Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T06:30:11.153Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

11 - INTRODUCTION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2010

David Austen-Smith
Affiliation:
Earl Dean Howard Distinguished Professor of Political Economy, Kellogg School of Management, Northwestern University
David Austen-Smith
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Illinois
Jeffry A. Frieden
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Miriam A. Golden
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles
Karl Ove Moene
Affiliation:
Universitetet i Oslo
Adam Przeworski
Affiliation:
New York University
Get access

Summary

Although a great deal of Michael Wallerstein's work concerns the inequality of income, wages, and wealth, very few of his papers contain significant normative claims beyond those of economic efficiency. Of course, the fact that Wallerstein eschewed any substantive normative discussions in his work does not imply that he held no views on the fairness or otherwise of particular patterns of wage and income inequality; far from it. Rather it reflects his belief that, before any compelling normative case can be made regarding any given distributions of income or wealth, it is necessary to understand as deeply as possible exactly how such distributions come about. And while there are a great many reasons offered in the literature for levels and changes in income inequality, Wallerstein focused on exploring how political-economic institutions influence and support particular distributions of income.

In the early 1980s, the ratio of wages earned by those in the 50th percentile of the wage distribution to those in the 10th percentile was 1.96 in the US, 1.64 in France, and 1.31 in Sweden. By the late 1990s, the ratios were 2.1, 1.59, and 1.39, respectively. Over the same period, evidence from a set of eighteen OECD countries (including the US, France, and Sweden) indicates, first, a strong negative correlation between pretax income inequality and government spending on “safety net” insurance against loss of income and, second, a negligible relationship between pretax income inequality and any purely redistributive government spending in favor of the poor.

Type
Chapter
Information
Selected Works of Michael Wallerstein
The Political Economy of Inequality, Unions, and Social Democracy
, pp. 241 - 249
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Alesina, A., Baqir, R., and Easterly, W.. 1999. “Public Goods and Ethnic Divisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 114 (4): 1243–1284.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alesina, A. and Glaeser, E.. 2004. Fighting Poverty in the US and Europe: A World of Difference. Oxford: Oxford University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Atkinson, A. B., L. Rainwater, and T. Smeeding. 1995. “Income Distribution in European Countries.” Working Paper 9535. Dept. of Applied Economics, University of Cambridge.
Austen-Smith, D. 2000. “Redistribution under Proportional Representation.” Journal of Political Economy 108 (4): 1235–1269.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Birchfield, V., and Crepaz, M. L.. 1998. “The Impact of Constitutional Structures and Collective and Competitive Veto Points on Income Inequality in Industrialized Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research 34 (1): 175–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blau, F., and Kahn, M.. 1996. “International Differences in Male Wage Inequality: Institutions versus Market Forces.” Journal of Political Economy 108 (2): 791–837.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Card, D. 1996. “The Effect of Unions on the Structure of Wages: A Longitudinal Analysis.” Econometrica 64 (4): 957–979.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, R. 1980. “Unionization and the Dispersion of Wages.” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 34 (1): 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Freeman, R. 1996. “Labor Market Institutions and Earnings Inequality.” New England Economic Review May/June: 157–168.Google Scholar
Hibbs, D., and Locking, H.. 1995. “Wage Compression, Wage Drift and Wage Inflation in Sweden.” Labour Economics 77 (1): 1–32.Google Scholar
Meltzer, R., and Richard, S.. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (3): 914–927.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moene, K., and Wallerstein, M.. 2001a. “Targeting and the Political Support for Welfare Policies.” Economics of Governance 2 (1): 3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moene, K., and Wallerstein, M.. 2001b. “Inequality, Social Insurance and Redistribution.” American Political Science Review 95 (4): 859–874.Google Scholar
Oskarsson, S. 2005. “Divergent Trends and Different Causal Logics: The Importance of Bargaining Centralization when Explaining Earning Inequality across Advanced Democratic Societies.” Politics and Society 33 (3): 359–385.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Perotti, R. 1996. “Growth, Income Distribution, and Democracy: What the Data Say.” Journal of Economic Growth 1 (1): 149–187.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Plott, C. 1967. “A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility under Majority Rule.” American Economic Review 57 (3): 787–806.Google Scholar
Roemer, J. 1998. “Why the Poor Don't Expropriate the Rich.” Journal of Public Economics 70 (3): 399–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roemer, J., and W. Lee. 2004. “Racialism and Redistribution in the United States: A Solution to the Problem of American Exceptionalism.” Working Paper. Yale University.
Romer, T. 1975. “Individual Welfare, Majority Voting and the Properties of a Linear Income Tax.” Journal of Public Economics 14 (1): 163–185.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, K. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science 23 (1): 27–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×