Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-r5fsc Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T20:02:59.652Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Asymmetrical bargaining in the conference on security and cooperation in Europe

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  22 May 2009

P. Terrence Hopmann
Affiliation:
P. Terrence Hopmann is Director of the Center of International Studies and an Associate Professor of Political Science at the University of Minnesota. Interviews upon which the research reported in this paper was based were undertaken in part while the author was a research fellow under the Fulbright-Hays Act in Belgium during 1975–76. Additional interviews were undertaken in Geneva, Switzerland in 1974, with the cooperation of the European Centre of the Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, especially of John Goormaghtigh and Jean Siotis. The author is also indebted to the Office of International Programs at the University of Minnesota for financial support for research and travel in Geneva in 1974. Finally, he would like to express his gratitude to Timothy King and Charles Walcott for their contributions to the development of the theory presented in this paper and to James Caporaso, Raymond Duvall, and Brian Job for their helpful comments on an earlier draft of this paper.
Get access

Extract

Bargaining relationships in formal international conferences and negotiations may involve structural asymmetries. A comprehensive analysis of these asymmetries in bargaining may be found in a synthesis of literature from formal game theory, structural-manipulative approaches to bargaining, social psychology, and the study of political influence. Propositions based on this literature focus on two factors which are likely to contribute to asymmetrical outcomes in negotiations: unequal costs to the negotiators from the failure to agree, and unequal resources available to employ in bargaining or influence attempts. An analysis of bargaining in the section of the Conference on Security and Cooperation in Europe (CSCE) dealing with the issues of European security gave qualified support to these propositions. Influence over the final text in the CSCE agreement is related to a rough index of losses which would have resulted for individual nations from the failure to reach agreement in the CSCE. In addition, influence over the final text is related to each nation's resources, especially military resources. More significantly, the two superpowers exerted considerable asymmetrical influence over what was not included in the CSCE agreement, thus exercising a substantial veto. Thus, the asymmetrical outcomes within the CSCE negotiations were reflective of both differences in “threat potential,” that is, in the losses which actors would receive if no agreement had ensued, as well as differences in resources.

Type
Part II
Copyright
Copyright © The IO Foundation 1978

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

1 Iklé, Fred Charles, How Nations Negotiate (New York: Praeger, 1964).Google Scholar

2 Lall, Arthur, Modern International Negotiations (New York: Columbia University Press, 1966).Google Scholar

3 Keohane, Robert O. and Nye, Joseph S., “World Politics and the International Economic System,” in Bergsten, C. Fred, ed., The Future of the International Economic Order: An Agenda for Research (Lexington, Mass.: Lexington Books, 1973).Google Scholar

4 Caporaso, James A., “Relational Control and Power in the Global System: A Structural and Behavioral Analysis” (Evanston: Northwestern University, mimeo, 1975).Google Scholar

5 Lall, p. 150.

6 Iklé, p. 2.

7 Young, Oran R., Bargaining: Formal Theories of Negotiation (Urbana, Ill.: University of Illinois Press, 1975), p. 23.Google Scholar

8 An excellent exposition of the “Battle of the Sexes” as a basis for the game theoretic treatment of the negotiated game may be found in Rapoport, Anatol, Two Person Game Theory (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1969).Google Scholar

9 Nash, John F., “Two Person Cooperative Games,” reprinted in Young, pp. 6971.Google Scholar

10 Several possible solutions not discussed here have been proposed by Raiffa, Howard, “Arbitration Schemes for Generalized Two-Person Games,” in Kuhn, H. W. and Tucker, A. W., eds., Contributions to the Theory of Games, 11 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1953),Google Scholar and Braithewaite, R. B., Theory of Games as a Tool for the Moral Philosopher (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1955).Google Scholar

11 L.S. Shapley, “A Value for N-Person Games,” in H.W. Kuhn and A.W. Tucker, eds., op. cit.

12 Nash, John F., “Noncooperative Games,” Annals of Mathematics, Vol. 54: 155–62.Google Scholar

13 Harsanyi, John C., “A Bargaining Model for the Cooperative N-Person Game,” in Luce, R.D. and Tucker, A.W., eds., Contributions to the Theory of Games, 4 (Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press, 1959).Google Scholar

14 For an extensive treatment of n-person game theory and of its limitations for the purposes of the present analysis see Rapoport, Anatol, N-Person Game Theory (Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press, 1970).Google Scholar

15 Walton, Richard E. and McKersie, Robert B., A Behavioral Theory of Labor Negotiations (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1965), p. 5.Google Scholar

16 Ibid., p. 4.

17 Young, p. 303.

18 Ibid., p. 307.

19 Dahl, Robert A., Modern Political Analysis (Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall, 1963), p. 40.Google Scholar

20 Harsanyi, John, “The Measurement of Social Power,” in Shubik, Martin, ed., Game Theory and Related Approaches to Social Behavior (New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1964), p. 186.Google Scholar

21 Ibid., p. 186.

22 Ibid., p. 187.

23 lbid., pp. 194–95.

24 Alker, Hayward R., “On Political Capabilities in a Schedule Sense: Measuring Power, Integration, and Development,” in Alker, H.R., Deutsch, K.W., and Stoetzel, A.H., eds., Mathematical Approaches to Politics (San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, Inc., 1973), p. 326.Google Scholar

25 Harsanyi, pp. 198–206.

26 Knorr, Klaus, The Power of Nations: The Political Economy of International Relations (New York: Basic Books, 1975), p.20.Google Scholar

27 On this point see the discussion of bargaining power in Schelling, Thomas C., The Strategy of Conflict (Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press, 1960), pp. 2228.Google Scholar

28 Although this latter argument is partly consistent with the so-called “falling domino” theory so widely propagated by American official spokesmen during the Vietnam war, it also makes it clear that an actor can bring such a phenomenon on itself through committing itself to a position which goes beyond the realistic possibility of concessions by the other party.

29 Schelling, p. 28.

30 Ibid., p. 36.

31 For a review of this laboratory research see Sawyer, Jack and Guetzkow, Harold, “Bargaining and Negotiation in International Relations,” in Kelman, Herbert, ed., International Behavior (New York: Holt, Rinehart, and Winston, 1965), pp. 508–11,Google Scholar and Daniel, Druckman, Human Factors in International Negotiation: Social Psychological Aspects of International Conflict (Beverly Hills, Cal.: Sage Professional Papers in International Studies, 1973), pp. 6874.Google Scholar

32 lt is evident that resources can provide only a partial indicator of the ability to influence, and that conceptualizations of influence based upon resources must also deal with this concept only in what Alker, pp. 330–32, has described as an “incomplete point sense.” Nevertheless, more complex conceptions of power are extremely difficult if not impossible to operationalize, so for the moment we must employ merely a rough indicator of influence capability treated in a relatively simple conceptual sense.

33 These data were obtained from the US Arms Control and Disarmament Agency, World Military Expenditures and Arms Transfers, 1965–1974 (Washington, D.C.: U.S. Government Printing Office, 1976)Google Scholar; all data are from 1974.

34 These data were from World Armaments and Disarmament: SIPRI Yearbook 1974 (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1974)Google Scholar; they apply only to the members of the NATO alliance and the Warsaw Treaty Organization.

35 The following documents were examined: CSCE Documents II/A/1 (19 September 1973) through II/A/36 (6 June 1975); II/A/101 (8 February 1974) through II/A/138 (1 April 1975); II/C/I (19 September 1973) through II/C/17 (12 March 1974); II/C/101 (13 March 1974) through II/C/121 (20 July 1975).

36 See Dahl, Robert A., Who Governs? (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1961).Google Scholar

37 Alker, p. 326.

37 Bachrach, Peter and Baratz, Morton S., “Decisions and Non-Decisions: An Analytical Framework,” American Political Science Review, Vol. 57 (09 1963).CrossRefGoogle Scholar

39 CSCE Document II/A/18, 28 January 1974.

40 CSCE Document II/A/30/Rev. 1, 17 March 1975.

41 CSCE Document II/A/1 14, 25 February 1974.

42 CSCE Document II/B/1.

43 CSCE Document II/C/1, 19 September 1973.

44 CSCE Document II/C/12, 4 February 1974.

45 CSCE Document II/C/13, 19 February 1974.

46 CSCE Document 1I/C/12, 4 February 1974.

47 CSCE Document II/C/13, 19 February 1974.

48 CSCE Document II/C/2 21 September 1973.

49 CSCE Document II/C/3 24 September 1973.

50 CSCE Document II/C/4, 26 September 1973.

51 CSCE Document II/C/10, 7 December 1973.

52 CSCE Document II/C/11, 21 January 1974.

53 CSCE Document II/C/8, 28 September 1973.

54 CSCE Document II/C/9, 23 October 1973.

55 CSCE Document II/C/3, 24 September 1973.