Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-23T13:01:59.089Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

L'Année sociologique et la réception de l'œuvre de Max Weber

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 July 2009

Get access

Abstract

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Notes Critiques
Copyright
Copyright © Archives Européenes de Sociology 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

BIBLIOGRAPHIE

Anonyme (1904). Weber, C. R. «Die ‘Objektivität’ sozialwissenschaftlicher und Sozialpolitik», Rivista internazionale di scienze sociali e discipline ausiliare, pp. 257259; (1904b) C. R. Weber ‘Agrarstatistische und sozialpolitische Betrachtungen zur fideikommissfrage in Preussen’, pp. 567–570; (1905) C. R. Weber ‘Die protestantische Ethik und die Geist des Kapitalismus’, pp. 89–93.Google Scholar
Anonyme, (1906). C. R. Weber ‘Russlands Übergang zum Scheinkostitutionalismus’, Rivista italiana di sociologia, p. 472.Google Scholar
Anonyme, (1908). C. R. Durkheim ‘Die methode der soziologie’, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, pp. 290291.Google Scholar
Anonyme, (1912). C. R. Simiand ‘La méthode positive en science économique’, Journal of Political Economy, pp. 535536.Google Scholar
L'Année sociologique, 1re série (Alcan 18971913), 12 tomes.Google Scholar
L'Année sociologique, 2e série (Alcan 19251927), 2 tomes.Google Scholar
Besnard, P. (1983). The epistemological polemist: François Simiand, in Besnard, P. (ed) The sociological domain, the Durkheimians and the founding of French sociology (Cambridge University Press).Google Scholar
von Böhm-Bawerk, E. (1890). The historical versus the deductive method in political economy, Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, pp. 244271.Google Scholar
Bousquet, G. H. (1928). C. R. ‘Grundriß der Sozialökonomie’, Journal des économistes, pp. 124125.Google Scholar
Brandford, V. (1926). A survey of recent and contemporary sociology, Sociological Review, pp. 315322.Google Scholar
Coase, R. (1975). Marshall on method, réed, dans Wood, J. C. (ed) Alfred Marshall, Critical Assessments (Croom Helm 1982), vol. I, pp. 409416.Google Scholar
Collini, S., Winch, D., Burrow, J. (1983). That Noble Science of Politics, a study in 19th century intellectual history (Cambridge University Press).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Commons, J. R. (1927). C. R. Tawney ‘Religion and the rise of capitalism’, American Economic Review, pp. 6368.Google Scholar
Cossa, L. (1892). Introduzione allo studio dell'economia politica3 (Ulrico Hoepli).Google Scholar
Craig, J. E. (1979). Maurice Halbwachs à Strasbourg, Revue française de sociologie, pp. 273292.Google Scholar
Diehl, C. (1923). The life and work of Max Weber, Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp. 87107.Google Scholar
Durkheim, E. (1975). Textes, tome II (Éd. de Minuit).Google Scholar
Fanfani, A. (1930). Riforma e capitalismo nella recente letteratura, Rivista internazionale di scienze sociali, pp. 358365.Google Scholar
Faucci, R. (1988). Schmoller e la scuola storica in Italia, Quaderni di storia dell'economia politica, pp. 111140.Google Scholar
Cide, C. (1894). Principes d'économie politique4 (Larose).Google Scholar
Cide, C. (1914). C. R. L'Année sociologique, tome XII, Revue d'économie politique, p. 245.Google Scholar
Gide, C. et Rist, C. (1909). Histoire des doctrines économiques depuis les physiocrates jusqu' à nos jours (Sirey).Google Scholar
Halbwachs, M. (1906). C. R. Pareto ‘Manuale di economia politica’, L'Année sociologique, pp. 527529.Google Scholar
Halbwachs, M. (1918). Le ‘Traité de sociologie générale’ de Vilfredo Pareto, Revue d'économie politique, pp. 578585.Google Scholar
Halbwachs, M. (1920). Science économique et sociologie : le ‘Traité de sociologie générale’ de Vilfredo Pareto, Revue d'économie politique, pp. 467475.Google Scholar
Halbwachs, M. (1925). Les origines puritaines du capitalisme, Revue d'histoire et de philosophie religieuse, pp. 132154.Google Scholar
Halbwachs, M. (1929). Max Weber : un homme, une œuvre, Annales d'histoire économique et sociale, pp. 8188.Google Scholar
Hennis, W. (1982). Max Weber ‘central question’, trad. anglaise, in Hennis, W. (1988) Max Weber : essays in reconstruction (Allen and Unwin).Google Scholar
Hennis, W. (1987). A Science of Man: Max Weber and the political economy of the German historical schools, in Mommsen, W. J. & Osterhammel, J. (eds) Max Weber and his contemporaries (Unwin Hyman), pp. 2558.Google Scholar
Hennis, W. (1991). The pitiless ‘sobriety of judgement’: Max Weber between Carl Menger and Gustav von Schmoller—the academic politics of value freedom, History of Human Sciences, pp. 2759.Google Scholar
Hirschhorn, M. (1988). Max Weber et la sociologie française (L'Harmattan).Google Scholar
Jevons, S. (1876). The future of political economy, reed, dans S. Jevons (1965) The Principle of Economics: a fragment of a treatise on the industrial mechanism of society (Kelley).Google Scholar
Jevons, S. (1879). The Theory of Political Economy2 (reed. Kelley 1965).Google Scholar
Karady, V. (1979). Stratégies de réussite et modes de faire-valoir de la sociologie chez les durkheimiens, Revue française de sociologie, pp. 4982.Google Scholar
Keynes, J. N. (1890). The Scope and Method of Political Economy (reed. Kelley 1955).Google Scholar
Knight, M. M. (1927). Recent literature on the origins of modern capitalism, Quarterly Journal of Economics, pp. 520533.Google Scholar
Koot, G. M. (1980). English historical economics and the emergence of economic history in England, History of Political Economy, pp. 174205.Google Scholar
Lescure, J. (1911). C. R. Verhandlungen des Vereins für Sozialpolitik in Wien, Revue d'économie politique, pp. 401402.Google Scholar
Lukes, S. (1974). Durkheim confirme Tiryakian, Archives européennes de sociologie, XV, pp. 354355.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Marshall, G. (1982). In Search of the Spirit of Capitalism: an essay on Max Weber's Protestant Ethic Thesis (Hutchison).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mastrogiuseppe, B. (1981). Max Weber in Italia (1907–1980), una bibliografia, Rassegna italiana di sociologia, pp. 227250.Google Scholar
Maunier, R. (1912). C. R. Simiand ‘La méthode positive en science économique’, Revue internationale de sociologie, p. 313.Google Scholar
Maurer, H. H. (1924). The sociology of religion: I: the sociology of protestantism, American Journal of Sociology, pp. 257286.Google Scholar
Mauss, M. (1927). Notes de méthode sur l'extension de la sociologie, rééd, dans M. Mauss, Œuvres, tome III, pp. 283297.Google Scholar
Menger, C. (1883). Problems of Political Economy and Sociology, trad. anglaise (Illinois, University Press, 1963).Google Scholar
Michels, R. (1909). C. R. Halbwachs ‘Les expropriations et le prix des terrains à Paris (1860–1900)’, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, p. 308.Google Scholar
Michels, R. (1928). C. R. Marianne Weber ‘Max Weber, ein Lebensbild’, Revue d'économie politique, pp. 323324.Google Scholar
Mommsen, W. J. (1974). The Age of Bureaucracy, Perspectives on the political sociology of M. Weber (Harper and Row).Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1896). Cours d'économie politique, Œuvres complètes, t. I (Droz 1964).Google Scholar
Pareto, V. (1903). Proemio, a Biblioteca di storia economica (Società editrice Libraria).Google Scholar
Parsons, T. (19281929). Capitalism in recent German literature: Sombart and Weber, Journal of Political Economy, pp. 641661; 31–51.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Poggi, G. (1983). Calvinism and the Capitalist Spirit, Max Weber's Protestant Ethic (Macmillan).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Prendergast, C. (1986). Alfred Schutz and the Austrian School of Economics, American Journal of Sociology, pp. 126.Google Scholar
Reberioux, M. (1983). Le débat de 1903 : historiens et sociologies, dans Carbonnel, C. O. & Livet, G. (eds). Au berceau des Annales (Presses de l'I.E.P. de Toulouse), pp. 219230.Google Scholar
Roth, G. & Schluchter, W. (1976). Max Weber's Vision of History, Ethics and Methods (California University Press).Google Scholar
Roversi, A. (1988). Max Weber e la teoria economica, dans Losito, M. & Schiera, P. (eds). Max Weber e le scienze sociali del suo tempo (Il Mulino), pp. 211229.Google Scholar
Scarf, L. A. (1984). From political economy to political sociology: Max Weber's early writings, in Glassman, R. M. & Murvar, V. (eds) (1984) Max Weber's Political Sociology: a pessimistic vision of a rationalized world (Greenwood Press).Google Scholar
Schmoller, G. (1883). Gli scritti di K. Menger e W. Dilthey sulla metodologia delle scienze politiche e sociali, trad. italienne, Quaderni di storia dell'economia politica (1988), pp. 141164.Google Scholar
Schmoller, G. (1894). L'économie politique, sa théorie et sa méthode, Revue d'économie politique, pp. 105140, 339–363, 462–479.Google Scholar
Schmoller, G. (1900). Principes d'économie politique, I, trad. française (Alcan 1905).Google Scholar
Schön, M. (1987). Gustav Schmoller and Max Weber, in Mommsen, W.J. & Osterhammel, J. (eds) Max Weber and his Contemporaries (Unwin Hyman), pp. 5970.Google Scholar
Schroeter, G. (1986). Reading the small print, or the Weber/Durkheim unawareness puzzle revisited, Archives européennes de sociologie, XXVII, pp. 195196.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1912). Economic Doctrine and Method, an Historical Sketch, trad. anglaise (Allen and Unwin 1954).Google Scholar
Schumpeter, J. (1954). History of economic analysis (Allen and Unwin).Google Scholar
Schwiedland, E. (1924). C. R. Weber ‘Gesammelte Aufsätze zur Wissenschaftslehre’, Economic Journal, p. 122.Google Scholar
Seidman, S. (1977). The Durkheim/Weber ‘unawareness puzzle’, Archives européennes de sociologie, XVIII, p. 356.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simiand, F. (1902). Essai sur le prix du charbon en France et au XIXe siècle, Année sociologique (Alcan).Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (1903). Méthode historique et science sociale, réédité par M. Cedronio dans Méthode historique et sciences societies (Éditions des archives contemporaines 1987), pp. 113169.Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (1903b). Sur la notion de cause en matière historique et sociologique, rééd. par M. Cedronio, op. cit. pp. 173176.Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (1906). La causalité en histoire, rééd. par M. Cedronio, op. cit. pp. 209241.Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (1907). Le salaire des ouvriers des mines de charbon en France : contribution à la théorie économique du salaire (Cornély).Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (1912). La méthode positive en science économique (Alcan).Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (1922). Statistiques et expériences, remarques de méthode (Rivière).Google Scholar
Simiand, F. (19301932). Recherches sur le mouvement général des prix du XVIe au XIXe siècle (Domat Montchrestien).Google Scholar
Tawney, R. H. (1923). Religious thought on social and economic questions in the 16th and 17th century, III: puritanism, Journal of Political Economy, pp. 804836.Google Scholar
Tawney, R. H. (1936). La religion et l'essor du capitalisme2, trad. française (Rivière 1951).Google Scholar
Tiryakian, E. (1966). A problem for the sociology of knowledge: the mutual unawareness of E. Durkheim and M. Weber, Archives européennes de sociologie, VII, pp. 330336.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tönnies, F. (1905). C. R. L'Année sociologique, I-VI, Archiv für Sozialwissenschaft und Sozialpolitik, pp. 237247.Google Scholar
Veyne, P. (1976). Le pain et le cirque (Le Seuil).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Weber, M. (1904). L'objectivité de la connaissance dans les sciences et la politique sociales, dans M. Weber (1965), pp. 117213.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (19041906). Roscher and Knies: the logical problems of historical economics, trad. anglaise (The Free Press 1975).Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1906). Études critiques pour servir à la logique des sciences de la culture, dans Weber (1965), pp. 215323.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1917). Essai sur le sens de la ‘neutralité axiologique’ dans les sciences sociologiques et économiques, dans Weber (1965), pp. 401477.Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1921). Économie et société, trad. française (Plon 1964).Google Scholar
Weber, M. (1965). Essais sur la théorie de la science, trad. française (Plon).Google Scholar
Whimster, S. (1980). The profession of history in the work of Max Weber: its origins and limitations, British Journal of Socialogy, pp. 352376.Google Scholar
Whimster, S. (1987). Karl Lamprecht and Max Weber: historical sociology within the confines of a historians' controversy, in Mommsen, W. J. & Osterhammel, J. (eds) Max Weber and his contemporaries (Unwin Hyman), pp. 268283.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1904). Ends and means in economics, dans Selected Papers on Economic Theory (rééd. Kelley 1969), pp. 5166.Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1911). Lectures on political economy2, trad. anglaise (Routledge and Kegan 1967).Google Scholar
Wicksell, K. (1921). Carl Menger, dans Selected Papers on Economic Theory (rééd. Kelley 1969), pp. 186192.Google Scholar
von Wiese, L. (1927). Current sociology, Germany, Sociological Review, pp. 2025.Google Scholar