Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T10:18:37.381Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Figures

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 September 2021

Jo. M. Martins
Affiliation:
International Medical University, Malaysia
Indra Pathmanathan
Affiliation:
United Nations University - International Institute for Global Health
David T. Tan
Affiliation:
United Nations Development Programme
Shiang Cheng Lim
Affiliation:
RTI International
Pascale Allotey
Affiliation:
United Nations University - International Institute for Global Health

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2021
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - SA
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-SA 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

Figures

  1. 2.1The susceptible–infected–recovered (SIR) system

  2. 2.2A causal loop diagram (CLD)

  3. 2.3Two types of feedback structure

  4. 2.4An influence diagram (ID)

  5. 4.1Pap smear slides taken and coverage in Malaysia, 1994–2003

  6. 4.2Trends in the utilisation pattern of OPDs

  7. 4.3Estimated outpatient visits to clinics per capita per annum, Malaysia, 1930s–2000s

  8. 4-AExpansion of scope in PHC services

  9. 4-BApproaches to healthcare require supportive practices and systems, which in turn create an ecosystem that is aligned to and facilitates that approach

  10. 4-CFour changes to the PHC clinics’ setting were critical to the ecosystem change: locus of financing and decision-making, scope and alignment of healthcare staff responsibilities, professional development pathways, and facilities and operations

  11. 4-DReviewed approach of primary healthcare (REAP-WISE)

  12. 4-aEmployee expectations and unionisation determine the effectiveness of their demands of employers for healthcare benefits

  13. 4-bMCO-imposed caps on per-visit reimbursement generates hidden costs through multiple visits (R1) or inadequate provision of care (B2)

  14. 4-cImpact of MCOs on employer–employee–union dynamics changing the prior system (Figure 4-a) in ways that result in lower health benefits for the workforce

  15. 4-dPathways toward government regulation of practices related to healthcare benefits are ineffectual due to limited ability of the public and medical professionals to organise (B4 loop) and lack of information on how these practices affect the burden on the public healthcare system (B5 loop)

  16. 5.1Evolving profile of types of hospitals, number of TB and leprosy beds, and childbirth in hospitals

  17. 5.2Utilisation of Ministry of Health hospitals in Peninsular Malaysia, 1970 and 1996

  18. 5.3Dynamics of providing more sophisticated clinical services

  19. 5.4Rising demand for medical care outpaced public hospital resources, creating a gap in public sector capacity

  20. 5.5Dynamics of improving clinical outcomes and establishing a quality culture at every level

  21. 5.6Dynamics of improving resource utilisation and client satisfaction

  22. 5.7Bed occupancy rates in MoH hospitals

  23. 5.8Harnessing technology to improve access to seamless, integrated care

  24. 5.9Composition of inpatient care utilisation in public and private sector by socio-economic status

  25. 5.10Interactions between the larger ecosystem and the healthcare provider sub-system with its enabling or constraining sub-systems

  26. 5-aThe rising demand for more sophisticated STC stressed the capacity of the public sector, thereby requiring greater investment

  27. 5-bIn the 1970s and 1980s, rising societal affluence further increased the demand for sophisticated healthcare, resulting in the growth of the private sector STC, drained specialists from the public sector to the private sector and counteracted efforts to increase public sector capacity

  28. 5-cIncreased investment resulted in increased availability of specialist services but was associated with the unanticipated effect of increased compartmentalisation of care

  29. 5-dInvestment in public sector organisational structure improved the capacity to deal with compartmentalisation

  30. 5-AThe gap between demand and supply

  31. 5-BA view of the wider system affecting dialysis demand and supply

  32. 5-CChanging the behaviour of the system through new policy

  33. 5-DEffect of the rapid expansion of services on the workforce

  34. 6.1Incidence rate of communicable diseases per 100,000 population, Malaysia, 1975–1997

  35. 6-AA criminalisation approach emphasising criminal enforcement, education and rehabilitative efforts failed to reduce the number of new HIV cases from injecting drugs use

  36. 6-BStigmatisation and the paradigm of regarding the MoH as the main provider of outreach and services were barriers to a harm reduction programme

  37. 6-CCommitment to MDG goals and local advocacy were critical enabling factors that overcame barriers to the adoption of the harm reduction approach

  38. 6-DSuccess of the pilots created favourable conditions for institutional changes that persisted even after key enabling factors for the adoption of the harm reduction approach (MDGs and local advocacy) receded

  39. 6-EWhile harm reduction strategies have reduced HIV in IDUs, the gains are being threatened by the increasing incidence of sexual transmission of HIV

  40. 7-AThe PWD strategy for expanding the water and sanitation network was unable to respond to rural disease burdens in a timely manner

  41. 7-BInadequate rural infrastructure investment in sanitation undermined community trust in government actors, hindering educational efforts that attempted to address the sanitation issues

  42. 7-CThe paradigm that the MoH mission is limited to healthcare delivery created internal and external barriers to its involvement in rural water and sanitation

  43. 7-aFactors that led to poor clinical waste management

  44. 7-bInability of the government to allocate sufficient resources for clinical waste management undercut both the enforcement of standards that did exist and the development of further standards necessary for ‘cradle-to-grave’ management

  45. 7-cOutsourcing of clinical waste services enabled necessary capital investment for clinical waste management, enabling the B1, B2 and B3 loops to function properly

  46. 8.1Malaysian doctors in the public and private sectors, 1955–2013

  47. 8.2Regional disparities in availability of doctors, 1970–2010

  48. 8.3Utilisation of outpatient services in Malaysia

  49. 8.4Distribution of selected specialist doctors in Malaysia, 2013

  50. 8.5Reported satisfaction with public and private clinics, 2015

  51. 8.6Reported satisfaction with public and private hospitals, 2015

  52. 8-ANew graduates entering the workforce as HOs

  53. 8-BDoctors’ average career path in Malaysia

  54. 8-CMeeting the demand

  55. 8-DLack of capacity planning

  56. 8-EImpact of the bottleneck on the HO experience

  57. 8-FThe specialist bottleneck

  58. 8-GSystems responses to the crisis

  59. 9.1Public and private health financing sources, Malaysia, 1997–2017

  60. 9-AConcerns over sustainable health care financing and quality of care are creating an impetus to improve hospital performance

  61. 9-BInstitutional pressures keep generic accounting approaches in place over the adoption of the case-mix approach

  62. 10.1Reinforcing loop showing how compliance with data collection improves the quality of data, enabling positive impacts on health outcomes

  63. 10-AFor telehealth functions that cut across health facilities, the more health facilities adopt and operate within a particular interoperable telehealth standard, the greater the benefit for other facilities to adopt that standard, creating a reinforcing cycle (R1 loop)

  64. 10-BThe push for the adoption of telehealth could increase the number of facilities adopting an interoperable telehealth standard or lead to the proliferation of incompatible standards

  65. 10-CThe proliferation of incompatible telehealth standards actually increases the cost of adopting interoperable standards (R3 loop) due to health facility operations and structures coming to rely on incompatible telehealth software

  66. 10-DThe lack of a critical mass of health facilities operating on the same telehealth standard reduces benefits for certain functions, such as health information exchange

  67. 11.1Number of received reports of ADR

  68. 11.2Number and ratio of pharmacists per 10,000 population

  69. 11.3Number and ratio of assistant pharmacists per 10,000 population

  70. 11.4MOH medicine expenditure, 2008–2017

  71. 11.5Number of outpatient prescriptions received, 2011–2017

  72. 11.6Export and import value of pharmaceutical products to Malaysia, 2013 and 2017

  73. 11-AThe registration and regulation of traditional medicines was in response to the adverse health impacts from the improper manufacture and use of traditional medicines and has successfully reduced poor practice and consequent outcomes

  74. 11-BRegulation of traditional medicines creates costs to traditional medicine businesses, which some actors attempt to bypass (R1), creating a race to close regulation loopholes (B1) and enforce existing regulations (B2)

  75. 11-CCreating benefits for traditional medicine businesses for compliance with regulation can reward good actors and reduce attempts to bypass regulation

  76. 12-AThe paradigm that affordable medical treatment should be a right has led to the creation of tools meant to limit the price of treatment (B1 loop). These tools have provided governments with important leverage to negotiate treatment prices with suppliers (B2 loop).

  77. 12-BReliance on the private sector for developing treatment solutions creates a competing paradigm that distrusts interference with market mechanisms (R1 loop). This paradigm undermines the availability of price control tools (B3 loop).

  78. 12-CAdvocates for market-driven development of medical products have pushed for trade agreements, IPR protection and the use of political pressure and sanctions that increase the risk of using price control tools to limit government actions to control treatment prices (B4 loop). For governments to successfully utilise these tools, they must take a variety of actions to mitigate against these risks.

  79. 13.1The WHO health system framework

  80. 13.2Proposed revised layout of the WHO building blocks depicted in Figure 13.1

  81. 14.1The health systems in society model contains eight linkages that form the macro-level feedback loops that shape the health system and its component building blocks

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×