Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T14:06:54.877Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Bibliography

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 December 2018

Sean Ingham
Affiliation:
University of California, San Diego
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Rule by Multiple Majorities
A New Theory of Popular Control
, pp. 178 - 186
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2019

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abizadeh, Arash. 2012. “On the Demos and Its Kin: Nationalism, Democracy, and the Boundary Problem.” American Political Science Review 106(4):867882.Google Scholar
Achen, Christopher H. and Bartels, Larry M.. 2016. Democracy for Realists: Why Elections Do Not Produce Responsive Government. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Alt, James, de Mesquita, Ethan Bueno and Rose, Shanna. 2011. “Disentangling Accountability and Competence in Elections: Evidence from U.S. Term Limits.” The Journal of Politics 73(1):171186.Google Scholar
Arneson, Richard J. 2009. The Supposed Right to a Democratic Say. In Contemporary Debates in Political Philosophy, ed. Christiano, Thomas and Christman, John. Oxford: Wiley-Blackwell, pp. 197212.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1951. Social Choice and Individual Values. New York: John Wiley & Sons, Inc.Google Scholar
Ashworth, Scott. 2012. “Electoral Accountability: Recent Theoretical and Empirical Work.” Annual Review of Political Science 15:183201.Google Scholar
Ashworth, Scott and de Mesquita, Ethan Bueno. 2006. “Delivering the Goods: Legislative Particularism in Different Electoral and Institutional Settings.” The Journal of Politics 68(1):168179.Google Scholar
Ashworth, Scott, de Mesquita, Ethan Bueno and Friedenberg, Amanda. 2018. “Learning about Voter Rationality.American Journal of Political Science 62(1):3754.Google Scholar
Austin-Smith, David and Banks, Jeffrey. 1999. Positive Political Theory I: Collective Preference. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Baron, David P. and Ferejohn, John A.. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83(4):11811206.Google Scholar
Barro, Robert J. 1973. “The Control of Politicians: An Economic Model.” Public Choice 14(1):1942.Google Scholar
Barry, Brian. 2002. “Capitalists Rule OK? Some Puzzles about Power.” Politics, Philosophy & Economics 1(2):155184.Google Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 2016. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. 2nd ed. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Bechtel, Michael M. and Hainmueller, Jens. 2011. “How Lasting Is Voter Gratitude? An Analysis of the Short- and Long-Term Electoral Returns to Beneficial Policy.” American Journal of Political Science 55(4):852868.Google Scholar
Beerbohm, Eric. 2012. In Our Name: The Ethics of Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy. 2006. Principled Agents? The Political Economy of Good Government. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Besley, Timothy and Burgess, Robin. 2002. “The Political Economy of Government Responsiveness: Theory and Evidence from India.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4):14151451.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. London: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Borowiak, Craig. 2011. Accountability and Democracy: The Pitfalls and Promise of Popular Control. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Boulianne, Shelley. 2018. “Mini-Publics and Public Opinion: Two Survey-Based Experiments.” Political Studies 66(1):119136.Google Scholar
Brennan, Jason. 2016. Against Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Broome, John. 1999. Ethics out of Economics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Busby, Ethan C., Druckman, James N. and Fredendall, Alexandria. 2017. “The Political Relevance of Irrelevant Events.” The Journal of Politics 79(1):346350.Google Scholar
Butler, Daniel M. 2014. Representing the Advantaged: How Politicians Reinforce Inequality. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Carnes, Nicholas. 2013. White-Collar Government: The Hidden Role of Class in Economic Policy Making. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Chen, Jidong, Pan, Jennifer and Yiqing, Xu. 2016. “Sources of Authoritarian Responsiveness: A Field Experiment in China.” American Journal of Political Science 60(2):383400.Google Scholar
Christiano, Thomas. 1993. Social Choice and Democracy. In The Idea of Democracy, eds. Copp, David, Hampton, Jean and Roemer, John E.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Christiano, Thomas. 1996. The Rule of the Many: Fundamental Issues in Democratic Theory. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Cohen, Joshua. 1986. “An Epistemic Conception of Democracy.” Ethics 97(1):2638.Google Scholar
Cohen, Joshua. 1997. Deliberation and Democratic Legitimacy. In Deliberative Democracy: Essays on Reason and Politics, eds. Bohman, James and Rehg, William. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Crespin, Michael H. and Rohde, David W.. 2010. “Dimensions, Issues, and Bills: Appropriations Voting on the House Floor.” The Journal of Politics 72(4): 976989.Google Scholar
Cutler, Fred, Johnston, Richard, Carty, Kenneth R., Blais, André and Fournier, Patrick. 2008. Deliberation, Information, and Trust: The British Columbia Citizens’ Assembly as Agenda Setter. In Designing Deliberative Democracy, eds. Warren, Mark and Pearse, Hilary. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert. 1956. A Preface to Democratic Theory: Expanded Edition. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1957. “The Concept of Power.” Behavioral Science 2(3):201215.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1971. Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 2005. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City. 2nd ed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha and Maskin, Eric. 2008. “On the Robustness of Majority Rule.” Journal of the European Economic Association 6(5):949973.Google Scholar
Dixit, Avinash and Londregan, John. 1996. “The Determinants of Success of Special Interests in Redistributive Politics.” The Journal of Politics 58(4):11321155.Google Scholar
Dougherty, Keith, Lynch, Michael and Madonna, Anthony. 2014. “Partisan Agenda Control and the Dimensionality of Congress.” American Politics Research 42(4): 600627.Google Scholar
Dowding, Keith. 2003. “Resources, Power and Systematic Luck: A Response to Barry.” Politics, Philosophy & Economics 2(3):305322.Google Scholar
Dowding, Keith. 2006. “Can Populism Be Defended? William Riker, Gerry Mackie and the Interpretation of Democracy.” Government and Opposition 41(3): 327346.Google Scholar
Downs, Anthony. 1957. An Economic Theory of Democracy. Boston: Addison-Wesley Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Dryzek, John S. 2000. Deliberative Democracy and Beyond. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Dryzek, John S. and List, Christian. 2003. “Social Choice Theory and Deliberative Democracy: A Reconciliation.” British Journal of Political Science 33(1):128.Google Scholar
Duch, Raymond M. and Stevenson, Randolph T.. 2008. The Economic Vote: How Political and Economic Institutions Condition Election Results. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dunn, John. 1999. Situating Political Accountability. In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, eds. Przeworski, Adam, Manin, Bernard and Stokes, Susan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dunn, John. 2005. Democracy: A History. New York: Atlantic Monthly Press.Google Scholar
Dworkin, Ronald. 2000. Sovereign Virtue: The Theory and Practice of Equality. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Egan, Patrick J. 2014. “Double-Peaked Policy Preferences and ‘Do Something’ Politics.” Journal of Politics 76(2):333349.Google Scholar
Elster, Jon. 2013. Securities Against Misrule: Juries, Assemblies, Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Estlund, David M. 2008. Democratic Authority. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Farrar, Cynthia, Fishkin, James S., Green, Donald P., List, Christian, Luskin, Robert C., and Paluck, Elizabeth Levy. 2010. “Disaggregating Deliberation’s Effects: An Experiment within a Deliberative Poll.British Journal of Political Science 40(2):333347.Google Scholar
Fearon, James. 1999. Electoral Accountability and the Control of Politicians: Selecting Good Types versus Sanctioning Poor Performance. In Democracy, Accountability, and Representation, eds. Przeworski, Adam, Manin, Bernard and Stokes, Susan. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Ferejohn, John. 1986. “Incumbent Performance and Electoral Control.” Public Choice 50:526.Google Scholar
Ferraz, Claudio and Finan, Frederico. 2008. “Exposing Corrupt Politicians: The Effects of Brazil’s Publicly Released Audits on Electoral Outcomes.” The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(2):703745.Google Scholar
Fiorina, Morris P. 1981. Retrospective Voting in American National Elections. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Fishkin, James S. 2009. When the People Speak: Deliberative Democracy and Public Consultation. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Fowler, Anthony and Hall, Andrew B.. 2016. “The Elusive Quest for Convergence.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 11(1):131149.Google Scholar
Fowler, Anthony and Hall, Andrew B.. 2018. “Do Shark Attacks Influence Presidential Elections? Reassessing a Prominent Finding on Voter Competence.” The Journal of Politics 80(4). https://doi.org/10.1086/699244.Google Scholar
Fowler, Anthony and Montagnes, Pablo B.. 2015a. “College Football, Elections, and False-Positive Results in Observational Research.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112(45):1380013804.Google Scholar
Fowler, Anthony and Montagnes, Pablo B.. 2015b. “Reply to Healy et al.: Value of Ex Ante Predictions and Independent Tests for Assessing False-Positive Results.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112(48):E6592E6592.Google Scholar
Gasper, John T. and Reeves, Andrew. 2011. “Make It Rain? Retrospection and the Attentive Electorate in the Context of Natural Disasters.” American Journal of Political Science 55(2):340355.Google Scholar
Gastil, John. 2000. By Popular Demand: Revitalizing Representative Democracy Through Deliberative Elections. Berkeley, CA: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Gastil, John, Knobloch, Katherine R. and Richards, Robert. 2015. Empowering Voters through Better Information: Analysis of the Citizens’ Initiative Review, 2010– 2014. Technical report, The Democracy Fund.Google Scholar
Gastil, John, Knobloch, Katherine R., Reedy, Justin, Henkels, Mark and Cramer, Katherine. 2018. “Assessing the Electoral Impact of the 2010 Oregon Citizens’ Initiative Review.” American Politics Research 46(3):534563.Google Scholar
Gehlbach, Scott. 2013. Formal Models of Domestic Politics. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gerber, Alan S., Green, Donald P. and Larimer, Christopher W.. 2008. “Social Pressure and Voter Turnout: Evidence from a Large-Scale Field Experiment.” American Political Science Review 102(1):3348.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence: Economic Inequality and Political Power in America. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin and Page, Benjamin I.. 2014. “Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens.” Perspectives on Politics 12(3): 564581.Google Scholar
Gourevitch, Alex. 2015. From Slavery to the Cooperative Commonwealth: Labor and Republican Liberty in the Nineteenth Century. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gourevitch, Alex. 2016. “The Limits of a Basic Income: Means and Ends of Workplace Democracy.” Basic Income Studies 11(1):1728.Google Scholar
Green, Jeffrey E. 2010. The Eyes of the People: Democracy in an Age of Spectatorship. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hamilton, Alexander, Madison, James and Jay, John. 2003. The Federalist with Letters of “Brutus. Ed. Ball, Terence. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, Daniel M. 1992. Essays on Philosophy and Economic Methodology. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Healy, Andrew J., Malhotra, Neil and Mo, Cecilia Hyunjung. 2010. “Irrelevant Events Affect Voters’ Evaluations of Government Performance.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 107(29):12804– 12809.Google Scholar
Healy, Andrew and Malhotra, Neil. 2009. “Myopic Voters and Natural Disaster Policy.” American Political Science Review 100(3):387406.Google Scholar
Healy, Andrew and Malhotra, Neil. 2010. “Random Events, Economic Losses, and Retrospective Voting: Implications for Democratic Competence.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 5(2):193208.Google Scholar
Healy, Andrew and Malhotra, Neil. 2013. “Retrospective Voting Reconsidered.” Annual Review of Political Science 16:285306.Google Scholar
Healy, Andrew, Malhotra, Neil and Mo, Cecilia Hyunjung. 2015. “Determining False-Positives Requires Considering the Totality of Evidence.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 112(48):E6591E6591.Google Scholar
Hibbs, Douglas A. 2006. Voting and the Macroeconomy. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Economy, eds. Weingast, Barry R. and Wittman, Donald A.. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 565586.Google Scholar
Hobbes, Thomas. 1998. On the Citizen. Eds. Richard Tuck and Michael Silverthorne. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1929. “Stability in Competition.” The Economic Journal 39(153): 4157.Google Scholar
Hsieh, Nien-hê. 2005. “Rawlsian Justice and Workplace Republicanism.” Social Theory and Practice 31(1):115142.Google Scholar
Huber, Gregory A., Hill, Seth J. and Lenz, Gabriel S.. 2012. “Sources of Bias in Retrospective Decision Making: Experimental Evidence on Voters’ Limitations in Controlling Incumbents.” American Political Science Review 106(4):720741.Google Scholar
Ingham, Sean. 2015. “Theorems and Models in Political Theory: An Application to Pettit on Popular Control.” The Good Society 24(1):98117.Google Scholar
Ingham, Sean. 2016a. “Popular Rule in Schumpeter’s Democracy.Political Studies 64(4):10711087.Google Scholar
Ingham, Sean. 2016b. “Social Choice and Popular Control.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 28(2):331349.Google Scholar
Ingham, Sean. 2018. “Why Arrow’s Theorem Matters for Political Theory Even If Preference Cycles Never Occur.” Public Choice. https://doi.org/10.1007/s11127–018–0521–9, last accessed August 28, 2018.Google Scholar
Ingham, Sean and Levin, Ines. 2018a. “Effects of Deliberative Minipublics on Public Opinion: Experimental Evidence from a Survey on Social Security Reform.” International Journal of Public Opinion Research 30(1):5178.Google Scholar
Ingham, Sean and Levin, Ines. 2018b. “Can Deliberative Minipublics Influence Public Opinion? Theory and Experimental Evidence.Political Research Quarterly 71(3): 654667.Google Scholar
Jacobs, Lawrence R. and Page, Benjamin I.. 2005. “Who Influences U.S. Foreign Policy?American Political Science Review 99(1):107123.Google Scholar
Johnson, James. 2014. “Models among the Political Theorists.” American Journal of Political Science 58(3):547560.Google Scholar
Karol, David and Miguel, Edward. 2007. “The Electoral Cost of War: Iraq Casualties and the 2004 U.S. Presidential Election.” The Journal of Politics 69(3):633648.Google Scholar
Key, V. O. 1966. The Responsible Electorate: Rationality in Presidential Voting, 1936– 1960. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1989. Congressmen’s Voting Decisions. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack and Johnson, James. 1994. “Aggregation and Deliberation: On the Possibility of Democratic Legitimacy.” Political Theory 22(2):277296.Google Scholar
Knight, Jack and Johnson, James. 2011. The Priority of Democracy: Political Consequences of Pragmatism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kolodny, Niko. 2014. “Rule over None II: Social Equality and the Justification of Democracy.” Philosophy & Public Affairs 42(4):287336.Google Scholar
Kriner, Douglas L. and Shen, Francis X.. 2007. “Iraq Casualties and the 2006 Senate Elections.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 32(4):507530.Google Scholar
Kurrild-Klitgaard, Peter. 2017. “Trump, Condorcet and Borda: Voting Paradoxes in the 2016 Republican Presidential Primaries.” European Journal of Political Economy 50. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.ejpoleco.2017.10.003.Google Scholar
Landa, Dimitri and Pevnick, Ryan. N.d. “What Could Justify Representative Democracy.” Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Landemore, Hélène. 2012. Democratic Reason: Politics, Collective Intelligence, and the Rule of the Many. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Landemore, Hélène. 2017. “Deliberative Democracy as Open, Not (Just) Representative Democracy.” Daedalus 146(3):5163.Google Scholar
Lane, Melissa. 2016. Popular Sovereignty as Control of Office-Holders: Aristotle on Greek Democracy. In Popular Sovereignty in Historical Perspective, eds. Bourke, Richard and Skinner, Quentin. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lax, Jeffrey R. and Phillips, Justin H.. 2009. “Gay Rights in the States: Public Opinion and Policy Responsiveness.” American Political Science Review 103(3):367386.Google Scholar
Bihan, Le, Patrick, . 2016. “Popular Referendum and Electoral Accountability.” Political Science Research and Methods 6(4):715731.Google Scholar
Le Breton, Michel. 1987. “On the Core of Voting Games.Social Choice and Welfare 4(4):295305.Google Scholar
Lee, David S. Enrico Moretti, and Butler, Matthew J.. 2004. “Do Voters Affect or Elect Policies? Evidence from the U. S. House.The Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(3):807859.Google Scholar
Lewis-Beck, Michael S. and Stegmaier, Mary. 2009. Economic Models of Voting. In The Oxford Handbook of Political Behavior, eds. Dalton, Russell J. and Klingemann, Hans-Dieter. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 518537.Google Scholar
Lindbeck, Assar and Weibull, Jörgen W.. 1987. “Balanced-Budget Redistribution as the Outcome of Political Competition.” Public Choice 52(3):273297.Google Scholar
List, Christian. 2002. “Two Concepts of Agreement.” The Good Society 11(1):7279.Google Scholar
List, Christian and Valentini, Laura. 2016. The Methodology of Political Theory. In The Oxford Handbook of Philosophical Methodology, eds. Cappelen, Herman, Gendler, Tamar Szabó and Hawthorne, John. New York: Oxford University Press, pp. 525550.Google Scholar
List, Christian and Pettit, Philip. 2011. Group Agency: The Possibility, Design, and Status of Corporate Agents. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
List, Christian, Luskin, Robert C., Fishkin, James S. and McLean, Iain. 2012. “Deliberation, Single-Peakedness, and the Possibility of Meaningful Democracy: Evidence from Deliberative Polls.” The Journal of Politics 75(1):8095.Google Scholar
Locke, John. 1988. Two Treatises of Government. Ed. Laslett, Peter. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lovett, Frank. 2010. A General Theory of Domination and Justice. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Lupia, Arthur and Matsusaka, John G.. 2004. “Direct Democracy: New Approaches to Old Questions.” Annual Review of Political Science 7:463482.Google Scholar
Mackie, Gerry. 2003. Democracy Defended. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Manin, Bernard. 1997. The Principles of Representative Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mansbridge, Jane. 2009. “A ‘Selection Model’ of Political Representation.” Journal of Political Philosophy 17(4):369398.Google Scholar
Marx, Karl. 1977. Karl Marx: Selected Writings. Ed. McLellan, David. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Maskin, Eric and Tirole, Jean. 2004. “The Politician and the Judge: Accountability in Government.” The American Economic Review 94(4):10341054.Google Scholar
Matsusaka, John G. 2010. “Popular Control of Public Policy: A Quantitative Approach.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 5(2):133167.Google Scholar
May, Kenneth O. 1952. “A Set of Independent Necessary and Sufficient Conditions for Simple Majority Decision.” Econometrica 20:680684.Google Scholar
McCormick, John P. 2006. “Contain the Wealthy and Patrol the Magistrates: Restoring Elite Accountability to Popular Government.” American Political Science Review 100(2):147163.Google Scholar
McCormick, John P. 2011. Machiavellian Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McGann, Anthony. 2006. The Logic of Democracy. Ann Arbor, MI: The University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard. 1979. “General Conditions for Global Intransitivities in Formal Voting Models.” Econometrica 47:10851112.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard and Schofield, Norman. 1987. “Generalized Symmetry Conditions at a Core Point.” Econometrica 55:923933.Google Scholar
Medearis, John. 2001. Joseph Schumpeter’s Two Theories of Democracy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Miller, David. 1992. “Deliberative Democracy and Social Choice.” Political Studies XL (special issue):5467.Google Scholar
Mounk, Yascha. 2018. The People vs. Democracy: Why Our Freedom Is in Danger & How to Save It. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Müller, Jan-Werner. 2016. What Is Populism? Philadelphia, PA: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Pattanaik, Prasanta K. 2014. Introduction. In The Arrow Impossibility Theorem, eds. Maskin, Eric and Sen, Amartya. New York: Columbia University Press, pp. 121.Google Scholar
Patty, John W. and Penn, Elizabeth Maggie. 2014. Social Choice and Legitimacy: The Possibilities of Impossibility. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Patty, John W. and Penn, Elizabeth Maggie. 2015. “Aggregation, Evaluation, and Social Choice Theory.” The Good Society 24(1):4972.Google Scholar
Penn, Elizabeth Maggie, Patty, John W. and Gailmard, Sean. 2011. “Manipulation and Single-Peakedness: A General Result.” American Journal of Political Science 55(2):436449.Google Scholar
Persson, Torsten and Tabellini, Guido Enrico. 2000. Political Economics: Explaining Economic Policy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Pettit, Philip. 1991. Decision Theory and Folk Psychology. In Foundations of Decision Theory, eds. Bacharach, Michael and Hurley, Susan. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Pettit, Philip. 2008. “Three Conceptions of Democratic Control.” Constellations 15(1):4655.Google Scholar
Pettit, Philip. 2012. On the People’s Terms: A Republican Theory and Model of Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pildes, Richard H. and Anderson, Elizabeth S.. 1990. “Slinging Arrows at Democracy: Social Choice Theory, Value Pluralism, and Democratic Politics.” Columbia Law Review 90(8):21212214.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1967. “A Notion of Equilibrium and Its Possibility under Majority Rule.” American Economic Review 57(4):787806.Google Scholar
Poole, Keith T. and Rosenthal, Howard. 2007. Ideology and Congress. 2nd ed. New Brunswick, NJ: Transaction Publishers.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. and Glen Weyl, E.. 2015. “Voting Squared: Quadratic Voting in Democratic Politics.” Vanderbilt Law Review 68:441.Google Scholar
Posner, Eric A. and Glen Weyl, E.. 2018. Radical Markets: Uprooting Capitalism and Democracy for a Just Society. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Przeworski, Adam, Manin, Bernard and Stokes, Susan, eds. 1999. Democracy, Accountability, and Representation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Rahman, K. Sabeel. 2017. Democracy against Domination. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Rawls, John. 1971. A Theory of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Regenwetter, Michel, Bernard, Grofman, Marley, A. A. J. and Tsetlin, Ilia. 2006. Behavioral Social Choice: Probabilistic Models, Statistical Inference, and Applications. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Riker, William. 1982. Liberalism against Populism. New York: Waveland Press.Google Scholar
Risse, Mathias. 2004. “Arguing for Majority Rule.” Journal of Political Philosophy 12(1):4164.Google Scholar
Saari, Donald G. 1997. “The Generic Existence of a Core for q-Rules.” Economic Theory 9(2):219260.Google Scholar
Saari, Donald G. 2003. “Capturing the ‘Will of the People’.” Ethics 113(2):333349.Google Scholar
Saunders-Hastings, Emma. 2018. “Plutocratic Philanthropy.” The Journal of Politics 80(1):149161.Google Scholar
Schumpeter, Joseph. 1942. Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy. New York: Harper & Brothers.Google Scholar
Scwhartzberg, Melissa. 2014. Counting the Many: The Origins and Limits of Supermajority Rule. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1977 a. “On Weights and Measures: Informational Constraints in Social Welfare Analysis.” Econometrica, 45(7): 15391572.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1977 b. “Social Choice Theory: A Re-Examination.” Econometrica, 45(1): 5388.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Ian. 2003. The State of Democratic Theory. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Shapiro, Ian. 2016. Politics against Domination. Cambridge, MA: The Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1979. “Institutional Arrangements and Equilibrium in Multidimensional Voting Models.” American Journal of Political Science, 23(1): 2759.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1986. Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions. In Political Science: The Science of Politics, ed. Herbert F. Weisberg. Algora Publishing, p. 51.Google Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. and Weingast, Barry R.. 1981. “Structure-Induced Equilibrium and Legislative Choice.” Public Choice 37(3):503519.Google Scholar
Sher, Itai. 2017. “Neutral Freedom and Freedom as Control.” Unpublished manuscript. Available at SSRN: https://ssrn.com/abstract=2652913 or http://dx.doi.org/10.2139/ssrn.2652913.Google Scholar
Skinner, Quentin. 1998. Liberty before Liberalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Snyder, James M. and Strömberg, David. 2010. “Press Coverage and Political Accountability.” Journal of Political Economy 118(2):355408.Google Scholar
Snyder, James M. and Ting, Michael M.. 2003. “Roll Calls, Party Labels, and Elections.” Political Analysis 11(4):419444.Google Scholar
Thompson, Dennis. 2002. Just Elections: Creating a Fair Electoral Process in the United States. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Tideman, Nicolaus. 2006. Collective Decision and Voting: The Potential for Public Choice. Burlington, VT: Ashgate Publishing Company.Google Scholar
Tocqueville, Alexis de. 2000. Democracy in America. New York: Perennial.Google Scholar
Tuck, Richard. 2016. The Sleeping Sovereign: The Invention of Modern Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Verba, Sidney, Schlozman, Kay Lehman and Brady, Henry E.. 1995. Voice and Equality: Civic Voluntarism in American Politics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Viehoff, Daniel. 2014. “Democratic Equality and Political Authority.” Philosophy & Public Affairs 42(4):337375.Google Scholar
Waldron, Jeremy. 1999. The Dignity of Legislation. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Warren, Mark and Pearse, Hilary, eds. 2008. Designing Deliberative Democracy. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Bibliography
  • Sean Ingham, University of California, San Diego
  • Book: Rule by Multiple Majorities
  • Online publication: 28 December 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108683821.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Bibliography
  • Sean Ingham, University of California, San Diego
  • Book: Rule by Multiple Majorities
  • Online publication: 28 December 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108683821.009
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Bibliography
  • Sean Ingham, University of California, San Diego
  • Book: Rule by Multiple Majorities
  • Online publication: 28 December 2018
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108683821.009
Available formats
×