Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-8bhkd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T19:16:02.453Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

13 - INEQUALITY, SOCIAL INSURANCE, AND REDISTRIBUTION

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 January 2010

Karl Ove Moene
Affiliation:
Professor of economics, University of Oslo; Scientic advisor, Center of Applied Research, Oslo, since 1987
David Austen-Smith
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Illinois
Jeffry A. Frieden
Affiliation:
Harvard University, Massachusetts
Miriam A. Golden
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles
Karl Ove Moene
Affiliation:
Universitetet i Oslo
Adam Przeworski
Affiliation:
New York University
Get access

Summary

How do changes in the inequality of income affect political support for welfare policy? Starting with the economic models of Romer (1975), Roberts (1977), and Meltzer and Richard (1981), the conventional view is that increased inequality in pretax earnings leads to greater political demand for redistributive policies. The logic is simple and compelling. If the majority of the electorate receives a below-average income and if an increase in inequality causes above-average incomes to rise and below-average incomes to fall, then it is reasonable to think that demands for public policies to reduce the gap between rich and poor will increase.

The argument of Romer (1975) and Meltzer and Richard (1981) is best illustrated by comparing two hypothetical lognormal income distributions with the same mean but different levels of inequality as shown in Figure 1. As the figure shows, the greater the variance of a distribution like the lognormal distribution that is skewed to the right, the greater the gap between median and mean income. In the models of Romer (1975), Roberts (1977), and Meltzer and Richard (1981), political competition drives the level of welfare spending toward the ideal point of the median income voter. The greater the gap between the pretax earnings of the median income voter and average (mean) income, the greater is the level of spending preferred by the median income voter and the higher is the equilibrium level of welfare spending.

Type
Chapter
Information
Selected Works of Michael Wallerstein
The Political Economy of Inequality, Unions, and Social Democracy
, pp. 285 - 319
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2008

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aitchison, John, and , J. A. C. Brown. 1957. The Lognormal Distribution. Cambridge:Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Alesini, Alberto, and Rodrik, Dani. 1994. “Distributive Politics and Economic Growth.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 109 (May):465–90.Google Scholar
Austen-Smith, David. 2000. “Redistributing Income under Proportional Representation.” Journal of Political Economic 108 (December):1235–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barr, Nicholas. 1992. “Economic Theory and the Welfare State:A Survey and Interpretation.” Journal of Economic Literature 30 (June):741–803.Google Scholar
Beck, Neal, and Katz, Jonathan. 1995. “What to Do (and Not to Do) with Time-Series Cross-Sectional Data in Comparative Politics.” American Political Science Review 89 (September):634–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1983. “A Theory of Competition among Pressure Groups for Political Influence.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 98 (August):371–400.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1985. “Public Policies, Pressure Groups, and Dead Weight Costs.” Journal of Public Economics 28 (December):329–47.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bénabou, Roland. 2000. “Unequal Societies:Income Distribution and the Social Contract.” American Economic Review 90 (March):96–129.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Blais, André, and Dobrzynska, Agnieszka. 1998. “Turnout in Electoral Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research 33 (March):239–61.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Casamatta, Georges, Cremer, Helmuth, and Pestieau, Pierre. 2000. “Political Sustainability and the Design of Social Insurance.” Journal of Public Economics 75 (March):341–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Castles, Francis G. 1982. “The Impact of Parties on Public Expenditure.” In The Impact of Parties:Politics and Policies in Democratic Capitalist States, ed. Francis Castles. London:Sage. Pp. 21–96.Google Scholar
Castles, Francis, and Mair, Peter. 1984. “Left-Right Political Scales:Some ‘Expert’ Judgements.” European Journal of Political Research 12 (January):73–88.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donder, Philippe, and Hindriks, Jean. 1998. “The Political Economy of Targeting.” Public Choice 95 (January):177–200.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Donder, Philippe, and Hindriks, Jean. 2000. “The Politics of Redistributive Social Insurance.” Department of Economics. University of London. Typescript.
Devroye, Dan. 2000. “Voting for Inequality.” Department of Government. Harvard University. Unpublished paper.
Esping-Andersen, Gösta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ:Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Franklin, Mark N. 1996. “Electoral Competition.” In Comparing Democracies:Elections and Voting in Global Perspective, ed. Lawrence LeDuc, Richard Niemi, and Pippa Norris. Thousand Oaks, CA:Sage. Pp. 216–35.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert J. 1998. “Political Participation, Income Distribution and Public Transfers in Developed Democracies.” Department of Political Science. University of Michigan, Ann Arbor. Typescript.
Freeman, Richard B. 1988. “Labour Market Institutions and Economic Performance.” Economic Policy 6 (April):64–80.Google Scholar
Friend, Irwin, and Blume, Marshall E.. 1975. “The Demand for Risky Assets.” American Economic Review 65 (December):900–22.Google Scholar
Gelbach, Jonah B., and Pritchett, Lant H.. 1997. “Indicator Targeting in a Political Equilibrium:Leakier Can Be Better.” Washington, DC:World Bank Policy Research Working Paper 1523.
Greene, William H. [1993] 1997. Econometric Analysis. Upper Saddle River, NJ:Prentice Hall.Google Scholar
Greenstein, Robert. 1991. “Universal and Targeted Approaches to Relieving Poverty:An Alternative View.” In The Urban Underclass, ed. Christopher Jencks and Paul Peterson. Washington, DC:Brookings Institution. Pp. 437–59.
Hibbs, Douglas A., and Locking, Håkan. 2000. “Wage Dispersion and Productive Efficiency:Evidence for Sweden.” Journal of Labor Economics 18 (October):755–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, Alexander. 1999. Social Democracy and Welfare Capitalism:A Century of Income Security Politics. Ithaca, NY:Cornell University Press.Google Scholar
Hicks, Alexander, and Swank, Duane. 1992. “Politics, Institutions and Social Welfare Spending in the Industrialized Democracies, 1960–1982.” American Political Science Review 86 (September):658–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, Ragin, Charles, and Stephens, John D.. 1993. “Social Democracy, Christian Democracy, Constitutional Structure and the Welfare State.” American Journal of Sociology 99 (November):711–49.Google Scholar
Huber, Evelyne, and Stephens, John D.. 2001. Development and Crisis in Advanced Welfare States. Chicago:University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, John, and Inglehart, Ronald. 1995. “Expert Interpretations of Party Space and Party Locations in 42 Societies.” Party Politics 1 (1):73–111.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Iversen, Torben, and Soskice, David. 2001. “An Asset Theory of Social Policy Preferences.” American Political Science Review 95 (December):875–93.Google Scholar
Korpi, Walter. 1983. The Democratic Class Struggle. London:Routledge and Kegan Paul.Google Scholar
Kristov, Lorenzo, Lindert, Peter, and McClelland, Robert. 1992. “Pressure Groups and Redistribution.” Journal of Public Economics 48 (July):135–63.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lijphart, Arend. 1997. “Unequal Participation: Democracy's Unresolved Dilemma.” American Political Science Review 91 (March):1–14.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meltzer, Allan H., and Richard, Scott F.. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (October):914–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moene, Karl Ove, and Wallerstein, Michael. 1998. “Rising Inequality and Declining Support for Redistribution.” Department of Political Science. Northwestern University. Typescript.
Moene, Karl Ove, and Wallerstein, Michael. 2001a. “Inequality, Social Insurance, and Redistribution:Additional Statistical Tables.” Department of Political Science. Northwestern University. Typescript.
Moene, Karl Ove, and Wallerstein, Michael. 2001b. “Targeting and Political Support for Welfare Spending.” Economics of Governance 2 (1):3–24.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moffitt, Robert, Ribar, David, and Wilhelm, Mark. 1998. “The Decline of Welfare Benefits in the U. S.:The Role of Wage Inequality.” Journal of Public Economics 68 (June):421–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1993. Employment Outlook, July 1993. Paris:OECD.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1994. New Orientations for Social Policy. Paris:OECD.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1996. Employment Outlook, July 1996. Paris:OECD.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1997. Statistical Compendium 1997/2 [CD-ROM]. Paris:OECD.
Organization for Economic Cooperation and Development. 1999. Social Expenditure Database, 1980–1996 [CD-ROM]. Paris:OECD.
Pampel, Fred C., and Williamson, John B.. 1989. “Welfare Spending in Advanced Industrial Democracies 1950–1980.” American Journal of Sociology 93 (May):1424–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Persson, Torsten, and Tabellini, Guido. 1994. “Is Inequality Harmful for Growth?American Economic Review 84 (June):600–21.Google Scholar
Piketty, Thomas. 1995. “Social Mobility and Redistributive Politics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 110 (August):551–84.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roberts, Kevis W. S. 1977. “Voting over Income Tax Schedules.” Journal of Public Economics 8 (December):329–40.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Caballero, Rodríguez, and Rafael, Francisco. 1998. “Essays on the Political Economy of Inequality, Redistribution and Growth.” Department of Economics. Harvard University. Ph.D. diss.
Roemer, John E. 1998. “Why the Poor Do Not Expropriate the Rich in Democracies:A New Argument.” Journal of Public Economics 70 (December):399–424.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roemer, John E. 1999. “The Democratic Political Economy of Progressive Income Taxation.” Econometrica 67 (January):1–20.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Romer, Thomas. 1975. “Individual Welfare, Majority Voting, and the Properties of a Lienar Income Tax.” Journal of Public Economics 14 (May):163–85.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rueda, David, and Pontusson, Jonas. 2000. “Wage Inequality and Varieties of Capitalism.” World Politics 52 (April):350–83.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Saint-Paul, Gilles. 1998. “The Dynamics of Exclusion and Fiscal Conservatism.” Department of Economics. Universitat Pompeu Fabra and CEPR. Typescript.
Shalev, Michael. 1983. “The Social Democratic Model and Beyond:Two Generations of Comparative Research on the Welfare State.” Comparative Social Research 6:316–51.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science 23 (February):27–59.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sinn, Hans-Werner. 1995. “A Theory of the Welfare State.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 97:495–526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Skocpol, Theda. 1991. “Targeting within Universalism:Politically Viable Policies to Combat Poverty in the United States.” In The Urban Underclass, ed. Christopher Jencks and Paul Peterson. Washington, DC:Brookings Institution. Pp. 411–36.
Stephens, John D. 1979. The Transition from Capitalism to Socialism. Atlantic Highlands, NJ:Humanities Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Swank, Duane. 1992. “Politics and the Structural Dependence of the State in Democratic Capitalist Nations.” American Political Science Review 86 (March):38–54.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wallerstein, Michael. 1999. “Wage-Setting Institutions and Pay Inequality in Advanced Industrial Societies.” American Journal of Political Science 43 (July):649–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wilensky, Harold L. 1975. The Welfare State and Equality. Berkeley:University of California Press.Google Scholar
Wright, Randall. 1996. “Taxes, Redistribution, and Growth.” Journal of Public Economics 62 (November):327–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×