Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-21T22:27:12.789Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Interviewed by Nicholas M. Kiefer

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  18 October 2010

Abstract

Econometrics as practiced by Arthur (Art) Goldberger demonstrates extraordinary sensitivity to issues of measurement and model specification, and unusual care and caution in interpretation of results, as well as a thorough and comprehensive mastery of econometric theory. His landmark 1964 book, Econometric Theory, set a new standard of rigor in econometrics, and at the same time treated the important problems posed by limited and qualitative dependent variables years before any other text. Art Goldberger's work ranges from early contributions to macro modeling through demand analysis, multivariate modeling with latent variables, and models for sample selectivity, to his highly regarded work on important social issues of heritability of IQ, effectiveness of public versus private schools, and measurement of salary discrimination. Goldberger's influential work, especially on modeling latent or unobservable variables, is widely known and applied in sociology and psychology as well as in economics. Art has been at Wisconsin for many years, and this association is an important reason for Wisconsin's continuing reputation as a leading center for quantitative social sciences.

The quality and influence of Art Goldberger's work has earned him many professional honors. He is a Fellow of the Econometric Society, the American Statistical Association, the American Academy of Arts and Sciences, and the American Association for the Advancement of Science, and has twice been a Guggenheim Fellow. He is a Distinguished Fellow of the American Economic Association and a member of the National Academy of Sciences. Art gave the Woytinsky Lecture at the University of Michigan in 1985.

This interview took place on May 5 in Art Goldberger's office overlooking Lake Mendota. Art's remarks cover a wide range of topics, and I hope they are of interest to social scientists generally as well as to econometricians.

Type
Et Interview
Copyright
Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1989

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

PUBLICATIONS OF ARTHUR S. GOLDBERGER

1.An Econometric Model of the United States 1929–52 (with Klein, L.R.). Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1955.Google Scholar
2.A statistical model for 1955 (with Suits, D.B.). Michigan Business Review (January 1955): 2528.Google Scholar
3.A note on the statistical discrepancy in the national accounts (with Gartaganis, A.J.). Econometrica 23 (1955): 166173.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
4.Impact Multipliers and Dynamic Properties of the Klein-Goldberger Model. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1959.Google Scholar
5.Conversion: the magnitude of the task. The Nation (March 28, 1959): 271275.Google Scholar
6.On pure and mixed statistical estimation in economics (with Theil, H.). International Economic Review 2 (1961): 6578.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
7.Note on stepwise least squares (with Jochems, D.B.). Journal of the American Statistical Association 56 (1961): 105110.Google Scholar
8.The covariance matrices of reduced-form coefficients and of forecasts for a structural econometric model (with Nagar, A.L. and Odeh, H.S.). Econometrica 29 (1961): 556573.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
9.Stepwise least squares: residual analysis and specification error. Journal of the American Statistical Association 56 (1961): 9981000.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
10.Toward a microanalytic model of the household sector (with Lee, Maw Lin). American Economic Review 52 (1962): pp. 241251.Google Scholar
11.Best linear unbiased prediction in the generalized linear regression model. Journal of the American Statistical Association 57 (1962): 369375.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
12.El uso de los modeles en la politica de desarrollo economico (with Chenery, H.B.). In Inter national Association for Research in Income and Wealth, El Ingreso y La Riqueza, pp. 90124. Mexico: Fondo de Cultura Economica, 1963.Google Scholar
13.Econometric Theory. New York: John Wiley and Sons, 1964. (Japanese translation, Tokyo: Oriental Economist, 1970; Spanish translation, Madrid: Editorial Tecnos, 1970; Polish translation, Warsaw: Panstwowe Wydawnictwo Economicane, 1972.)Google Scholar
14.An instrumental variable interpretation of Ar-class estimation. The Indian Economic Journal 13 (1965): 424431.Google Scholar
15.The economist's role in policy formation. In Yotopoulos, Pan A. (ed.), Economic Analysis and Economic Policy, pp. 2529. Athens: Center of Planning and Economic Research, 1966.Google Scholar
16.Comment (on paper by Thorbecke and Condos). In Adelman, I. and Thorbecke, E., eds., The Theory and Design of Economic Development, pp. 208209. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press, 1966.Google Scholar
17.On the interpretation and estimation of Cobb-Douglas functions. Econometrica 36 (1968): 464472.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
18.Topics in Regression Analysis. New York: Macmillan, 1968.Google Scholar
19.Directly additive utility and constant marginal budget shares. Review of Economic Studies 36 (1969): 251254.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
20.On the exact covariance of products of random variables (with Bohrnstedt, G.W.). Journal of the American Statistical Association 64 (1969): 14391442.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
21.A cross-country comparison of consumer expenditure patterns (with Gamaletsos, T.). European Economic Review 1 (1970): 357400.Google Scholar
22.On Boudon's method of linear causal analysis. American Sociological Review 35 (1970): 97101.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
23.On the statistical analysis of identities. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 52 (1970): 154155.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
24.Estimation of Pareto's law from grouped data (with Aigner, D.J.). Journal of the American Statistical Association 65 (1970): 712723.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
25.Unbiased prediction by recursive least squares. Econometrica 38 (1970): 367.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
26.A minimum-distance interpretation of limited-information estimation (with Olkin, I.). Econometrica 39 (1971): 635639.Google Scholar
27.Econometrics and psychometrics: a survey of communalities. Psychometrika 36 (1971): 83107.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
28.The treatment of unobservable variables in path analysis (with Hauser, R.M.). In Costner, H.L. (ed.), Sociological Methodology 1971, Chapter 4. San Francisco: Jossey-Bass, 1971.Google Scholar
29.Maximum-likelihood estimation of regressions containing unobservable independent variables. International Economic Review 13 (1972): 115.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
30.Factor Analysis by Generalized Least Squares (with Joreskog, K.G.). Psychometrika 37 (1972): 243260.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
31.Structural equation methods in the social sciences. Econometrica 40 (1972): 9791002.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
32.Dependency rates and savings rates: further comment. American Economic Review 63 (1973): 232233.Google Scholar
33.Correlations between binary outcomes and probabilistic predictions. Journal of the American Statistical Association 68 (1973): 84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
34.Structural equation models: an overview. In Goldberger, A.S. and Duncan, O.D. (eds.), Structural Equation Models in the Social Sciences, Chapter 1. New York: Seminar Press, 1973.Google Scholar
35.Efficient estimation in overidentified models: an interpretive analysis. In Goldberger, A.S. and Duncan, O.D. (eds.), Structural Equation Models in the Social Sciences, Chapter 7. New York: Seminar Press, 1973.Google Scholar
36.Structural Equation Models in the Social Sciences (co-edited with Duncan, O.D.). New York: Seminar Press, 1973.Google Scholar
37.Unobservable variables in econometrics. In Zarembka, P. (ed.), Frontiers of Econometrics, Chapter 7. New York: Academic Press, 1974.Google Scholar
38.On the explanatory power of dummy variable regressions (with Aigner, D.J. and Kalton, G.). International Economic Review 16 (1975): 503510.Google Scholar
39.Estimation of a model with multiple indicators and multiple causes of a single latent variable (with Joreskog, K.G.). Journal of the American Statistical Association 70 (1975): 631639.Google Scholar
40.Mysteries of the meritocracy. In Block, N. J. and Dworkin, G. (eds.), The IQ Controversy: Critical Readings, pp. 265279. New York: Pantheon, 1976.Google Scholar
41.Jensen on Burks. Educational Psychologist 12 (1976): 6478.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
42.On Jensen's method for twins. Educational Psychologist 12 (1976): 7982.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
43.Twin methods: a skeptical view. In Taubman, P. (ed.), Kinometrics: Determinants of Socioeconomic Success within and between families, pp. 299324. Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1977.Google Scholar
44.On Thomas' model for kinship correlations. Psychological Bulletin 84 (1977): 12391244.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
45.Latent Variables in Socio-Economie Models (co-edited with Aigner, A.J.). Amsterdam: North-Holland, 1977.Google Scholar
46.Pitfalls in the resolution of IQ inheritance. In Morton, N.E. & Chung, C.S. (eds.), Genetic Epidemiology, pp. 195215. New York: Academic Press, 1978.Google ScholarPubMed
47.The non-resolution of IQ inheritance by path analysis. American Journal of Human Genetics 30 (1978): 442445.Google Scholar
48.The genetic determination of income: comment. American Economic Review 68 (1978): 960969.Google Scholar
49.Heritability. Economica 46 (1979): 327347.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
50.Issues in the analysis of selectivity bias (with Barnow, B.S. & Cain, G.G.). In Stromsdorfer, E.W. & Farkas, G. (eds.), Evaluation Studies Review Annual, Volume 5, pp. 4359. Beverly Hills: Sage Publications, 1980.Google Scholar
51.Linear regression after selection. Journal of Econometrics 15 (1981): 357366.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
52.The causal analysis of cognitive outcomes in the Coleman, Hoffer and Kilgore report (with Cain, G.C.). Sociology of Education 55 (1982): 103122.Google Scholar
53.Abnormal selection bias. In Karlin, S., Goodman, L.A., & Amemiya, T. (eds.), Studies in Econometrics, Time Series, and Multivariate Statistics, pp. 6785. New York: Academic Press, 1983.Google Scholar
54.Public and private schools revisited (with Cain, G.G.). Sociology of Education 56 (1983): 208218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
55.Proportional projections in limited dependent variable models (with Chung, C-F.). Econometrica 52 (1984): 531534.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
56.Redirecting reverse regression. Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 2 (1984): 114116.Google Scholar
57.Reverse regression and salary discrimination. Journal of Human Resources 19 (1984): 293318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
58.Functional Form and Utility: A Review of Consumer Demand Theory. Boulder: Westview Press, 1987.Google Scholar