Bartlett, C. J., “The Special Relationship”: A Political History ofAnglo–American Relations since 1945 (London: Longman, 1992)Google Scholar, chap. 2; Baylis, John, Anglo–American Defense Relations, 1939–1984: The Special Relationship, 2d ed. (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1984)CrossRefGoogle Scholar, chap. 2; and Rosecrance, R. N., Defense of the Realm: British Strategy in the Nuclear Epoch (New York: Columbia University Press, 1968), pp. 44–46.Google Scholar
34. Baylis, John, British Defense Policy (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1989), p. 60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
35. Ibid., pp. 60–61.
36. Ibid., p. 63.
37. The quotations are from Christian de la Malène and Melnik, Constantine, Attitude of the French Parliament and Government Toward Atomic Weapons, doc. RM-2170-RC (Santa Monica, Calif.: Rand Corporation, 14 05 1958)Google Scholar, cited in Kohl, Wilfred L., French Nuclear Diplomacy (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1971) p. 33Google Scholar; and Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, p. 129Google Scholar, respectively; emphasis added. See also similar comments by French Premier Barre, Raymond, in “French Prime Minister on France's Nuclear Policy,” Xinhua General Overseas News Service (hereafter, Xinhua), 4 07 1977Google Scholar, Mead Data Central, Inc., NEXIS Library, NEWS, ALLNWS (hereafter, NEXIS).
38. Yost, David S., “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe, Part 1: Capabilities and Doctrine,” Adelphi Paper 194 (Winter 1984/1985), p. 6.Google Scholar
39. Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 140–48.Google Scholar
40. See Ullman, Richard H., “The Covert French Connection,” Foreign Policy 75 (Summer 1989), pp. 3–33CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Davidson, Ian, “France Rejoins Its Allies,” Financial Times, 3 05 1983, pp. 22ff.Google Scholar, NEXIS; and “Nuclear Secrets,” The Economist, 3 06 1989, pp. 29ff.Google Scholar, NEXIS.
41. See Chang, Gordon H., Friends and Enemies (Stanford, Calif.: Stanford University Press, 1990)Google Scholar, chaps. 4 and 5; and Zhang, Deterrence and Strategic Culture, chap. 8.
42. Zagoria, The Sino–Soviet Conflict 1956–1961, chap. 4.
43. Ibid., chap. 5.
44. Christensen, “Domestic Mobilization and International Conflict,” chap. 6.
45. Discussions with analysts in Beijing in 1991 at the institutions listed in the acknowledgments suggest there is room for debate over exactly what the Chinese expected the Soviets to do during the crisis. See also Chang, , Friends and Enemies, pp. 190–94Google Scholar; and Nelsen, , Power and Insecurity, pp. 41–45.Google Scholar
46. Mao's cautiousness in the face of U.S. nuclear threats contrasts sharply with his public posture of indifference and defiance. Circumspect behavior could have reflected either Mao's fear of U.S. might or, as Christensen's work suggests, his limited aim of provoking a war scare for domestic consumption, but no war. See Li, “The Politics of Artillery Shelling”; Zhang, Deterrence and Strategic Culture, chap. 8; and Christensen, “Domestic Mobilization and International Conflict,” chap. 6.
47. In the now famous line from foreign affairs minister Chen Yi, China would shoulder any burden necessary to bring the strategic weapons program to fruition, “even if the Chinese had to pawn their trousers for this purpose.” See Lewis and Xue, China Builds the Bomb, p. 130.
48. For an unusually explicit Chinese view of the nuclear threat posed by the Soviet Union beginning in 1969, see ”People's Daily Article: ‘Get Rid of Blind Belief in Nuclear Weapons,’” Xinhua, 14 May 1977, NEXIS.
49. Si, Chen, “Year Ender: Overall Strategic Considerations Should be Given Top Priority,” Xinhua, 20 12 1980Google Scholar, NEXIS; and “France Reorientates Strategy Against Soviet Threat,” Xinhua, 12 01 1977Google Scholar, NEXIS.
50. Garrett, Banning N. and Glaser, Bonnie S., War and Peace: The Views from Moscow and Beijing (Berkeley, Calif.: Institute of International Studies, 1984), p. 80.Google Scholar
51. See Segal, Gerald, “China's Strategic Posture and the Great-Power Triangle,” Pacific Affairs 53 (Winter 1980/1981), p. 693CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Garrett, and Glaser, , War and Peace, pp. 57–58 and 80.Google Scholar As part of this approach, China encouraged the strengthening of NATO, a move that would have, of course, limited the Soviets' ability to concentrate their resources against China on the eastern front. See John W. Lewis, “China's Military Doctrines and Force Posture,” in Fingar, , China's Quest for Independence, pp. 183–85Google Scholar; Ross, “From Lin Biao to Deng Xiaoping,” pp. 290–91; Qi, Ya and Zhou, Jirong, “Does the Soviet Union Have a Global Strategy,” Renmin Ribao, 20 05 1981Google Scholar, in FBIS, 21 May 1981, p. C4.
52. See Zong, He, “Changes and Development Trends in the International Situation,” Shijie Zhishi 11 (1 06 1983)Google Scholar, in FBIS, 21 July 1983, pp. A3–5; and Xing, Shuguang, Li, Yunhua, and Liu, Yingna, “Soviet–U.S. Balance of Power and its Impact on the World Situation in the 1980s,” Guoji Wenti Yanjiu (01 1983)Google Scholar, in FBIS, 21 April 1983, pp. A3–5. The Chinese also began to point out some of the limitations on Soviet power projection capabilities in the Far East owing to geography and the economic underdevelopment of Soviet Asia. See Xie, Wenqing, “U.S.–Soviet Military Contention in the Asia-Pacific Region,” Shijie Zhishi, 16 03 1987Google Scholar, in FBIS, 31 March 1987, pp. A2 and A5; and Jia, Bei, “Gorbachev's Policy Toward the Asian Pacific Region,” Guoji Wenti Yanjiu, 13 04 1987Google Scholar, in FBIS, 14 May 1987, pp. C8–14. In these circumstances, the Chinese felt less constrained to soft-peddle their objections to continued U.S. support of Taiwan. See Ross, “From Lin Biao to Deng Xiaoping,” p. 293.
53. On the U.S. self-interest in the security of Western Europe, see Walt, Stephen M., “The Case for Finite Containment: Analyzing U.S. Grand Strategy,” International Security 14 (Summer 1989), pp. 5–49.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
54. For Churchill's early postwar articulation of this concern, see Pierre, Andrew J., Nuclear Politics: The British Experience with an Independent Strategic Force (New York: Oxford University Press, 1974), pp. 68 and 82.Google Scholar
55. Lingering concerns about the future of U.S. commitments to Europe resurfaced in the mid-1980s, especially during the run-up to signing the Intermediate-range Nuclear Forces (INF) Treaty in 1987. See Housego, David, “French Army Sounds Alarm on Defence Cuts,” Financial Times, 7 12 1982, p. 2Google Scholar, NEXIS; Haydon, Simon, “France Boosts Nuclear Force Amid Worries Over Missile Deal,” The Reuter Library Report, 26 11 1987Google Scholar, NEXIS; and “Nuclear Deterrence Vital, Says Former French Prime Minister,” Xinhua, 29 12 1987Google Scholar, NEXIS.
56. On entrapment and abandonment, see Snyder, “The Security Dilemma in Alliance Politics.” On conflicting interests (because greater security for smaller allies might reduce security for the superpower patron), see van Ypserle de Strihou, “Comment,” p. 61. As mentioned below, and as Melissen and Wheeler each emphasize, the second-ranking powers at times also worried about entrapment. See Melissen, Jan, “Prelude to Interdependence: The Anglo–American Relationship and the Limits of Great Britain's Nuclear Policy, 1952–57,” Arms Control 11 (12 1990), pp. 205–31CrossRefGoogle Scholar; and Wheeler, Nicholas, “The Atlee Government's Nuclear Strategy, 1945–51,” in Deighton, Ann, ed., Britain and the First Cold War (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1990), pp. 130–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
57. See Lewis, and Xue, , China Builds the Bomb, pp. 37–39 and 41–42Google Scholar; Norris, Robert, Burrows, Andrew S., and Fieldhouse, Richard K., British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons: Nuclear Weapons Databook: Volume 5 (Boulder, Colo.: Westview Press, 1994), p. 327.Google Scholar
58. Soviet assistance was specified in six agreements concluded with China between 1955 and 1958. See Lewis, and Xue, , China Builds the Bomb, pp. 40–42.Google Scholar
59. Barnett, A. Doak, China and the Major Powers in East Asia (Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution, 1977), pp. 32–37.Google Scholar
60. Lewis, and Xue, , China Builds the Bomb, pp. 64Google Scholar, 72 and 160–63.
61. See D. Li, “Independence and China's External Relations,” p. A2; Lewis, and Xue, , China Builds the Bomb, pp. 63–64Google Scholar; and Christensen, “Domestic Mobilization and International Conflict,” p. 465.
62. Lewis, and Xue, , China Builds the Bomb, pp. 72 and 150.Google Scholar
63. Lin, , China's Nuclear Weapons Strategy, p. 107.Google Scholar In Nie Rongzhen's words, depending on foreigners for technological assistance would keep China “vulnerable to outside manipulation” and always one step behind. See Lewis, and Xue, , China Builds the Bomb, p. 238.Google Scholar
64. Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, p. 37.Google Scholar A top figure in the British nuclear weapons program, Sir John Anderson, stated, “We cannot afford after the war to face the future without this weapon and rely entirely on America should Russia or some other power develop it.” See Malone, Peter, The British Nuclear Deterrent (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1984) p. 49.Google Scholar The conditions of cooperation were contained in the August 1943 Quebec agreement. See Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, pp. 31–49Google Scholar; Malone, , The British Nuclear Deterrent, pp. 45–48Google Scholar; and Gormly, James L., “The Washington Declaration and the ‘Poor Relation’: Anglo–American Atomic Diplomacy, 1945–46,” Diplomatic History (Spring 1984), p. 127.Google Scholar
65. The 1943 Quebec agreement had not resolved conflicts over nuclear sharing. Essentially an executive agreement on principles, much remained to be worked out by the Combined Policy Committee it established. See Malone, , The British Nuclear Deterrent, p. 49.Google Scholar
66. See Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, p. 120Google Scholar; and Malone, , The British Nuclear Deterrent, pp. 51–53.Google Scholar
67. On parallels between the reasoning behind Prime Minister Atlee's decision to build the atomic bomb in 1947 and Churchill's 1954 decision to build the hydrogen bomb, see Melissen, “Prelude to Interdependence,” pp. 214–15.
68. Wheeler, “The Atlee Government's Nuclear Strategy, 1945–51,” p. 135.
69. Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, pp. 70Google Scholar, 75, 76, and 112–22.
70. Ibid., p. 93; emphasis added. See also pp. 81 and 135; and Wheeler “The Atlee Government's Nuclear Strategy, 1945–51,” p. 136. Ironically, perhaps, British fears of abandonment were compounded by fears of entrapment aroused by MacArthur's risky adventurism in Korea reinforcing the determination of the Atlee government to push ahead with the British bomb as the means to a degree of foreign policy independence. Ibid., pp. 137 and 143–44.
71. Baylis, , British Defense Policy, p. 61.Google Scholar
72. Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, p. 141.Google Scholar See also Malone, , The British Nuclear Deterrent, pp. 57–58.Google Scholar The phrase “substantial progress” apparently referred to knowledge of the Ulam-Teller concept of the thermonuclear bomb. British scientists demonstrated such knowledge in meetings with U.S. physicists in the winter of 1957–58. See Dombey, Norman and Grove, Eric, “Britain's Thermonuclear Bluff,” London Review of Books 22 (10 1992), p. 10.Google Scholar Recent revelations indicate that the British successfully tested a bomb based on this design only in 1958, not in 1957 as Macmillan seemed to have claimed, and that a usable weapon was produced only in late 1960. See Wilkie, Tom, “First H-bomb Built Amid Safety Fears,” The Independent, 25 06 1993, p. 3Google Scholar, NEXIS; and Norris, Burrows, and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, pp. 32–43.Google Scholar
73. See Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, pp. 224–25Google Scholar; and Rosecrance, , Defense of the Realm, p. 13.Google Scholar
74. On the events surrounding the cancellation of Skybolt, see Neustadt, Richard, Alliance Politics (New York: Columbia University Press, 1970).Google Scholar McNamara, in his famous line, condemned small nuclear forces as “dangerous, expensive, prone to obsolescence and lacking in credibility as a deterrent.” See Malone, , The British Nuclear Deterrent, p. 156.Google Scholar
75. U.S. delivery-systems technology offered a cost-effective solution to guaranteeing Britain's continued ability to field an independently controlled deterrent. Washington granted London's request for access to American SLBMs; these would be fitted with British nuclear warheads and placed aboard British-built submarines. See Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, pp. 224–37.Google Scholar
76. See Simpson, John, The Independent Nuclear State (New York: St. Martin's Press, 1983), pp. 225–26CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Norris, , Burrows, , and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, pp. 98 and 102.Google Scholar
77. United Press International, “Secret Papers from '60s Reveal British Nuclear Strategy,” United Press International, 1 01 1994, NEXIS.Google Scholar
78. Mendl, , Deterrence and Persuasion, pp. 92–93.Google Scholar
79. Herring and Immerman report that “Eisenhower and Dulles peremptorily rejected the French proposal [for armed intervention]. Dulles advised the administration that because the security of the United States was not directly threatened, the political risk could in no way be justified.” See Herring, George C. and Immerman, Richard H., “Eisenhower, Dulles, and Dienbienphu: ‘The Day We Didn't Go to War’Revisited,” The Journal of American History 71 (09 1984), p. 359CrossRefGoogle Scholar, emphasis added.
80. See Mend], , Deterrence and Persuasion, pp. 95 and 100Google Scholar; Yost, “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe. Part 1,” p. 4; and Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 16–20 and 35.Google Scholar The first key nuclear weapons funding decision was taken on 26 December 1954. See Norris, , Burrows, , and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, pp. 183–84.Google Scholar
81. Ripsman, Norrin M., “The Impact of Decision-making Autonomy Upon Democratic Peace-making Policies,” Ph.D. diss., University of Pennsylvania, Philadelphia, Penn., n.d.Google Scholar
82. See Mendl, , Deterrence and Persuasion, pp. 15 and 103Google Scholar; Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 35–36Google Scholar; and Wynfred Joshua “New Perspectives in U.S. French Nuclear Relations,” Research Memorandum SSC-RM-8974–2, Stanford Research Institute, August 1972, p. 10, cited in Norris, , Burrows, , and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, p. 184 n. 17.Google Scholar However much the French may have doubted American dependability, Eisenhower did warn the Soviets against nuclear attacks on the U.S. allies during the Suez Crisis.
83. Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 234 and 274.Google Scholar
84. De Gaulle, cited in Ibid., p. 234.
85. Ibid., pp. 5–6 and 356–57.
86. When Eisenhower pushed for revisions in the McMahon Act in 1954 and 1958 that facilitated sharing nuclear information with allies, the regulations approved by a wary U.S. Congress Joint Committee on Atomic Energy effectively restricted such sharing to Britain by stipulating that recipients must have already “made substantial progress in the development of atomic weapons.” See Ibid., p. 6. See also Mendl, , Deterrence and Persuasion, pp. 55–58Google Scholar; Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 64–66 and 80–81Google Scholar; and Ullman, “The Covert French Connection,” pp. 5 and 6–7.
87. On De Gaulle's anger at the lack of American cooperation, see the report of his September 1958 confrontation with General Lauris Norstad, the Supreme Allied Commander, Europe, in Norris, , Burrows, , and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, p. 188, n. 21.Google Scholar During 1959 and 1960 France announced that their Mediterranean fleet would be withdrawn from NATO command in time of war, that they would not allow U.S. intermediate range ballistic missiles under American control to be stationed on French soil, and that no tactical nuclear weapons could be stockpiled in France. See Mendl, , Deterrence and Persuasion, p. 61.Google Scholar
88. See Yost, “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe, Part 1,” pp. 13–14; and Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 356 and 357.Google Scholar
89. See Ullman, “The Covert French Connection,” p. 7; and Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, pp. 217–29.Google Scholar
90. Doubts about genuine acceptance are raised, however, by a recently declassified report that indicates “the French continued their nuclear program” during the 1960s “[i]n spite of U.S. efforts” to “constantly thwart … France's nuclear ambitions” as part of a nonproliferation policy aimed at persuading Paris to abandon the independent deterrent. See Joshua, , New Perspectives in U.S.–French Relations, pp. 65–66Google Scholar, cited in Norris, , Burrows, , and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, p. 190Google Scholar, n. 49, emphasis added.
91. See Pierre, , Nuclear Politics, pp. 238–39Google Scholar; and Kohl, , French Nuclear Diplomacy, p. 233.Google Scholar A recently released U.S. Central Intelligence Agency (CIA) document reports German Chancellor Konrad Adenauer's comment that De Gaulle rejected the U.S. Polaris as a trick to humiliate France because it offered only missiles for which France did not yet have submarines or warheads. See U.S. CIA, Adenauer's Attitude Towards de Gaulle, Memorandum OCI 0749/63, 4 February 1963, pp. 1–2, cited in Norris, , Burrows, , and Fieldhouse, , British, French, and Chinese Nuclear Weapons, p. 188, n. 24.Google Scholar
92. See Heisbourg, Francois, “The British and French Nuclear Forces,” Survival 31 (07/08 1989), pp. 301–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
93. Yost, “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe, Part 1,” p. 5. For a classic account of Franco-American conflict over flexible response versus threats of massive retaliation, see Yost, David S., “French Nuclear Targeting,” in Ball, Desmond and Richelson, Jeffrey, eds., Strategic Nuclear Targeting (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1986), pp. 127–56 at pp. 147–48.Google Scholar
94. Yost, “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe, part 1,” p. 5.
95. Ibid., p. 33.
96. Ullman, “The Covert French Connection,” p. 18.
97. Note, however, the 1980 statement by the director of the planning department of France's Foreign Ministry that its nuclear deterrent “guarantees the security of our territory, and the safekeeping of our political sovereignty …[and] assures her diplomatic independence in security matters, with respect to the United States as much as the Soviet Union, which is something fundamental.” See Yost, “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe, Part 1,” p. 14. And a more moderate degree of independence was maintained in the French refusal, similar to the Chinese, to participate in those arms control regimes seen as superpower infringements on the sovereign choice of other states. See Yost, David S., “France's Deterrent Posture and Security in Europe, Part 2: Capabilities and Doctrine,” Adelphi Paper 195 (Winter 1984/1985), chap. 3.Google Scholar
98. See Malone, , The British Nuclear Deterrent, pp. 173Google Scholar, 179, and 180; Ullman, “The Covert French Connection,” p. 8.
99. See Ullman, “The Covert French Connection,” pp. 10, 11, and 13. Compare Davidson, “France Rejoins Its Allies,” p. 22; Ian Davidson, “French Play Down U.S. ‘Secret Nuclear Help,’” Financial Times, 30 May 1989, p. 3, NEXIS; and “Nuclear Secrets,” The Economist, p. 29.
100. The logic and viability of nuclear deterrence of the strong by the weak as practiced by Britain, China, and France is discussed further in Goldstein, “Robust and Affordable Security.” For more general arguments about the significance of relative numbers of nuclear weapons, see Jervis, Robert, The Illogic of American Nuclear Strategy (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1984)Google Scholar; and Jervis, Robert, The Meaning of the Nuclear Revolution (Ithaca, N.Y.: Cornell University Press, 1989).Google Scholar
101. Goldstein, Avery, “Understanding Nuclear Proliferation: Theoretical Explanation and China's National Experience,” Security Studies 2 (Spring/Summer 1993), pp. 213–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
- 31
- Cited by