Article contents
Microchips and Public Policy – The Political Economy of High Technology
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 27 January 2009
Abstract
- Type
- Review Article
- Information
- Copyright
- Copyright © Cambridge University Press 1992
References
1 Cyert, Richard and Mowery, David, Technology and Employment: Innovation and Growth in the US Economy (Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 1987), p. 5Google Scholar; also Cohen, Stephen S. and Zysman, John, Manufacturing Matters: The Myth of the Post-Industrial Economy (New York: Basic Books, 1987), p. 170Google Scholar; and Forester, Tom, ed., The Microelectronics Revolution (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1980), p. 295.Google Scholar
2 TUC, Annual Economic Survey, 1979.
3 Among works generated during the 1950s–early 1960s debate were Buckingham, Walter, Automation: Its Impact on Business and People (New York: Mentor, 1965)Google Scholar; Diebold, John, Automation (Princeton, NJ: Van Norstrand, 1952)Google Scholar; Dechert, Charles, The Social Impact of Cybernetics (New York: Simon & Schuster, 1965)Google Scholar; and Wiener, Norbert, The Human Use of Human Beings (New York: Houghton Mifflin, 1954).Google Scholar There was a still earlier edition of the automation debate during the great depression of the 1930s; see chapter 1 in Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment.Google Scholar
4 For example, Shonfield, Andrew, Modern Capitalism (Oxford: Oxford University Press, 1965).Google Scholar
5 Nora, Simon and Minc, Alain, The Computerization of Society (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1980).Google Scholar This originally was a commissioned report to the French President Giscard d'Estaing, composed by two inspecteurs des finances and a team of specialists. It was published in January 1978 and became a best-seller.
6 Dosi, et al. , eds (London: Frances Pinter, 1988)Google Scholar; Freeman, and Soete, (London: Frances Pinter, 1990)Google Scholar; Cyert, and Mowery, (Washington, DC: National Academy Press, 1987)Google Scholar; Derian, (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990)Google Scholar; Oakley, and Owen, (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1990)Google Scholar; Friedman, (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1988)Google Scholar; Zuboff, (New York: Basic Books, 1989)Google Scholar; and Matthews, (London: Pluto, 1989).Google Scholar
7 Nelson, Richard R. and Soete, Luc, ‘Policy Conclusions’Google Scholar, in Dosi, et al. , eds., Technical Innovation and Economic Growth, p. 633.Google Scholar
8 Friedman, , Misunderstood Miracle, pp. 17, 161.Google Scholar
9 In itself job loss is not a symptom of grave underlying problems. A dynamic economy sheds as many as one of every ten jobs each year while the labour displaced is absorbed elsewhere in more productive and profitable activities. This pleasant scenario assumes that workers' skills are at least partially transferable and/or that adequate public/private provisions for retraining exist. It also assumes that labour is quite mobile or else that capital is – but not too much so (going offshore). Unemployment becomes a policy problem when (1) the rate of displacement outruns the pace of job creation for a protracted period, and (2) when public pressure is brought to bear on policy-makers who are ideologically disposed and institutionally capable of responding with ameliorative measures.
10 Polanyi, Karl, The Great Transformation (Boston, Mass.: Beacon Press, 1944), pp. 140–1.Google Scholar
11 Rosenberg, Nathan, Inside The Black Box: Technology and Economics (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1982), p. ix.Google Scholar
12 Rosenberg, , Inside The Black Box, p. 236.Google Scholar Also see Smith, Merritt Roe, ed., Military Enterprise and Industrial Technology (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1987), p. 9.Google Scholar
13 Flamm, Kenneth, Targeting the Computer (Washington, DC: Brookings Institution, 1987), p. 18.Google Scholar
14 Flamm, , Targeting the Computer, p. 77.Google Scholar
15 Oakley, and Owen, , Alhey, pp. 178, 221.Google Scholar
16 Quoted in Derian, , America's Quest for Leadership in High Technology, pp. 143–4Google Scholar; also Nelson, Richard R., ‘Institutions Supporting Technical Change in the United States’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory, p. 323.Google Scholar
17 Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, pp. 37, 38.Google Scholar
18 Derian, , America's Quest, p. 143Google Scholar; also see Mowery, David and Rosenberg, Nathan, Technology and the Pursuit of Economic Growth (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1989).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
19 Derian, , America's Quest, pp. 106–24.Google Scholar
20 New York Times, 20 02 1991.Google Scholar
21 New York Times, 20 02 1991.Google Scholar
22 Oakley, and Owen, , Alvey, p. 60.Google Scholar
23 Oakley, and Owen, , Alvey, pp. 12–13.Google Scholar
24 Oakley, and Owen, , Alvey, pp. 186–7.Google Scholar
25 Freeman, Christopher, Clark, John and Soete, Luc, Unemployment and Technical Innovation (London: Frances Pinter, 1982).Google Scholar
26 Freeman, , Clarke, and Soete, , Unemployment, p. 16.Google Scholar
27 Schumpeter, Joseph, Business Cycles: A Theoretical, Historical and Statistical Analysis of the Capitalist Process (New York: McGraw-Hill, 1939), 2 volsGoogle Scholar; Goldstein, Joshua, Long Cycles: Prosperity and War in the Modern Age (New Haven, Conn.: Yale University Press, 1988)Google Scholar; Mandel, Ernest, Late Capitalism (London: New Left Books, 1975)Google Scholar; Mensch, Gerhard, Stalemate in Technology (Cambridge, Mass.: Ballinger Press, 1979)Google Scholar; Thompson, William R., ‘Long Waves, Technological Innovation, and Relative Decline’, International Organization, 44 (1990), 62–89.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
28 Freeman, , Clark, and Soete, , Unemployment, pp. 74, 76.Google Scholar
29 Freeman, , Clark, and Soete, , Unemployment, pp. 79, 97.Google Scholar
30 Freeman, , Clark, and Soete, , Unemployment, pp. 153–7.Google Scholar
31 See, for example, Kuttner, Robert, The End of Laissez-Faire (New York: Houghton Mifflin, 1990).Google Scholar
32 Freeman, , ‘Preface to Part II. Evolution, Technology and Institutions: A Wider Framework for Economic Analysis’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , Technical Change and Economic Theory, p. 11.Google Scholar The notion of a ‘techno-economic paradigm’ derives from theories of scientific paradigm change. For an overview of these debates see Jacobsen, J. K. and Gilman, Roger, ‘The Dialectical Character of Feyerabend's Philosophy of Science’, Nature, Society and Thought, 4 (1991), 5–30.Google Scholar
33 Freeman, , Clark, and Soete, , Unemployment and Technical Innovation, p. 191.Google Scholar
34 The Guardian, 28 06 1989 and 8 01 1990.Google Scholar
35 Independent on Sunday, Business Section, 20 12 1990, p. 4.Google Scholar
36 Massey, Doreen and Meegan, Richard, The Anatomy of Job Loss (London: Methuen, 1982), p. 225.Google Scholar
37 Massey, and Meegan, , The Anatomy of Job Loss, pp. 183–4.Google Scholar
38 See Green, Francis, ed., The Restructuring of the UK Economy (London: Macmillan, 1989)Google Scholar and Jessop, Bob, Bonner, Kevin and Bromley, Simon, ‘Farewell to Thatcherism?’ New Left Review No. 179 (1990), 81–102.Google Scholar
39 Forester, Tom, High Tech Society (Cambridge, Mass.: MIT Press, 1987), p. 180.Google Scholar
40 Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, p. 2.Google Scholar
41 Boyer, Robert, ‘Technical Change and the Theory of Regulation’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , ed., Technica Change and Economic Theory, p. 73.Google Scholar
42 Dosi, Giovanni, ‘The Nature of the Innovative Process’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory, p. 227.Google Scholar
43 Piore, Michael and Sabel, Charles, The Second Industrial Divide (New York: Basic Books, 1987).Google Scholar
44 Friedman, , Misunderstood Miracle, p. 25.Google Scholar
45 See Agliette, Michel, A Theory of Capitalist Regulation: The US Experience (London: Verso, 1979)Google Scholar; Liepitz, Alain, Mirages and Miracles: The Crisis of Global Fordism (London: Verso, 1987)Google Scholar; and, a critical appraisal from the left, Brenner, Robert and Glick, Mark, ‘The Regulation Approach: Theory and History’, New Left Review, No. 188 (1991), 45–120.Google Scholar
46 Friedman, , Misunderstood Miracles, p. 13.Google Scholar
47 Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, p. 29.Google Scholar Scott Lash distinguishes between post-Fordism, which is a ‘functional disintegration of Fordist hierarchies into a plethora of smaller firms’, and neo-Fordism, which ‘entails only the disaggregation of the functions of the firm, which remain within the physical space of the large company’ (‘Disintegrating Firms’, Socialist Review 21 (1991), p. 104Google Scholar). What is at stake is the kind and degree of workplace control. See also Pavitt, Keith, ‘Chips and Trajectories’, in MacLeod, Roy, ed., Technology and the Human Prospect (London: Frances Pinter, 1986), pp. 31–54.Google Scholar
48 Matthews, , Tools of Change, p. 180.Google Scholar
49 See Dosi, and Orenigo, , ‘Coordination and Transformation: An Overview of Structures, Behaviours and Change in Evolutionary Environments’, p. 27Google Scholar; Clark, Norman and Juma, Calestous, ‘Evolutionary Theories in Economic Thought’Google Scholar; and Freeman, Christopher and Perez, Carlota, ‘Structural Crises of Adjustment: Business Cycles and Investment Behaviour’, p. 45Google Scholar, all in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory.Google Scholar
50 Gordon, David M., Reich, Michael and Edwards, Richard, Segmented Work, Divided Workers: The Historical Transformation of Labour in the US (Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 1982).Google Scholar
51 See Noble, David, Forces of Production (New York: Knopf, 1985)Google Scholar; Shaiken, Harley, Work Transformed (New York: Holt, Rinehart, Winston, 1986)Google Scholar; and Friedman, , Misunderstood Miracle.Google Scholar
52 Freeman, , ‘Japan: A New National System of Innovation?’Google Scholar in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory, p. 344.Google Scholar Also Dankbaar, Ben, ‘International Competition and National Institutions: The Case of the Automobile Industry’Google Scholar, in Freeman, and Soete, , New Explorations in the Economics of Technical Change, p. 170.Google Scholar
53 Steedman, H. and Wagner, K. in The Independent, 2 01 1991.Google Scholar
54 Von Wolferen, Karel, The Enigma of Japanese Power (New York: Knopf, 1989), p. 181.Google Scholar
55 See Jacobsen, J. K. and Hofhansel, Claus, ‘Safeguards and Profits: Civilian Nuclear Exports, Neo-Marxism and the Statist Approach’, International Studies Quarterly, 28 (1984), 195–218CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Jacobsen, J. K., ‘Peripheral Postindustrialism: Ideology, High Technology and Development’, in Caporaso, James A., ed., A Changing International Division of Labor (London: Frances Pinter, 1987), pp. 91–122.Google Scholar
56 A policy crisis occurs if the credibility of a state's commitment to full employment is compounded by harm inflicted on groups that support incumbent parties. Cuts in social spending and public employment lighten the tills of many businesses. Slack capacity raises unit costs so that export sector firms must lower profit margins or else lose competitiveness. High interest rates and overvalued currency interfere with inter-industry purchasing patterns so that multiplier effects diminish. Unused ‘human capital’ strains state budgets because fewer taxes and more compensation are paid. The discontent of declining producer groups is expressed in protectionist inclinations. All the more reason to attend to the issues of technological design and workplace reforms.
57 Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, p. 133Google Scholar; Forester, , High Tech Society, p. 217Google Scholar; and Zuboff, , In the Age of the Smart Machine.Google Scholar
58 Rolfe, Heather, ‘In the Name of Progress: Skills and Attitudes toward Technological Change’, New Technology, Work and Employment, 5 (1990), 110–17.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
59 Nora, and Minc, , The Computerization of Society, pp. 4–5.Google Scholar
60 Nora, and Minc, , The Computerization of Society, pp. 42–5.Google Scholar
61 Friedman, , Misunderstood Miracle, p. 38.Google Scholar
62 The Independent, 2 01 1991.Google Scholar
63 The Guardian, 14 02 1990.Google Scholar
64 Matthews, , Tools of Change, pp. 134–5.Google Scholar
65 Dosi, , ‘Introduction’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory, p. 3.Google Scholar
66 Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, p. 62.Google Scholar
67 Forester, , High Tech Society, pp. 198, 213Google Scholar; also Knights, David and Wilmott, Hugh, New Technology and the Labour Process (London: Macmillan, 1988), p. 251.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
68 Esping-Andersen, Gosta, The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1990), p. 181.Google Scholar
69 Freeman, , Clark, and Soete, , Unemployment and Technical Innovation, p. 122.Google Scholar
70 See Dosi, , ‘The Nature of the Innovative Process’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , Technical Change and Economic Theory, pp. 227–8.Google Scholar
71 Przeworski, Adam, ‘Material Interests, Class Compromise and the Transition to Socialism’, Politics and Society, 7 (1980), 125–53, p. 149.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
72 Castells, Manuel, The Economic Crisis and American Society (Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press, 1980), p. 56.Google Scholar
73 Katzenstein, Peter, Small States in the World Economy (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1986).Google Scholar
74 See Esping-Andersen, , Three Worlds of Welfare CapitalismGoogle Scholar; Freeman, John, Democracy and Markets (Ithaca, NY: Cornell University Press, 1989)Google Scholar; and Fagerberg, Jan et al. , ‘The Decline of Social Democratic State Capitalism in Norway’, New Left Review, No. 181 (1991), 60–94.Google Scholar
75 Matthews, , Tools of Change, p. 113.Google Scholar
76 Dankbaar, , ‘International Competition and National Institutions’Google Scholar, in Freeman, and Soete, , New Explorations, p. 169.Google Scholar
77 Castells, , The Economic Crisis and American Society, p. 56.Google Scholar
78 ‘[These] organizations … illustrated how the need to defend and reproduce the legitimacy of managerial authority can channel potential innovation toward the conventional emphasis on automation. In this context, managers emphasize machine intelligence and managerial control over the knowledge base at the expense of developing knowledge in the operating work force. They use the technology as a fail-safe system to increase their sense of certainty and control over both production and organizational functions’ (Zuboff, , In the Age of the Smart Machine, p. 390).Google Scholar
79 Block, Fred, ‘Rethinking the Political Economy of the Welfare State’, in Block, Fred, Cloward, Richard, Ehrenriech, Barbara and Piven, Frances Fox, eds, The Mean Season: The Attack on the Welfare State (New York: Pantheon, 1987), p. 111.Google Scholar
80 Noble, , Forces of Production, p. 65.Google Scholar
81 Matthews, , Tools of Change, p. 141.Google Scholar
82 Matthews, , Tools of Change, p. 158.Google Scholar
83 Frohlich, Dieter and Krieger, Hubert, ‘Technological Change and Worker Participation in Europe’, New Technology, Work and Employment, 5 (1990), 90–103, p. 95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
84 Albertijn, Michel, Honcke, Bob, and Wigaerts, Davy, ‘Technology Agreements and Industrial Relations in Belgium’, New Technology, Work and Employment 5 (1990), 3–18, p. 6.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
85 Noble, , Forces of Production, p. 164.Google Scholar
86 Esping-Andersen, , The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism, p. 153.Google Scholar
87 Unger, Kurt, ‘Industrial Structure, Technical Change and Microeconomic Behaviour in LDCs’Google Scholar, in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory, pp. 484–5Google Scholar; Freeman, , Clark, and Soete, , Unemployment and Technical Innovation, pp. 162–82.Google Scholar
88 My thanks to a referee who suggested this point.
89 Henderson, Jeffrey, The Globalisation of High Technology Production (London: Routledge, 1989), p. 143CrossRefGoogle Scholar; Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, p. 81Google Scholar; also Freeman, , ‘Technical Innovation in the World Chemical Industry and Changes of Techno-Economic Paradigm’Google Scholar, in Freeman, and Soete, , New Explorations, pp. 74–92.Google Scholar
90 Derian, , America's Quest, p. 229.Google Scholar
91 Cyert, and Mowery, , Technology and Employment, pp. 81, 126.Google Scholar; Chenais, François, ‘Multinational Enterprises and the International Diffusion of Technology’, p. 520Google Scholar; and Unger, , ‘Industrial Structure, Technical Change and Microeconomic Behaviour in LDCs’Google Scholar, both in Dosi, , ed., Technical Change and Economic Theory, p. 491.Google Scholar
92 Nora, and Minc, , The Computerization of Society, p. 41.Google Scholar
93 A more benign view of the present and future of Japanese work practices is given in Aoki, Masahiko, ‘A New Paradigm of Work Organizational Coordination?’ in Marglin, Stephen and Schor, Juliet, eds, The Golden Age of Capitalism: Reinterpreting the Postwar Experience (Oxford: Clarendon Press, 1990), pp. 267–93.Google Scholar
94 Friedman, , Misunderstood Miracle, p. 13.Google Scholar
95 Polanyi, , The Great Transformation, p. 140, fn. 16.Google Scholar
- 1
- Cited by