Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-rdxmf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T06:25:52.361Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - THE STRUCTURE OF CLASS CONFLICT IN DEMOCRATIC CAPITALIST SOCIETIES

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2010

Adam Przeworski
Affiliation:
Carroll and Milton Petrie Professor in the Department of Politics, New York University
David Austen-Smith
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Illinois
Jeffry A. Frieden
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Miriam A. Golden
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles
Karl Ove Moene
Affiliation:
Universitetet i Oslo
Adam Przeworski
Affiliation:
New York University
Get access

Summary

The combination of private ownership of the instruments of production with representative political institutions based on widespread suffrage constitutes a compromise between workers, who consent to the private appropriation of profit by owners of capital, and capitalists, who accept the democratic institutions through which workers can make effective claims for an improvement of their material conditions.

This form of societal organization was considered to be inherently unstable by Marx, who believed that capitalist democracy is “only the political form of revolution of bourgeois society and not its conservative form of life,” (1934, p. 18) “only a spasmodic, exceptional state of things … impossible as the normal form of society.” (1972, p. 198) Once introduced, Marx thought, political democracy would either be extended to the “social realm” by workers nationalizing the means of production or subverted by capitalists using the ownership of capital to restore their political power. Yet in many countries, capitalist democracy has persisted over long periods of time.

Marx's predictions may have been false for at least two distinct reasons. His followers have tended to accept a model of conflict in which interests of classes are irreconcilably opposed to each other, a model that implies that workers should always be hostile to capitalism and capitalists. If this model is correct and if capitalism nevertheless survives in its democratic form, it must be the result of the activities of some institutions, typically thought to be the state, which provide physical repression, ideological domination, cooptation of workers' leaders, or whatever else is necessary to perpetuate capitalism in the face of the permanent threat posed by workers.

Type
Chapter
Information
Selected Works of Michael Wallerstein
The Political Economy of Inequality, Unions, and Social Democracy
, pp. 18 - 57
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Bowles, Samuel, and Gintis, Herbert, 1980. The crisis of liberal democratic capitalism: the case of the United States. Presented at the annual meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, D.C.
Chiaramonte, Gerardo. 1975. Report to the Central Committee of the P.C.I. October 29–30. Italian Communist.
Clough, Shepard B. 1968. European economic history. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Edel, Matthew. 1979. A note on collective action, Marxism, and the prisoner's dilemma. Journal of Economic Issues 13:751–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ferejohn, John, and Page, Talbot. 1978. On the foundations of intertemporal choice. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 78:269–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Glyn, Andrew, and Sutcliffe, Bob. 1972. Capitalism in crisis. New York: Pantheon Books.Google Scholar
Goldberg, Samuel. 1958. Introduction to difference equations. New York: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Gramsci, Antonio. 1971. Prison notebooks. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
Griffuelhes, Victor. 1910. L'Inferiorité des Capitalistes Francais. Mouvement Socialiste 226:329–32.Google Scholar
Harsanyi, John C. 1977. Rational behavior and bargaining equilibrium in games and social situations. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Heller, Agnes. 1974. The theory of need in Marx. London: Allison and Busby.Google Scholar
Helmstädter, Ernst. 1973. The long-run movement of the capital-output ratio and of labor's share. In Mirrlees, James and Stern, N. H. (eds.). Models of economic growth. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hoel, Michael. 1975. Aspects of distribution and growth in a capitalist economy. Memorandum of the Institute of Economics. Oslo, Norway: University of Oslo.Google Scholar
Hoel, Michael (1978). Distribution and growth as a differential game between workers and capitalists. International Economic Review 19:335–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Jacobsen, John K. 1980. Chasing progress. Ph. D. dissertation. University of Chicago.Google Scholar
Keynes, John M. 1936. The general theory of employment, interest, and money. New York: Harcourt, Brace, Jovanovich.Google Scholar
Kolm, Serge. 1977. La Transition Socialiste: La Politique Economique de Gauche. Paris: Editions du Cerf.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1966. Modern economic growth: rate, structure, and spread. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Lancaster, Kelvin. 1973. The dynamic inefficiency of capitalism. Journal of Political Economy 81:1092–109.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lange, Oskar. 1938. On the economic theory of socialism. In Lippincott, Benjamin (ed.). On the economic theory of socialism. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Maddison, Angus. 1964. Economic growth in the west. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1934. The eighteenth brumaire of Louis Bonaparte. Moscow: Progress Publishers.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl 1967. Capital. New York: International Publishers.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl 1972. Writings on the Paris commune. Edited by Hal, Draper. New York: Monthly Review.Google Scholar
McDonald, Ian M., and Solow, Robert M. 1981. Wage bargaining and employment. American Economic Review 71:896–908.Google Scholar
Miliband, Ralph. 1969. The state in capitalist society. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Nash, John. 1954. Equilibrium states in n-person games. Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 36:48–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Odling-Smee, J. C. 1973. Personal saving revisited – more statistics, fewer facts. Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics 35:21–9.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donnell, O' Guillermo A. 1973. Modernization and bureaucratic-authoritarianism: studies in South American politics. Berkeley: Institute of International Studies, University of California.Google Scholar
Offe, Claus, and Wiesenthal, Helmut. 1980. Two logics of collective action: theoretical notes on social class and organizational form. Political Power and Social Theory 1:67–115.Google Scholar
Pasinetti, Luigi L. 1962. Rate of profit and income distribution in relation to the rate of economic growth. Review of Economic Studies 29:267–79.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pirker, Theo, ed. 1965. Komintern und Faschismus. Stuttgart: Deutsche Verlags-Anstalt.Google Scholar
Poulantzas, Nicos. 1973. Political power and social classes. London: New Left Books.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam. 1980. Material bases of consent: politics and economics in a hegemonic system. Political Power and Social Theory 1:23–68.Google Scholar
Roemer, John E. 1979. Mass action is not individually rational: reply. Journal of Economic Issues 13:763–7.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roemer, John E. 1982. A practical theory of exploitation and class. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1960. The strategy of conflict. Cambridge: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1978. Micromotives and macrobehavior. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Sombart, Werner. 1976. Why there is no socialism in the United States. White Plains, N.Y.: International Arts and Sciences.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stackelberg, H.. 1952. The theory of the market economy. Translation and Introduction by A. T. Peacock. London: William Hodge.Google Scholar
Taylor, Michael. 1976. Anarchy and cooperation. London: John Wiley and Sons.Google Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1979. An estimate of savings out of wages in the United States, 1949–1970. Unpublished. University of Chicago.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×