Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-2brh9 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T08:14:59.539Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  19 October 2023

H. Spencer Banzhaf
Affiliation:
North Carolina State University
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
Pricing the Priceless
A History of Environmental Economics
, pp. 239 - 276
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abraham, C., and Thedié, J.. 1960. “Le prix d’une vie humaine dans les decisions economiques.” Revue Francaise de Recherche Operationnelle 4: 157–68.Google Scholar
Abraham, Katharine G., and Mackie, Christopher, eds. 2005. Beyond the Market: Designing Nonmarket Accounts for the United States. National Research Council, Committee on National Statistics. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.Google Scholar
Adelman, Irma, and Griliches, Zvi. 1961. “On an Index of Quality Change.” Journal of the American Statistical Association 56: 535–48.Google Scholar
Adler, Matthew D. 2016. “Benefit–Cost Analysis and Distributional Weights: An Overview.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 10(2): 264–85.Google Scholar
Alacevich, Michele. 2020. “Paul Rosenstein-Rodan and the Birth of Development Economics.” CHOPE Working Paper 2020-04.Google Scholar
Alchian, A.A., Bodenhorn, G.D., Enke, S., Hitch, C.H., Hirshleifer, J., and Marshall, A.W.. 1951. “What is the Best System?” Jan. 4. RA D-860.Google Scholar
Allin, Bushrod W. 1953. “Is Group Choice Part of Economics?The Quarterly Journal of Economics 67(3): 362–79.Google Scholar
Amadae, S.M. 2003. Rationalizing Capitalist Democracy: The Cold War Origins of Rational Choice Liberalism. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
American Association of State Highway Officials. 1951. A Policy on Road User Benefit Analyses for Highway Improvements. Part I. Passenger Cars in Rural Areas.Google Scholar
Anderson, Terry L., and Hill, Peter J.. 2004. The Not So Wild, Wild West: Property Rights on the Frontier. Stanford: Stanford University Press.Google Scholar
Andersson, Julius J. 2019. “Carbon Taxes and CO2 Emissions: Sweden as a Case Study.” American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 11(4): 130.Google Scholar
Anthoff, David, and Emmerling, Johannes. 2019. “Inequality and the Social Cost of Carbon.” Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 6(2): 243–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J. 1969. “The Organization of Economic Activity: Issues Pertinent to the Choice of Market versus Non-Market Allocation.” In The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPB System, 4764. US Congress, Joint Economic Committee. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., and Fisher, Anthony C.. 1974. “Environmental Preservation, Uncertainty, and Irreversibility.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 88(2): 312–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth J., Cropper, Maureen L., Eads, George C., Hahn, Robert W., et al. 1996. “Is There a Role for Benefit-Cost Analysis in Environmental, Health, and Safety Regulation?Science 272(5259): 221–22.Google Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth, Dasgupta, Partha, Goulder, Lawrence, Daily, Gretchen, et al. 2004. “Are We Consuming Too Much?Journal of Economic Perspectives 18(3): 147–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arrow, Kenneth, Solow, Robert, Portney, Paul R., Leamer, Edward E., Radner, Roy, and Schuman, Howard. 1993. “NOAA Panel on Contingent Valuation.” 15 CFR Chapter IX, Federal Register 58: 4601–14.Google Scholar
Ashenfelter, Orley. 2006. “Measuring the Value of a Statistical Life: Problems and Prospects.” Economic Journal 116: C10C23.Google Scholar
Ashton, Peter M., Shabman, Leonard A., and Cooper-Ruska, Catherine. 1976. “A Legal-Historical Analysis of Navigation User Charges.” Journal of the Water Resources Planning and Management Division 102(1): 89100.Google Scholar
Aslanbeigui, Nahid, and Oakes, Guy. 2015. Arthur Cecil Pigou. London: Palgrave Macmillan.Google Scholar
Association of Environmental and Resource Economists (AERE). 1995. Membership Handbook. https://aere.memberclicks.net/assets/docs/handbook2016_000.pdfGoogle Scholar
Ayres, Robert U., and Kneese, Allen V.. 1969. “Production, Consumption, and Externalities.” American Economic Review 59(3): 282–97.Google Scholar
Ayres, Robert U., Van den Berrgh, Jeroen, and Gowdy, John. 2001. “Strong Versus Weak Sustainability: Economics, Natural Sciences, and Consilience.” Environmental Ethics 23(2): 155–68.Google Scholar
Azzi, Cory F., and Cox, James C.. 1973. “Equity and Efficiency in Evaluation of Public Programs.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 87: 495502.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E. 2017. “From Business Cycle Theory to the Theory of Employment: Alvin Hansen and Paul Samuelson.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 39(1): 8999.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., and Biddle, Jeff. 2000. “The Concept of Applied Economics: A History of Ambiguity and Multiple Meanings.” In Toward a History of Applied Economics, ed. by Backhouse, Roger E. and Biddle, Jeff. History of Political Economy 32(S): 124. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., and Cherrier, Béatrice. 2017. “The Age of the Applied Economist: The Transformation of Economics since the 1970s.” In The Age of the Applied Economist: The Transformation of Economics since the 1970s, ed. by Backhouse, Roger E. and Cherrier, Béatrice. History of Political Economy 49(S): 133. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., and Medema, Steve G.. 2009a. “Defining Economics: The Long Road to Acceptance of the Robbins Definition.” Economica 76: 805–20.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., and Medema, Steven G.. 2009b. “Retrospectives: On the Definition of Economics.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 23(1): 221–33.Google Scholar
Backhouse, Roger E., Bateman, Bradley, and Medema, Steven. 2010. “The Reception of Marshall in the United States.” In The Impact of Alfred Marshall’s Ideas, ed. by Raffaelli, Tiziano, Becattini, Giacomo, Caldari, Katia, and Dardi, Marco, 5980. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Bailey, Martin J. 1956. “The Welfare Cost of Inflationary Finance.” Journal of Political Economy 64(2): 93110.Google Scholar
Bailey, Martin J. 1968. “Comments.” In Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis, ed. by Chase, Samuel B., Jr., 162–66. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Balisciano, Márcia L. 1998. “Hope for America: American Notions of Economic Planning between Pluralism and Neoclassicism, 1930–1950.” In From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, ed. by Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm. History of Political Economy 30(S): 153–78. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Balogh, Brian. 2002. “Scientific Forestry and the Roots of the Modern American State: Gifford Pinchot’s Path to Progressive Reform.” Environmental History 7(2): 198225.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2000. “Productive Nature and the Net Product: Quesnay’s Economies Animal and Political.” History of Political Economy 32(3): 517–51.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2001. “Quantifying the Qualitative: Quality-Adjusted Price Indexes, 1915–1961.” In The Age of Economic Measurement, ed. by Klein, Judy L. and Morgan, Mary S.. History of Political Economy 33(S): 345–70. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2004. “The Form and Function of Price Indexes: An Historical Accounting.” History of Political Economy 36(4): 589616.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2005. “Green Price Indices.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 49(2): 262–80.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2006. “The Other Economics Department: Demand and Value Theory in Early Agricultural Economics.” In Agreement on Demand: The History of 20th Century Demand Theory, ed. by Mirowski, Philip and Wade Hands, D.. History of Political Economy 38(S): 931. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2010a. “The Chicago School of Welfare Economics.” In The Elgar Companion to the Chicago School, ed. by Emmett, Ross, 5969. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2010b. “The Free Market Environmentalist Case for Cap and Trade.” Working Paper, Property and Environment Research Center.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2011a. “Consumer Sovereignty in the History of Environmental Economics.” History of Political Economy 43(2): 339–45.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2011b. “Regulatory Impact Analyses of Environmental Justice Effects.” Journal of Land Use and Environmental Law 27(1): 130.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2020. “The Conservative Roots of Carbon Pricing.” National Affairs.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer. 2022. “Financing Outdoor Recreation: An Introduction.” Land Economics 98(3): 421–27.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, H. Spencer, Fitzgerald, Timothy, and Schnier, Kurt. 2013. “Nonregulatory Approaches to the Environment: Coasean and Pigouvian Perspectives.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 7(2): 238–58.Google Scholar
Banzhaf, Spencer, Ma, Lala, and Timmins, Christopher. 2019. “Environmental Justice: The Economics of Race, Place, and Pollution.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 33(1): 185208.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Barber, William J. 1985. From New Era to New Deal: Herbert Hoover, the Economists, and American Economic Policy, 1921–1933. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barbier, Edward B. 2011. Capitalizing on Nature: Ecosystems as Natural Assets. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Barbier, Edward B. 2021. “The Evolution of Economic Views on Natural Resource Scarcity.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 15(1): 2444.Google Scholar
Barlow, E.J. 1950. “Preliminary Proposal for Air Defense Study.” October. RA D(L)-816-2.Google Scholar
Barnett, Harold J., and Morse, Chandler. 1963. Scarcity and Growth: The Economics of Natural Resource Availability. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Bateman, Bradley W. 1998. “Clearing the Ground: The Demise of the Social Gospel Movement and the Rise of Neoclassicism in American Economics.” In From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, ed. by Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm. History of Political Economy 30(S): 2952. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Bateman, Bradley W., and Kapstein, Ethan B.. 1999. “Retrospectives: Between God and the Market: The Religious Roots of the American Economic Association.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 13(4): 249–58.Google Scholar
Bateman, Ian J., Harwood, Amii R., Mace, Georgina M., Watson, Robert T., et al. 2013. “Bringing Ecosystem Services into Economic Decision-Making: Land Use in the United Kingdom.” Science 341(6141): 4550.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Bator, Francis M. 1957. “The Simple Analytics of Welfare Maximization.” American Economic Review 47(1): 2259.Google Scholar
Bator, Francis M. 1958. “The Anatomy of Market Failure.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 71(3): 351–79.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. [1952] 1965. Welfare Economics and the Theory of the State. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J. 1970. “Review of Cost and Choice, by James M. Buchanan.” Journal of Economic Literature 8(4): 1210–11.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J., and Oates, Wallace E.. 1971. “The Use of Standards and Prices for Protection of the Environment.” Scandinavian Journal of Economics 73(1): 4254.Google Scholar
Baumol, William J., and Oates, Wallace E.. 1975. The Theory of Environmental Policy. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1965. “A Theory of the Allocation of Time.” Economic Journal 75: 493517.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Becker, Gary S. 1976. The Economic Approach to Human Behavior. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Beckmann, Martin J., and Thomas, Marschak. 1955. “An Economic Approach to Location Theory.” Kyklos 8(2): 109–22.Google Scholar
Beckmann, Martin J., McGuire, C. B., and Winsten, Christopher B.. 1956. Studies in the Economics of Transportation. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Bennett, Brett. 2015. Plantations and Protected Areas: A Global History of Forest Management. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Berkman, Richard L., and Kip Viscusi, W.. 1973. Damming the West. Ralph Nader’s Study Group Report on the Bureau of Reclamation. New York: Grossman Publishers.Google Scholar
Berman, Elizabeth Popp. 2017. “From Economic to Social Regulation: How the Deregulatory Moment Strengthened Economists’ Policy Position.” In The Age of the Applied Economist: The Transformation of Economics since the 1970s, ed. by Backhouse, Roger E. and Cherrier, Béatrice. History of Political Economy 49(S): 187212. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Berman, Elizabeth Popp. 2022. Thinking Like an Economist: How Efficiency Replaced Equality in US Public Policy. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Berta, Nathalie. 2017. “On the Definition of Externality as a Missing Market.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 24(2): 287318.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berta, Nathalie. 2019. “The History of Incentives in Environmental Economics.” In Incentives and Environmental Policies: From Theory to Empirical Novelties, ed. by Ouvrard, Benjamin and Stenger, Anne, 3154. London: ISTE.Google Scholar
Berta, Nathalie. 2020. “Efficiency without Optimality: A Pragmatic Compromise for Environmental Policies in the Late 1960s.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 42(4): 539–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berta, Nathalie. 2021. “A Note on John Dales and the Early History of Emissions Trading: Mixing Standards and Markets for Rights.” Cahiers d’économie politique 79(1): 6184.Google Scholar
Berta, Nathalie, and Bertrand, Elodie. 2014. “Market Internalization of Externalities: What is Failing?Journal of the History of Economic Thought 36(3): 331–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bertrand, Elodie. 2015. “From the Firm to Economic Policy: The Problem of Coase’s Cost.” History of Political Economy 47(3): 481510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bianchi, Marina. 1998. “Tastes for Novelty and Novel Tastes: The Role of Human Agency in Consumption.” In The Active Consumer: Novelty and Surprise in Consumer Choice, ed. by Bianchi, Marina, 6486. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Bianchi, Marina, and De Marchi, Neil. 1997. “The Taste-Less Theory of Consumer Choice Meets Novelty.” In Pluralism in Economics, ed. by Salanti, Andrea and Screpanti, Ernesto, 177–90. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Biddle, Jeff. 2021. “Statistical Inference in Economics in the 1920s and 1930s: The Crop and Livestock Forecasts of the U.S. Department of Agriculture.” In Exploring the History of Statistical Inference in Economics, ed. by Biddle, Jeff and Boumans, Marcel. History of Political Economy 53(S): 5380. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Bilmes, Linda, and Stiglitz, Joseph. 2006. “The Economic Costs of the Iraq War: An Appraisal Three Years after the Beginning of the Conflict.” NBER Working Paper 12054.Google Scholar
Bishop, Richard C., and Heberlein, Thomas. 1979. “Measuring Values of Extra-Market Goods: Are Indirect Measures Biased?American Journal of Agricultural Economics 61(5): 926–30.Google Scholar
Bishop, Richard C., Boyle, Kevin J., Carson, Richard T., Chapman, David, et al. 2017. “Putting a Value on Injuries to Natural Assets: The BP Oil Spill.” Science 356(6335): 253–54.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Blomquist, Glenn C. 2015. “Value of Life, Economics of.” In International Encyclopedia of Social and Behavioral Sciences, ed. by Wright, James D., 2nd ed., 16133–39. Oxford: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Bohm, Peter. 1972. “Estimating Demand for Public Goods: An Experiment.” European Economic Review 3(2): 111–30.Google Scholar
Boianovsky, Mauro, and Hoover, Kevin D.. 2009. “The Neoclassical Growth Model and Twentieth-Century Economics.” In Robert Solow and the Development of Growth Economics, ed. by Boianovsky, Mauro and Hoover, Kevin D.. History of Political Economy 41(S): 123. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Bouk, Dan. 2015. How Our Days Became Numbered: Risk and the Rise of the Statistical Individual. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1945. “The Consumption Concept in Economic Theory.” American Economic Review 35(2): 114.Google Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1955. Economic Analysis, 3rd ed. New York: Harper Brothers.Google Scholar
Boulding, Kenneth E. 1966. “The Economics of the Coming Spaceship Earth.” In Environmental Quality in a Growing Economy, ed. by Jarrett, Henry, 314. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Boulier, Bryan L., and Goldfarb, Robert S.. 1998. “On the Use and Nonuse of Surveys in Economics.” Journal of Economic Methodology 5(1): 121.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel J. 2005. How Economists Model the World into Numbers. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Boumans, Marcel J. 2009. “Observations of an Expert.” History of Observation in Economics Working Paper Series, Working Paper #4.Google Scholar
Bowers, Edward A. 1891. “The Present Condition of the Forests on Public Lands.” Publications of the American Economic Association 6(3): 5774.Google Scholar
Bowes, Michael D., and Krutilla, John V.. 1985. “Multiple Use Management of Public Forestland.” In Handbook of Natural Resource and Energy Economics, Vol. 2, ed. by Kneese, Allen V. and Sweeney, James L., 531–69. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Bowley, Arthur L. 1920. “Cost of Living and Wage Determination.” Economic Journal 30(117): 114–17.Google Scholar
Boyd, James, and Spencer Banzhaf, H.. 2007. “What are Ecosystem Services? The Need for Standardized Environmental Accounting Units.” Ecological Economics 63(2–3): 616–26.Google Scholar
Breit, William, and Hirsch, Barry T., eds. 2009. “Thomas C. Schelling.” In The Lives of the Laureates, 5th ed., 393420. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Bright, Geoff, Connors, Emily, and Grice, Joe. 2019. “Measuring Natural Capital: Towards Accounts for the UK and a Basis for Improved Decision-Making.” Oxford Review of Economic Policy 35(1): 88108.Google Scholar
Bromley, Daniel W., and Beattie, Bruce R.. 1973. “On the Incongruity of Program Objectives and Project Evaluation: An Example from the Reclamation Program.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 55: 472–76.Google Scholar
Bromley, Daniel W., Schmid, A. Allan, and Lord, William B.. 1971. “Public Water Resource Project Planning and Evaluation.” Center for Resource Policy Studies and Programs, The University of Wisconsin.Google Scholar
Brooks, David. 2000. Bobos in Paradise: The New Upper Class and How They Got There. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Brooks, Karl Boyd. 2006. Public Power, Private Dams: The Hells Canyon High Dam Controversy. Seattle: University of Washington Press.Google Scholar
Brookshire, David S., Randall, Alan, and Stoll, John R.. 1980. “Valuing Increments and Decrements in Natural Resource Service Flows.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 62(3): 478–88.Google Scholar
Broome, John. 1978. “Trying to Value a Life.” Journal of Public Economics 9: 91100.Google Scholar
Brown, William G., Singh, Ajmer, and Castle, Emery N.. 1962. “An Economic Evaluation of the Oregon Salmon and Steelhead Sport Fishery.” Agricultural Experiment Station, Corvallis, OR.Google Scholar
Bruni, Luigino, and Sugden, Robert. 2007. “The Road Not Taken: How Psychology Was Removed from Economics, and How It Might Be Brought Back.” Economic Journal 117: 146–73.Google Scholar
Buchanan, James M., and Stubblebine, W.M. Craig. 1962. “Externality.” Economica 29: 371–84.Google Scholar
Bullard, Robert D. 1994. Dumping in Dixie: Race, Class, and Environmental Quality, 2nd ed. Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Burke, Marshall, Hsiang, Solomon M., and Miguel, Edward. 2015. “Global Non-Linear Effect of Temperature on Economic Production.” Nature 527: 235–39.Google Scholar
Burt, Oscar R., and Brewer, Durward. 1971. “Estimation of Net Social Benefits from Outdoor Recreation.” Econometrica 39: 813–27.Google Scholar
Callicott, J. Baird. 1989. In Defense of the Land Ethic. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Callicott, J. Baird. 1994. “A Brief History of American Conservation Philosophy.” In Sustainable Ecological Systems, ed. by Covington, W. Wallace and Debano, Leonard F., 1014. Fort Collins: Rocky Mountain Forest & Range Experiment Station.Google Scholar
Callicott, J. Baird. 1999. Beyond the Land Ethic. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Callon, Michel. 1998. “Introduction: The Embeddedness of Economic Markets in Economics.” In The Laws of Markets, ed. by Callon, Michel, 157. Oxford: Blackwell.Google Scholar
Cameron, Trudy Ann. 2010. “Euthanizing the Value of a Statistical Life.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 4: 161–78.Google Scholar
Cannan, Edwin. 1922. Wealth: A Brief Explanation of the Causes of Economic Welfare, 2nd ed. London: P.S. King & Son.Google Scholar
Carleton, Tamma, and Greenstone, Michael. 2022. “A Guide to Updating the US Government’s Social Cost of Carbon.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 16(2): 196218.Google Scholar
Carlson, Jack. 1963. Valuation of Life Saving. Dissertation, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Carson, Richard T. 2011. Contingent Valuation: A Comprehensive Bibliography and History. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Carson, Richard T., and Michael Hanemann, W.. 2005. “Contingent Valuation.” In Handbook of Environmental Economics, ed. by Mäler, Karl-Göran and Vincent, Jeffrey, 821936. Amsterdam: Elsevier.Google Scholar
Carson, Richard T., Mitchell, Robert C., Hanemann, Michael, Kopp, Raymond J., Presser, Stanley, and Ruud, Paul A.. 2003. “Contingent Valuation and Lost Passive Use: Damages from the Exxon Valdez Oil Spill.” Environmental and Resource Economics 25(3): 257–86.Google Scholar
Carvalho, Jean-Paul. 2007. “An Interview with Thomas Schelling.” Oxonomics 2: 1–8.Google Scholar
Cason, Timothy N., and Plott, Charles R.. 2014. “Misconceptions and Game Form Recognition: Challenges to Theories of Revealed Preference and Framing.” Journal of Political Economy 122(6): 1235–70.Google Scholar
Castle, Emery N. 1965. “The Market Mechanism, Externalities, and Land Economics.” Journal of Farm Economics 47(3): 542–56.Google Scholar
Castle, Emery N. 1969. “Testimony Presented to the Water Resources Council Hearing in Portland, Oregon.” Aug. 11. AMP 79.Google Scholar
Castle, Emery N., and Youmans, Russell C.. 1968. “Economics in Regional Water Research and Policy.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 50: 1655–70.Google Scholar
Castle, Emery N., and Youmans, Russell C.. 1970. “Economics in Regional Water Research and Policy: Reply.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 52: 145–46.Google Scholar
Castle, Emery N., Kelso, Maurice M., and Gardner, Delworth. 1963. “Water Resources Development: A Review of New Federal Evaluation Procedures.” Journal of Farm Economics 45: 693704.Google Scholar
Castle, Emery N., Kelso, Maurice M., Stevens, Joe B., and Stoevener, Herbert H.. 1981. “Natural Resource Economics, 1946–75.” In A Survey of Agricultural Economics Literature, vol. 3, ed. by Martin, Lee R., 393500. Minneapolis: University of Minnesota Press.Google Scholar
Cherrier, Beatrice, and Fleury, Jean-Baptiste. 2017. “Economists’ Interest in Collective Decision after World War II: A History.” Public Choice 172(1): 2344.Google Scholar
Christensen, Paul P. 1989. “Historical Roots for Ecological Economics: Biophysical vs. Allocative Approaches.” Ecological Economics 1: 1736.Google Scholar
Cicchetti, Charles J., and Kerry Smith, V.. 1970. “A Noted on Jointly Supplied Mixed Goods.” Quarterly Review of Economics and Business 10(3): 9094.Google Scholar
Cicchetti, Charles J., and Kerry Smith, V.. 1973. “Congestion, Quality Deterioration, and Optimal Use: Wilderness Recreation in the Spanish Peaks Primitive Area.” Social Science Research 2: 1530.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cicchetti, Charles J., Davis, Robert K., Hanke, Steve H., and Haveman, Robert H.. 1973. “Evaluating Federal Water Projects: A Critique of Proposed Standards.” Science 181(4101): 723–28.Google Scholar
Cicchetti, Charles J., Fisher, Anthony C., and Kerry Smith, V.. 1976. “An Econometric Evaluation of a Generalized Consumer Surplus Measure: The Mineral King Controversy.” Econometrica 44(6): 1259–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V. 1947. “Capital Returns from Soil Conservation Practices.” Journal of Farm Economics 29: 1181–96.Google Scholar
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V. 1956. “Concepts Used as Economic Criteria for a System of Water Rights.” Land Economics 32(4): 295312.Google Scholar
Ciriacy-Wantrup, S.V., and Bishop, Richard C.. 1975. “‘Common Property’ as a Concept in Natural Resource Policy.” Natural Resources Journal 15(4): 713–27.Google Scholar
Clark, John Maurice. 1936. Preface to Social Economics. Ed. by Abramovitz, Moses and Ginzberg, Eli. New York: Farrar and Rinehart.Google Scholar
Clark, John Maurice, Grant, Eugene L., and Kelso, Maurice M.. 1952. Report of Panel of Consultants on Secondary or Indirect Benefits of Water Use Projects. Submitted to the Bureau of Reclamation.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion. 1951. Uncle Sam’s Acres. New York: Dodd, Mead & Company.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion. 1958. Statistics on Outdoor Recreation. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion. 1959a. “The Crisis in Outdoor Recreation.” American Forests, March-April. Reproduced as RFF Reprint #13.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion. 1959b. “Methods of Measuring the Demand for and Value of Outdoor Recreation.” Paper presented at a meeting of the Taylor-Hibbard Club, University of Wisconsin, Jan. 13. Reproduced as RFF Reprint #10.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion. 1981. New Deal Planning: The NRPB. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion. 1987. From Sagebrush to Sage: The Making of a Natural Resource Economist. Washington, DC: Ana Publications.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion, and Knetsch, Jack L.. 1963. “Outdoor Recreation Research: Some Concepts and Suggested Areas of Study.” Paper presented to the National Conference on Outdoor Recreation Research, Ann Arbor, MI. Reproduced as RFF Reprint #43.Google Scholar
Clawson, Marion, and Knetsch, Jack L.. 1966. Economics of Outdoor Recreation. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Coase, R.H. 1937. “The Nature of the Firm.” Economica 4: 386405.Google Scholar
Coase, R.H. 1959. “The Federal Communications Commission.” Journal of Law and Economics 2: 140.Google Scholar
Coase, R.H. 1960. “The Problem of Social Cost.” Journal of Law and Economics 3: 144.Google Scholar
Coates, Peter. 1998. Nature: Western Attitudes since Ancient Times. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Cobb, Gary D. 1973. “Evolving Water Policies in the United States.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 55: 1003–7.Google Scholar
Coffin, William G. 1863. Document No. 32. Report of the Commissioner of Indian Affairs for 1862. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Cohen, Jon S., and Weitzman, Martin L.. 1975. “A Marxian Model of Enclosures.” Journal of Development Economics 1(4): 287336.Google Scholar
Cohen, Lizabeth. 2003. A Consumers’ Republic: The Politics of Mass Consumption in Postwar America. New York: Alfred A. Knopf.Google Scholar
Collard, David. 1996. “Pigou and Future Generations: A Cambridge Tradition.” Cambridge Journal of Economics 20(5): 585–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Collins, Robert M. 1990. “The Emergence of Economic Growthmanship in the United States: Federal Policy and Economic Knowledge in the Truman Years.” In The State and Economic Knowledge, ed. Furner, Mary O. and Supple, Barry, 138–70. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Coman, Katharine. [1911] 2011. “Some Unsettled Problems of Irrigation.” American Economic Review 1(1): 119. Republished in vol. 101(1): 36–48.Google Scholar
Costanza, Robert, d’Arge, Ralph, De Groot, Rudolf, Farber, Stephen, et al. 1997. “The Value of The World’s Ecosystem Services and Natural Capital.” Nature 387(6630): 253–60.Google Scholar
Costanza, Robert, Farber, Stephen C., and Maxwell, Judith. 1989. “Valuation and Management of Wetlands Ecosystems.” Ecological Economics 1: 335–61.Google Scholar
Costanza, Robert, de Groot, Rudolf, Sutton, Paul, Van der Ploeg, Sander, et al. 2014. “Changes in the Global Value of Ecosystem Services.” Global Environmental Change 26: 152–58.Google Scholar
Coy, Peter. 1997. “The In Your Face Economist.” Businessweek. Accessed at www.bloomberg.com/news/articles/1997-06-29/the-in-your-face-economist.Google Scholar
Crabbé, Philippe J. 1983. “The Contribution of L.C. Gray to the Economic Theory of Exhaustible Natural Resources and Its Roots in the History of Economic Thought.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 10: 195220.Google Scholar
Craver, Earlene. 1986. “Patronage and the Directions of Research in Economics: The Rockefeller Foundation in Europe, 1924–38.” Minerva 24: 205–22.Google Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D. 1966. “The Structuring of Atmospheric Pollution Control Systems.” In The Economics of Air Pollution, ed. by Wolozin, Harold, 6186. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D. 1967. Some Economics of Air Pollution Control. Dissertation, University of Missouri.Google Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D. 1968. “Some Economics of Air Pollution Control.” Natural Resources Journal 8(2): 236–58.Google Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D. 1972. “On Air Pollution Control Instruments,” Loyola of Los Angeles Law Review 5: 280–97.Google Scholar
Crocker, Thomas D. 2011. “Trading Access to and Use of the Natural Environment: The Multiple Origins of ‘Cap and Trade’.” Working paper, University of Wyoming.Google Scholar
Cronon, William. 1995. “The Trouble with Wilderness; or, Getting Back to the Wrong Nature.” In Uncommon Ground: Toward Reinventing Nature, ed. by Cronon, William, 6990. New York: W.W. Norton.Google Scholar
Cropper, Maureen, Hammitt, James K., and Robinson, Lisa A.. 2011. “Valuing Mortality Risk Reductions: Progress and Challenges.” Annual Review of Resource Economics 3: 313–36.Google Scholar
Crutchfield, James A. 1962. “Valuation of Fishery Resources.” Land Economics 38: 145–54.Google Scholar
Cummings, Ronald G., Brookshire, David S., and Schulze, William D., eds. 1986. Valuing Environmental Goods: An Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld.Google Scholar
Currie, John Martin, Murphy, John A., and Schmitz, Andrew. 1971. “The Concept of Economic Surplus and Its Use in Economic Analysis.” Economic Journal 81: 741–99.Google Scholar
Currie, Lauchlin, and Sandilands, Roger. 1997. “Implications of an Endogenous Theory of Growth in Allyn Young’s Macroeconomic Concept of Increasing Returns.” History of Political Economy 29(3): 413–43.Google Scholar
Daily, Gretchen C., ed. 1997. Nature’s Services: Society’s Dependence on Natural Ecosystems. Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
Dales, J.H. 1968a. “Land, Water, and Ownership.” Canadian Journal of Economics 1(4): 791804.Google Scholar
Dales, J.H. 1968b. Pollution, Property, and Prices. Toronto: University of Toronto Press.Google Scholar
Darmstadter, Joel. 2003. “Hans H. Landsberg and Sam H. Schurr: Reflections and Appreciation.” Energy Journal 24(4): 116.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha. 2021. The Economics of Biodiversity: The Dasgupta Review. London: HM Treasury.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, Partha, Marglin, Stephen, and Sen, Amartya. 1972. Guidelines for Project Evaluation. New York: United Nations.Google Scholar
Daston, Lorraine. 1998. “The Nature of Nature in Early Modern Europe.” Configurations 6: 149–72.Google Scholar
Davidson, Paul, Adams, F. Gerard, and Seneca, Joseph. 1966. “The Social Value of Water Recreational Facilities Resulting from an Improvement in Water Quality: The Delaware Estuary.” In Water Research, ed. by Kneese, Allen V., 175211. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Davis, Otto A., and Whinston, Andrew. 1962. “Externalities, Welfare, and the Theory of Games.” Journal of Political Economy 70(3): 241–62.Google Scholar
Davis, Robert K. 1963a. The Value of Outdoor Recreation: An Economic Study of the Maine Woods. Dissertation, Harvard University.Google Scholar
Davis, Robert K. 1963b. “Recreation Planning as an Economic Problem.” Natural Resources Journal 3: 239–49.Google Scholar
Davis, Robert K. 1968. The Range of Choice in Water Management: A Study of Dissolved Oxygen in the Potomac Estuary. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Dawson, John A. 1957. The Demand for Irrigation Water in the Ainsworth Area of Nebraska. PhD Dissertation, University of Chicago.Google Scholar
De Haven, James C., and Hirshleifer, Jack. 1957. “Feather River Water for Southern California.” Land Economics 33: 198209.Google Scholar
Debates in the Massachusetts Constitutional Convention 1917–1918. 1919. Boston: Wright and Potter.Google Scholar
Demsetz, Harold. 1969. “Information and Efficiency: Another Viewpoint.” Journal of Law and Economics 12(1): 122.Google Scholar
Deschênes, Olivier, Greenstone, Michael, and Shapiro, Joseph S.. 2017. “Defensive Investments and the Demand for Air Quality: Evidence from the NOx Budget program.” American Economic Review 107(10): 2958–89.Google Scholar
Desmarais-Tremblay, Maxime. 2017a. “Musgrave, Samuelson, and the Crystallization of the Standard Rationale for Public Goods.” History of Political Economy 49(1): 5992.Google Scholar
Desmarais-Tremblay, Maxime. 2017b. “A Genealogy of the Concept of Merit Wants.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 24(3): 409–40.Google Scholar
Desmarais-Tremblay, Maxime. 2020. “W.H. Hutt and the Conceptualization of Consumer Sovereignty.” Oxford Economic Papers 72(4): 1050–71.Google Scholar
DesRoches, C. Tyler. 2015. The World as a Garden: A Philosophical Analysis of Natural Capital in Economics. PhD Dissertation, University of British ColumbiaGoogle Scholar
DesRoches, C. Tyler. 2018a. “On the Historical Roots of Natural Capital in the Writings of Carl Linnaeus.” Research in the History of Economic Thought and Methodology 36C: 103–17.Google Scholar
DesRoches, C. Tyler. 2018b. “What is Natural about Natural Capital during the Anthropocene?Sustainability 10. https://doi.org/10.3390/su10030806.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Desrosières, Alain. 1998. The Politics of Large Numbers: A History of Statistical Reasoning. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Desvousges, William H., Reed Johnson, F., Dunford, Richard W., Boyle, Kevin J., Hudson, Sara P., and Nicole Wilson, K.. 1993. “Measuring Natural Resource Damages with Contingent Valuation: Tests of Validity and Responsibility.” In Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment, ed. by Hausman, Jerry A., 91164. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Devons, Ely. 1961. Essays in Economics. London: Allen & Unwin.Google Scholar
Diamond, Peter A., and Hausman, Jerry A.. 1994. “Contingent Valuation: Is Some Number Better than No Number?Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(4): 4564.Google Scholar
Diamond, Peter A., Hausman, Jerry A., Leonard, Gregory K., and Denning, Mike A.. 1993. “Does Contingent Valuation Measure Preferences? Experimental Evidence.” In Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment, ed. by Hausman, Jerry A., 4190. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert, ed. 1965. Measuring Benefits of Government Investments. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1953. “Mathematical, or ‘Linear,’ Programming: A Nonmathematical Exposition.” American Economic Review 43: 797825.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1960. “Operations Research.” American Economic Review 50: 575–86.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1963. “An Economic Strategy for West Pakistan.” Asian Survey 3: 217–23.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1974. “The Technical Basis for Decision-Making.” In The Governance of Common Property Resources, ed. by Haefele, Edwin T., 525. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1978. “Forty Years of Cost-Benefit Analysis.” In Econometric Contributions to Public Policy, ed. by Stone, Richard and Peterson, William, 268–84. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1996. “Why Benefit-Cost Analysis Is Widely Disregarded and What to Do about It.” Interfaces 16: 1–6. Reprinted in Economic Theory and Public Decisions, ed. by Robert Dorfman. Cheltenham, UK: Elgar, 1997.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert. 1997. “Introduction.” In Economic Theory and Public Decisions, ed. by Robert Dorfman, xiii–xxxiii. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Dorfman, Robert, Samuelson, Paul, and Solow, Robert M.. 1958. Linear Programming and Economic Analysis. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Drèze, J. 1962. “L’utilité sociale d’une vie humaine.” Revue Française de Recherche Opérationnelle 22: 139–55.Google Scholar
Dublin, Louis, and Lotka, Alfred. 1930. The Money Value of a Man. New York: Ronald Press.Google Scholar
Dufwenberg, Martin, and Harrison, Glenn W.. 2008. “Peter Bohm: Father of Field Experiments.” Experimental Economics 11(3): 213–20.Google Scholar
Eckstein, Otto. 1957. “Investment Criteria for Economic Development and the Theory of Intertemporal Welfare Economics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 71: 5685.Google Scholar
Eckstein, Otto. 1958. Water-Resource Development: The Economics of Project Evaluation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Eckstein, Otto. 1961. “A Survey of the Theory of Public Expenditure Criteria.” In Public Finances: Needs, Sources and Utilization, ed. by Buchanan, James M., 439504. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Edwards, José M. 2010. Joyful Economists: Remarks on the History of Economics and Psychology from the Happiness Studies Perspective. PhD Dissertation, Université Paris I Panthéon-Sorbonne.Google Scholar
Ehrlich, Paul R., and Ehrlich, Anne. 1968. The Population Bomb. New York: Ballentine Books.Google Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B. Jr., and Hébert, Robert F.. 1978. “French Engineers, Welfare Economics, and Public Finance in the Nineteenth Century.” History of Political Economy 10(4): 636–68.Google Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Hébert, Robert F.. 1985. “Consumer Surplus: The First Hundred Years.” History of Political Economy 17: 419–54.Google Scholar
Ekelund, Robert B., Jr., and Hébert, Robert F.. 1999. The Secret Origins of Modern Microeconomics: Dupuit and the Engineers. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Ellis, Howard S. 1950. “The Economic Way of Thinking.” American Economic Review 40: 112.Google Scholar
Ellis, Howard S. 1953. “Is Group Choice a Part of Economics? Further Comment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 67(4): 609–13.Google Scholar
Ellis, Howard S., and Fellner, William. 1943. “External Economies and Diseconomies.” American Economic Review 33(3): 493511.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1893. Outlines of Economics. New York: Meadville Penna.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1908. Outlines of Economics, 2nd ed. With Thomas S. Adams, Max O. Lorenz, and Allyn A. Young. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1918a. “Conservation and Economic Theory.” In The Foundations of National Prosperity: Studies in the Conservation of Permanent National Resources, ed. by Ely, Richard T., Hess, Ralph H., Leith, Charles K., and Carver, Thomas Nixon, 368. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1918b. “Preface.” In The Foundations of National Prosperity: Studies in the Conservation of Permanent National Resources, ed. by Ely, Richard T., Hess, Ralph H., Leith, Charles K., and Carver, Thomas Nixon, v–vii. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T. 1938. Ground Under Our Feet: An Autobiography. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T., and Morehouse, Edward W.. 1924. Elements of Land Economics. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Ely, Richard T., and Wehrwein, George S.. 1940. Land Economics. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Emmett, Ross B. 2008. “Frank H. Knight’s Criticism of Henry George.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 67(1): 6166.Google Scholar
Enthoven, Alain. 2019. “How Systems Analysis, Cost-Effectiveness Analysis, or Benefit-Cost Analysis First Became Influential in Federal Government Program Decision-Making.” Journal of Benefit-Cost Analysis 10(2): 146–55.Google Scholar
Etner, François. 1987. Histoire du calcul économique en France. Paris: Economica.Google Scholar
Ewert, Sara E. Dant. 2001. “Evolution of an Environmentalist: Senator Frank Church and the Hells Canyon Controversy.” Montana: The Magazine of Western History (Spring): 36–51.Google Scholar
Ezekiel, Mordecai. 1937. “The Broadening Field of Agricultural Economics.” Journal of Farm Economics 19: 96101.Google Scholar
Federal Inter-Agency River Basin Committee (FIARBC), Subcommittee on Benefits and Costs. 1950. Proposed Practices for Economic Analysis of River Basin Projects. Report of the Subcommittee on Benefits and Costs. Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Federal Inter-Agency River Basin Committee (FIARBC), Subcommittee on Benefits and Costs. 1958. Proposed Practices for Economic Analysis of River Basin Projects. Report of the Subcommittee on Evaluation Standards. Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Fein, Rashi. 1958. Economics of Mental Illness. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Fenichel, Eli P., and Abbott, Joshua K.. 2014. “Natural Capital: From Metaphor to Measurement.” Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 1(1/2): 127.Google Scholar
Fernow, Bernard E. 1891. “Practicability of an American Forest Administration.” Publications of the American Economic Association 6(3): 75101.Google Scholar
Fernow, Bernard E. 1902. Economics of Forestry. New York: Thomas E. Crowell & Co.Google Scholar
Fernow, Bernard E. [1907]. 1913. A Brief History of Forestry: In Europe, the United States, and Other Countries. Toronto: University Press.Google Scholar
Finch, Adam, and van den Bergh, Jeroen. 2022. “Assessing the Authenticity of National Carbon Prices: A Comparison of 31 Countries.” Global Environmental Change 74: 102525.Google Scholar
Fischel, William A. 2006. “Footloose at Fifty: An Introduction to the Tiebout Anniversary Essays.” In The Tiebout Model at Fifty: Essays in Public Economics in Honor of Wallace Oates, ed. by Fischel, William A., 120. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.Google Scholar
Fisher, Anthony C., and Krutilla, John V.. 1974. “Valuing Long Run Ecological Consequences and lrreversibilities.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 1(2): 96108.Google Scholar
Fisher, Anthony C., and Peterson, Frederick M.. 1976. “The Environment in Economics: A Survey.” Journal of Economic Literature 14(1): 133.Google Scholar
Fisher, Anthony C., Krutilla, John V., and Cicchetti, Charles J.. 1972. “The Economics of Environmental Preservation: A Theoretical and Empirical Analysis.” American Economic Review 62(4): 605–19.Google Scholar
Fisher, Anthony C., Krutilla, John V., and Cicchetti, Charles J.. 1974. “The Economics of Environmental Preservation: Further Discussion.” American Economic Review 64(6): 1030–39.Google Scholar
Fisher, Franklin M., Griliches, Zvi, and Kaysen, Carl. 1962. “The Cost of Automobile Model Changes since 1949.” Journal of Political Economy 70(5): 433–51.Google Scholar
Fleurbaey, Marc, and Abi-Rafeh, Rossi. 2016. “The Use of Distributional Weights in Benefit–Cost Analysis: Insights from Welfare Economics.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 10(2): 286307.Google Scholar
Fleury, Jean-Baptiste. 2010. “Drawing New Lines: Economists and Other Social Scientists on Society in the 1960s.” In The Unsocial Social Science? Economics and Neighboring Disciplines since 1945, ed. by Backhouse, Roger E. and Fontaine, Philippe. History of Political Economy 42(S): 315–42. Durham: Duke University PressGoogle Scholar
Fontaine, Philippe. 2014. “Free Riding.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 36(3): 359–76.Google Scholar
Fort, D. M., Niskanen, W.A., Pascal, A.H., and Sharpe, W.F.. 1959. “Proposal for a ‘Smog Tax’.” RAND Corporation paper P-1621-RC.Google Scholar
Fourcade, Marion. 2009. “The Political Valuation of Life: A Comment on W. Kip Viscusi’s ‘The Devaluation of Life’.Regulation and Governance 3: 291–97.Google Scholar
Fourcade, Marion. 2011. “Cents and Sensibility: Economic Valuation and the Nature of ‘Nature’.American Journal of Sociology 116(6): 1721–77.Google Scholar
Fox, Karl A. 1987. “Agricultural Economics.” In New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics, ed. by Eatwell, John, Milgate, Murray, and Newman, Peter, 5562. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Franco, Marco P. Vianna. 2018. “Searching for a Scientific Paradigm in Ecological Economics: The History of Ecological Economic Thought, 1880s–1930s.” Ecological Economics 153: 195203.Google Scholar
Franco, Marco P. Vianna, and Missemer, Antoine. 2023. A History of Ecological Economic Thought. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1966. “Adjusted Benefit-Cost Ratios for Six Recent Reclamation Projects.” Journal of Farm Economics 48: 1002–12.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1967a. “Income Distribution and Planning for Public Investment.” American Economic Review 57: 494508.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1967b. “Six Federal Reclamation Projects and the Distribution of Income.” Water Resources Research 3: 319–32.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1968. “The Relevance of Benefit-Cost Analysis: A Comment on an Exchange.” Unpublished manuscript, June. AMP 96.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1969a. “Income Redistribution and Social Choice: A Pragmatic Approach.” Public Choice 7: 321.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III. 1969b. “Project Design and Evaluation with Multiple Objectives.” In The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPB System. A Compendium of papers submitted to the Subcommittee on Economy in Government of the Joint Economic Committee. Vol. 1, 565–78. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III, and Haveman, Robert H.. 1970. “Benefit-Cost Analysis and Multiple Objectives: Current Issues in Water Resources Planning.” Water Resources Research 6: 1533–39.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick, III, and Haveman, Robert H.. 1971. “Water Pollution Control, River Basin Authorities and Economic Incentives: Some Current Policy Issues.” Public Policy 19: 5374.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick III, and Haveman, Robert H.. 1972. “Residuals Changes for Pollution Control: A Policy Evaluation.” Science 177: 322–29.Google Scholar
Freeman, A. Myrick III, and Norris, Jeffrey C.. 1988. “Quasi-Optimal Pricing for Cost Recovery in Multiple Purpose Water Resource Projects.” In Environmental Resources and Applied Welfare Economics: Essays in Honor of John V. Krutilla, ed. by Kerry Smith, V., 119–34. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. “The Methodology of Positive Economics.” In Essays in Positive Economics, ed. by Milton Friedman, 343. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1969. “The Optimum Quantity of Money.” In The Optimum Quantity of Money and Other Essays, 1–50. Chicago: Aldine.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Savage, L.J.. 1948. “The Utility Analysis of Choices Involving Risk.” Journal of Political Economy 56(4): 270304.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton, and Savage, L.J.. 1952. “The Expected Utility Hypothesis and the Measurability of Utility.” Journal of Political Economy 60(6): 463–74.Google Scholar
Frisch, Ragnar. 1946. “Repercussion Studies at Oslo.” American Economic Review 38(3): 367–72.Google Scholar
Fromm, Gary. 1965. “Civil Aviation Expenditures.” In Measuring Benefits of Government Investments, ed. by Dorfman, Robert, 172216. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Fromm, Gary. 1968. “Comments.” In Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis, ed. by Chase, Samuel B., Jr., 166–76. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Furner, Mary O. 1975. Advocacy and Objectivity: A Crises in the Professionalization of American Social Science, 1865–1905. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky.Google Scholar
Furner, Mary O., and Supple, Barry, eds. 1990. The State and Economic Knowledge. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Gaffney, Mason. 1957. “Concepts of Financial Maturity of Timber and Other Assets.” Agricultural Economics Information Series paper no. 62, Raleigh, NC.Google Scholar
Gaffney, Mason. 1961. “Diseconomies Inherent in Western Water Laws: A California Case Study.” In Water and Range Resources and Economic Development of the West, Proceedings of the Western Agricultural Resource Council. www.masongaffney.org/publications/H3-DiseconomiesInherentinWesternWaterLaws21.CV.CV.pdf.Google Scholar
Gaffney, Mason. 2008. “Keeping Land in Capital Theory: Ricardo, Faustmann, Wicksell, and George.” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 67(1): 119–41.Google Scholar
Georgescu-Roegen, Nicholas. 1971. The Entropy Law and the Economic Process. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2003. Modeling Rational Agents: From Interwar Economics to Early Modern Game Theory. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2011. “When Low is No Good: Predatory Pricing and US Antitrust Law (1950–1980).” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 18(5): 777806.Google Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2017. “The (Rail)Road to Lochner: Reproduction Cost and the Gilded Age Controversy over Rate Regulation.” History of Political Economy 49(1): 3158.Google Scholar
Giocoli, Nicola. 2018. “‘Value Is Not a Fact’: Reproduction Cost and the Transition from Classical to Neoclassical Regulation in Gilded Age America.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 40(4): 445–70.Google Scholar
Glover, W.H. 1952. Farm and College. Madison: The University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Goldstein, J.R. 1961. “RAND: The History, Operations, and Goals of a Nonprofit Corporation.” Mimeo. Accessed from www.rand.org/content/dam/rand/pubs/papers/2008/P2236-1.pdf.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd D. 1981. “The Truman Administration: Toward a National Energy Policy.” In Energy Policy in Perspective: Today’s Problems, Yesterday’s Solutions, ed. by Goodwin, Craufurd D., 162. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd D. 1983. “The Value Authority Idea – The Fading of a National Vision.” In TVA: Fifty Years of Grass-Roots Democracy, ed. by Hargrove, Erwin C. and Conkin, Paul K., 263–96. Urbana: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Goodwin, Craufurd D. 2008. “Ecologist Meets Economics: Aldo Leopold, 1887–1948.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 30(4): 429–52.Google Scholar
Gordon, H. Scott. 1954. “The Economic Theory of a Common-Property Resource: The Fishery.” Journal of Political Economy 62(2): 124–42.Google Scholar
Gordon, Irene M., and Knetsch, Jack L.. 1979. “Consumer’s Surplus Measures and the Evaluation of Resources.” Land Economics 55(1): 110.Google Scholar
Goulder, Lawrence H., and Schein, Andrew R.. 2013. “Carbon Taxes Versus Cap and Trade: A Critical Review.” Climate Change Economics 4(3): 13500103.Google Scholar
Graves, Gregory. 1995. Pursuing Excellence in Water Planning and Policy Analysis: A History of the Institute for Water Resources. Report prepared for the US Army Corps of Engineers, Institute for Water Resources.Google Scholar
Gray, L.C. 1913. “The Economic Possibilities of Conservation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 27(3): 497519.Google Scholar
Gray, L.C. 1914. “Rent Under the Assumption of Exhaustibility.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 28: 466–89.Google Scholar
Gray, L.C., and Regan, Mark. 1940. “Needed Points of Development and Reorientation in Land Economic Theory.” Journal of Farm Economics 22(1): 3446.Google Scholar
Gray, L.C., Stewart, Charles L., Turner, Howard A., Sanders, J.T., and Spillman, W.J.. 1924. “Farm Ownership and Tenancy.” In Yearbook of the Department of Agriculture, 1923, 507600. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Greenberg, Kyle, Greenstone, Michael, Ryan, Stephen P., and Yankovich, Michael. 2022. “The Heterogeneous Value of a Statistical Life: Evidence from US Army Reenlistment Decisions.” NBER Working Paper 29104.Google Scholar
Greenstone, Michael, Kopits, Elizabeth, and Wolverton, Ann. 2013. “Developing a Social Cost of Carbon for US Regulatory Analysis: A Methodology and Interpretation.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 7(1): 2346.Google Scholar
Griliches, Zvi. 1961. “Hedonic Price Indexes for Automobiles: An Econometric Analysis of Quality Change.” In Price Statistics of the Federal Government, prepared by the Price Statistics Review Committee of the National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Guala, Franceso. 2005. The Methodology of Experimental Economics. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Guala, Franceso. 2007. “How to Do Things with Experimental Economics.” In Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics, ed. by MacKenzie, Donald, Muniesa, Fabian, and Siu, Lucia, 128–62. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
H.M. Treasury. 2003. The Green Book: Appraisal and Evaluation in Central Government. www.hm-treasury.gov.uk/d/green_book_complete.pdf.Google Scholar
Haab, Timothy C., Interis, Matthew G., Petrolia, Danield, and Whitehead, John C.. 2013. “From Hopeless to Curious? Thoughts on Hausman’s ‘Dubious to Hopeless’ Critique of Contingent Valuation.” Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy 35(4): 593612.Google Scholar
Hammack, Judd, and Brown, Gardner M.. 1974. Waterfowl and Wetlands: Toward Bioeconomic Analysis. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Hammitt, James K., and Treich, Nicolas. 2007. “Statistical vs. Identified Lives in Benefit-Cost Analysis.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 35(1): 4565.Google Scholar
Hammond, Richard J. 1960. Benefit-Cost Analysis and Water Pollution Control. Food Research Institute, Stanford University.Google Scholar
Hammond, Richard J. 1966. “Convention and Limitation in Benefit-Cost Analysis.” Natural Resources Journal 6 (April): 195222.Google Scholar
Hampson, Chris. 2010. “Warren County and Environmental Justice: A Community Fighting Back.” Senior Thesis, University of North Carolina at Asheville.Google Scholar
Hands, D. Wade, and Mirowski, Philip. 1998. “Harold Hotelling and the Neoclassical Dream.” In Economics and Methodology: Crossing Boundaries, ed. by Backhouse, Roger. E., Hausman, Daniel M., Mäki, Uskali, and Salanti, Andrea, 322–97. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W. Michael. Undated. “Economic Valuation.” Mimeo. Berkeley: University of California.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W. Michael. 1991. “Willingness-to-Pay vs. Willingness-to-Accept: How Much Can They Differ?American Economic Review 81(3): 635–47.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W. Michael. 1992. “Preface.” In Pricing the European Environment, ed. by Navrud, Ståle, 935. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W. Michael. 1994. “Valuing the Environment through Contingent Valuation.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(4): 1943.Google Scholar
Hanemann, W. Michael. 2006. “The Economic Conception of Water.” In Water Crisis: Myth or Reality? ed. by Rogers, Peter P., Llamas, M. Ramón, and Martínez-Cortina, Louis, 6192. London: Taylor & Francis.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. 1954. “Monopoly and Resource Allocation.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 44(2): 7787.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. [1955] 1974. “The Taxation of Mineral Industries.” In Taxation and Welfare, 208–17. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. 1959a. “Using the Resources at Hand More Effectively.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 49(2): 134–46.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. 1959b. “The Corporation Income Tax: An Empirical Appraisal.” In Tax Revision Compendium, Vol. I, submitted to the Committee on Ways and Means. 231–50. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. [1961] 1974. “The Tax Treatment of Oil Exploration.” Paper presented at the Second Energy Institute. In Taxation and Welfare, ed. by Arnold C. Harberger, 218–26. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. 1964a. “The Measurement of Waste.” American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 54(3): 5876.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. [1964b] 1974. “Taxation, Resource Allocation, and Welfare.” In Taxation and Welfare, ed. by Arnold C. Harberger, 2562. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Harberger, Arnold C. 1971. “Three Basic Postulates for Applied Welfare Economics: An Interpretive Essay.” Journal of Economic Literature 9(3): 785–97.Google Scholar
Hardin, Garrett. 1968. “The Tragedy of the Commons.” Science 162: 1243–48.Google Scholar
Harrod, R.F. 1938. “Scope and Method in Economics.” The Economic Journal 48: 383412.Google Scholar
Harvey, Mark W.T. 1994. A Symbol of Wilderness: Echo Park and the American Conservation Movement. Albuquerque: University of New Mexico Press.Google Scholar
Hausman, Jerry A., ed. 1993. Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Haveman, Robert H. 1965. Water Resources Investment and the Public Interest. Nashville: Vanderbilt University Press.Google Scholar
Haveman, Robert H. 1966. “Comment” [on Weisbrod 1966]. In Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis, ed. by Chase, Samuel B., Jr., 209–13. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Haveman, Robert H. 1967. “Benefit-Cost Analysis: Its Relevance to Public Investment Decisions: Comment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 81: 695–99.Google Scholar
Haveman, Robert H. 1973. “Efficiency and Equity in Natural Resource and Environmental Policy.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 55: 868–78.Google Scholar
Hawley, Ellis W. 1990. “Economic Inquiry and the State in New Era America: Antistatist Corporatism and Positive Statism in Uneasy Coexistence.” In The State and Economic Knowledge, ed. Furner, Mary O. and Supple, Barry, 287324. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Hays, Samuel P. 1959. Conservation and the Gospel of Efficiency: The Progressive Conservation Movement, 1890–1920. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hays, Samuel P. 1982. “From Conservation to Environment: Environmental Politics in the United States since World War Two.” Environmental Review 6(2): 1441.Google Scholar
Hays, Samuel P. 1987. Beauty, Health, and Permanence: Environmental Politics in the United States, 1955–1985. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Heinzerling, Lisa. 2000. “The Rights of Statistical People.” Harvard Environmental Law Review 24: 189207.Google Scholar
Henry, John F. 1995. John Bates Clark: The Making of a Neoclassical Economist. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Heukelom, Floris. 2012. “Three Explanations for the Kahneman-Tversky Programme of the 1970s.” The European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 19(5): 797828.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. 1939. “Foundations of Welfare Economics.” Economic Journal 49: 696712.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. 1941. “The Rehabilitation of Consumers’ Surplus.” Review of Economic Studies 8(2): 108–16.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. 1943. “The Four Consumer’s Surpluses.” Review of Economic Studies 11(1): 3141.Google Scholar
Hicks, J.R. 1946. Value and Capital, 2nd ed. Oxford: Clarendon Press.Google Scholar
Hines, Lawrence G. 1958. “Measurement of Recreation Benefits: A Reply.” Land Economics 34(4): 365–67.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack. 1950. “Remarks on Bombing Systems Analysis.” Memorandum to C.J. Hitch, 15 June. RA D-893-PR.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack. 1970. Investment, Interest and Capital. Englewood Cliffs: Prentice-Hall.Google Scholar
Hirshleifer, Jack, De Haven, James C., and Milliman, Jerome W.. 1960. Water Supply: Economics, Technology, and Policy. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Hitch, Charles. 1953. “Sub-Optimization in Operations Problems.” Journal of the Operations Research Society of America 1: 8799.Google Scholar
Hitch, Charles. 1955. “An Appreciation of Systems Analysis.” Journal of the Operations Research Society of America 3: 466–81.Google Scholar
Hitch, Charles J., and McKean, Roland N.. 1960. Economics of Defense in the Nuclear Age. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Hood, Katherine. 2017. “The Science of Value: Economic Expertise and the Valuation of Human Life in US Federal Regulatory Agencies.” Social Studies of Science 47(4): 441–65.Google Scholar
Hope, Chris. 2006. “The Marginal Impact of CO2 from PAGE 2002: An Integrated Assessment Model Incorporating the IPCC’s Five Reasons for Concern.” Integrated Assessment Journal 6(1): 1956.Google Scholar
Hope, Chris, Anderson, John, and Wenman, Paul. 1993. “Policy Analysis of the Greenhouse Effect: An Application of the PAGE Model.” Energy Policy 21(3): 327–38.Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1931. “The Economics of Exhaustible Resources.” Journal of Political Economy 39(2): 137–75.Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1932. “Edgeworth’s Taxation Paradox and the Nature of Demand and Supply Functions.” Journal of Political Economy 40(5): 577616.Google Scholar
Hotelling, Harold. 1938. “The General Welfare in Relation to Problems of Taxation and of Railway and Utility Rates.” Econometrica 6(3): 242–69.Google Scholar
Hounshell, David. 1997. “The Cold War, RAND, and the Generation of Knowledge, 1946–1962.” Historical Studies in the Physical and Biological Sciences 27: 237–67.Google Scholar
Hufschmidt, Maynard A. 1967. “The Harvard Water Program: A Summing Up.” In Water Research, ed. by Kneese, Allen V. and Smith, Stephen C., 441–55. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Hufschmidt, Maynard A. 2000. “Benefit-Cost Analysis: 1933–1985.” Water Resources Updates 116: 4249.Google Scholar
Jardini, David R. 1996. Out of the Blue Yonder: The Rand Corporation’s Diversification into Social Welfare Research, 1946–1968. Dissertation, Carnegie-Mellon University.Google Scholar
Jarrett, Henry, ed. 1966a. Environmental Quality in a Growing Economy. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Jarrett, Henry. 1966b. “Editor’s Introduction.” In Environmental Quality in a Growing Economy, ed. by Jarrett, Henry, vii–xv. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Johnson, Edwin L. 1967. “A Study in the Economics of Water Quality Management.” Water Resources Research 3(2): 291305.Google Scholar
Johnson, Marianne. 2015. “Public Goods, Market Failure, and Voluntary Exchange.” In Market Failure in Context, ed. by Marciano, Alain and Medema, Steven G.. History of Political Economy 47(S): 174–98. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Johnston, Robert J., Boyle, Kevin J., Wiktor Adamowicz, Jeff Bennett, et al. 2017. “Contemporary Guidance for Stated Preference Studies.” Journal of the Association of Environmental and Resource Economists 4(2): 319405.Google Scholar
Joint Committee on Conservation. 1909. Report of the National Conservation Commission. 3 vols. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Jones-Lee, M.W. 1976. The Value of Life: An Economic Analysis. Chicago: The University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Jones-Lee, M.W, ed. 1982. The Value of Life and Safety. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Jonsson, Fredrik Albritton. 2013. Enlightenment’s Frontier: The Scottish Highlands and the Origins of Environmentalism. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Journal of Farm Economics. 1966. “News Notes.” 48(1): 177.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel. 1986. “Comments by Professor Daniel Kahneman.” In Valuing Environmental Goods: An Assessment of the Contingent Valuation Method, ed. by Cummings, Ronald G., Brookshire, David S., and Schulze, William D., 185–94. Totowa, NJ: Rowman & Allanheld.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Knetsch, Jack. 1992. “Valuing Public Goods: The Purchase of Moral Satisfaction.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22: 5770.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos. 1979. “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk.” Econometrica 47(2): 263–91.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack, and Thaler, Richard H.. 1990. “Experimental Tests of the Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem.” Journal of Political Economy 98(6): 1325–48.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, Knetsch, Jack, and Thaler, Richard H.. 1991. “Anomalies: The Endowment Effect, Loss Aversion, and Status Quo Bias.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5(1): 193206.Google Scholar
Kaldor, N. 1939. “Welfare Propositions of Economics and Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility.” The Economic Journal 49: 549–52.Google Scholar
Kalter, Robert J., and Stevens, Thomas H.. 1971. “Resource Investments, Impact Distribution, and Evaluation Concepts.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 53: 206215.Google Scholar
Kalter, Robert J., Lord, W.B., Allee, D.J., Castle, E.N., et al. 1969. Criteria for Federal Evaluation of Resource Investments. Water Resource and Marine Science Center, Cornell University.Google Scholar
Kaplan, Fred. 1983. The Wizards of Armageddon. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Bruce E. 2017. “The Origins and Theoretical Foundation of Original Institutional Economics Reconsidered.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 39(3): 293322.Google Scholar
Kaufman, Gordon D. 1972. “A Problem for Theology: The Concept of Nature.” Harvard Theological Review 65(3): 337–66.Google Scholar
Kern, William S. 2003. “McCulloch, Scrope, and Hodgskin: Nineteenth-Century Versions of Julian Simon.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 25(3): 289301.Google Scholar
Kingsland, Sharon E. 1994. “Economics and Evolution: Alfred James Lotka and the Economy of Nature.” In Natural Images in Economic Thought: Markets Read in Tooth and Claw, ed. by Mirowski, Philip, 231–46. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kirkendall, Richard S. 1963. “L.C. Gray and the Supply of Agricultural Land.” Agricultural History 37(4): 206–14.Google Scholar
Klarman, Herbert E. 1965. The Economics of Health. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Klein, Judy L., and Morgan, Mary S.. 2001. The Age of Economic Measurement. Supplement to vol. 33 of History of Political Economy. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1956. An Industry Study Approach to the Problem of Exclusive Dealing. Dissertation, Indiana University.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1960. “Normative Problems in the Evaluation of Water-Resources Development Projects.” Southwestern Social Sciences Quarterly 40(4): 301–13.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1962. Water Pollution – Economic Aspects and Research Needs. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1964. The Economics of Regional Water Quality Management. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1968. “The ‘Problem Shed’ as a Unit for Environmental Control.” Archives of Environmental Health 16: 124–27.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1969. “Statement of Allen V. Kneese, Director, The Quality of the Environment Program for Resources for the Future, Inc.” In Economic Analysis and the Efficiency of Government: Hearings before the Subcommittee on Efficiency of Government of the Joint Economic Committee, 91st Cong., 342–9.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1971a. “Background for the Economic Analysis of Environmental Pollution.” Swedish Journal of Economics 73(1): 124.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1971b. “Environmental Pollution: Economics and Policy.” American Economic Review 61(2): 153–66.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V. 1988. “Three Decades of Water Resources Research: A Personal Perspective.” In Environmental Resources and Applied Welfare Economics: Essays in Honor of John V. Krutilla, ed. by Kerry Smith, V., 4555. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V., and Bower, Blair T.. 1968. Managing Water Quality: Economics, Technology, Institutions. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V., and Mäler, Karl-Göran. 1973. “Bribes and Charges in Pollution Control: An Aspect of the Coase Controversy.” Natural Resources Journal 13: 705–15.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V., and Nobe, Kenneth C.. 1962. “The Role of Economic Evaluation in Planning for Water Resource Development.” Natural Resources Journal 2: 445–82.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V., and Schultze, Charles L.. 1975. Pollution, Prices, and Public Policy. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Kneese, Allen V., Ayres, Robert U., and d’Arge, Ralph C.. 1970. Economics and the Environment: A Materials Balance Approach. Baltimore: Johnsons Hopkins University Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L. 1963. “Outdoor Recreation Demands and Benefits.” Land Economics, November: 387–396.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L. 1964. “Economics of Including Recreation as a Purpose of Eastern Water Projects.” Journal of Farm Economics 46(5): 1148–57.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L. 1989. “The Endowment Effect and Evidence of Nonreversible Indifference Curves.” American Economic Review 79(5): 1277–84.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L. 2003. Personal telephone conversation. May 15th.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L., and Davis, Robert K.. 1966. “Comparisons of Methods for Recreation Evaluation.” In Water Research, ed. by Kneese, Allen V. and Smith, Stephen C., 125–42. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L., and Sinden, J.A.. 1984. “Willingness to Pay and Compensation Demanded: Experimental Evidence of an Unexpected Disparity in Measures of Value.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 99(3): 507–21.Google Scholar
Knetsch, Jack L., Haveman, Robert H., Howe, Charles W., Krutilla, John V., and Brewer, Michael F.. 1969. Federal Natural Resources Development: Basic Issues in Benefit and Cost Measurement. Natural Resources Policy Center. Washington, DC: George Washington University.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1924. “Some Fallacies in the Interpretation of Social Cost.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 38(4): 582606.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1944. “Realism and Relevance in the Theory of Demand.” Journal of Political Economy 52(4): 289318.Google Scholar
Knight, Frank H. 1953. “Is Group Choice a Part of Economics? Comment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 67(4): 605–9.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V. 1955. “Criteria for Evaluating Regional Development Programs.” American Economic Review Papers & Proceedings 45(2): 120–32.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V. 1962. “Welfare Aspects of Benefit-Cost Analysis.” Journal of Political Economy 69(3): 226–35.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V. 1967a. “Conservation Reconsidered.” American Economic Review 57(4): 777–86.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V. 1967b. “Some Environmental Effects of Economic Development.” Daedalus 96(4): 1058–70.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V. 1981. “Reflections of an Applied Welfare Economist.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 8: 110.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V., and Cicchetti, Charles J.. 1972. “Evaluating Benefits of Environmental Resources with Special Application to the Hells Canyon.” Natural Resource Journal 12: 128.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V., and Eckstein, Otto. 1958. Multiple Purpose River Development: Studies in Economic Analysis. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Krutilla, John V., and Fisher, Anthony C.. 1975. The Economics of Natural Environments: Studies in the Valuation of Commodity and Amenity Resources. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Kula, E. 1998. History of Environmental Economic Thought. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Kumekawa, Ian. 2017. The First Serious Optimist: A.C. Pigou and the Birth of Welfare Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Kuznets, Simon. 1948. “On the Valuation of Social Income: Reflections on Professor Hicks’ Article.” Economica 15 (February, May): 116, 116–31.Google Scholar
Lagueux, Maurice. 2010. “The Residual Character of Externalities.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 17(4): 957–73.Google Scholar
Lancaster, Kelvin J. 1966. “A New Approach to Consumer Theory.” Journal of Political Economy 74(2): 132–57.Google Scholar
Landsberg, Hans H. 1964. Natural Resources for US Growth: A Look Ahead to the Year 2000. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Landsberg, Hans H. 1987. “Resources for Freedom – In Retrospect.” In Resources for Freedom: Summary of Volume I of a Report to the President, 8394. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Landsberg, Hans H., Fischman, Leonard L., and Fisher, Joseph L.. 1963. Resources in America’s Future: Patterns of Requirements and Availabilities, 1960–2000. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Landsberg, Hans H., and Schurr, Sam H.. 1968. Energy in the United States: Sources, Uses, and Policy Issues. New York: Random House for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Lane, Richard. 2014. The Nature of Growth: The Postwar History of the Economy, Energy, and the Environment. Dissertation, University of Sussex.Google Scholar
Lave, Lester B. 1968. “Safety in Transportation: The Role of Government.” Law and Contemporary Problems 33(3): 512–35.Google Scholar
Leonard, Bryan, and Libecap, Gary D.. 2019. “Collective Action by Contract: Prior Appropriation and the Development of Irrigation in the Western United States.” Journal of Law and Economics 62(1): 67115.Google Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 1991. “War as a ‘Simple Economic Problem:’ The Rise of an Economics of Defense.” In Economics and National Security, ed. by Goodwin, Craufurd D.. History of Political Economy 23(S): 261–83. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Leonard, Robert J. 2010. Von Neumann, Morgenstern, and the Creation of Game Theory: From Chess to Social Science, 1900–1960. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Leonard, Robert. 2019. “E.F. Schumacher and the Making of ‘Buddhist Economics,’ 1950–1973.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 41(2): 159–86.Google Scholar
Leonard, Thomas C. 2016. Illiberal Reformers. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Leopold, Aldo. [1933] 1991. “The Conservation Ethic.” Reprinted in The River of the Mother of God and Other Essays, ed. by Flader, Susan L. and Callicott, J. Baird, 181–92. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Leopold, Aldo. 1934. “Conservation Economics.” Journal of Forestry 32(5): 537–44.Google Scholar
Leopold, Aldo. 1939. “A Biotic View of Land.” Journal of Forestry 37(9): 727–30.Google Scholar
Leopold, Aldo. [1949] 1987. A Sand County Almanac and Sketches Here and There. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Levy, David M. 1999. Interview with Arnold Harberger. www.minneapolisfed.org/pubs/region/99-03/harberger.cfm. Accessed July 17, 2007.Google Scholar
Lin, Qi Feng. 2014. “Aldo Leopold’s Unrealized Proposals to Rethink Economics.” Ecological Economics 108: 104–14.Google Scholar
Linnerooth, Joanne. 1982. “Murdering Statistical Lives…?” In The Value of Life and Safety, ed. by Jones-Lee, M.W., 229–61. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
List, John A. 2003. “Does Market Experience Eliminate Market Anomalies?Quarterly Journal of Economics 118(1): 4171.Google Scholar
Little, I.M.D. 1950. A Critique of Welfare Economics. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Loehman, Edna, and Whinston, Andrew. 1974. “An Axiomatic Approach to Cost Allocation for Public Investment.” Public Finance Quarterly 2(2): 236–50.Google Scholar
Lynd, Robert S. 1939. Knowledge for What? The Place for Social Science in American Culture. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Lyons, Barrow. 1955. Tomorrow’s Birthright: A Political and Economic Interpretation of our Natural Resources. New York: Funk and Wagnalls.Google Scholar
Maas, Harro. 2021. “Politicizing the Environment: (In)direct Inference, Rationality, and the Credibility of the Contingent Valuation Method.” In Exploring the History of Statistical Inference in Economics, ed. by Biddle, Jeff and Boumans, Marcel. History of Political Economy 53(S): 293323. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Maas, Harro, and Morgan, Mary S., eds. 2012. Observing the Economy. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Maas, Harro, and Svorenčík, Andrej. 2017. “Fraught with Controversy: Organizing Expertise on Contingent Valuation.” History of Political Economy 49(2): 315–45.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur. 1951. Muddy Waters: The Army Engineers and the Nation’s Rivers. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur. 1966. “Benefit-Cost Analysis: Its Relevance to Public Investment Decisions.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 80: 208–26.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur. 1967. “Reply.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 81: 700–2.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur. 1970. “Public Investment Planning in the United States: Analysis and Critique.” Public Policy 18: 211–43.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur. 1989. “Interview with Professor Arthur Maass.” Water Resources People and Issues. www.usace.army.mil/inet/usace-docs/eng-pamphlets/ep870-1-35/basic.pdf.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur, and Major, David C.. 1970. “Economics in Regional Water Research and Policy: Comment.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 52: 144–45.Google Scholar
Maass, Arthur, Hufschmidt, Maynard M., Dorfman, Robert, Thomas, Harold A., Jr., Marglin, Stephen A., and Fair, Gordon Maskew. 1962. Design of Water-Resource Systems: New Techniques for Relating Economic Objectives, Engineering Analysis, and Governmental Planning. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
MacDonald, Dwight. 1956. The Ford Foundation: The Men and the Millions. New York: Reynal.Google Scholar
MacKenzie, Donald, Muniesa, Fabian, and Siu, Lucia, eds. 2007. Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Major, David C. 1969. “Benefit-Cost Ratios for Projects in Multiple Objective Investment Programs.” Water Resources Research 5(6): 1174–78.Google Scholar
Major, David C. 1975. “Appraising Proposed Federal Standards for Water Resources Investment.” Science 187: 7980.Google Scholar
Major, David C. 1977. Multiobjective Water Resource Planning. Washington, DC: American Geophysical Union.Google Scholar
Marciano, Alain. 2013. “Why Market Failures are Not a Problem: James Buchanan on Market Imperfections, Voluntary Cooperation, and Externalities.” History of Political Economy 45(2): 223–54.Google Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. 1963a. “The Social Rate of Discount and the Optimal Rate of Investment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 77: 95111.Google Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. 1963b. “The Opportunity Costs of Public Investment.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 77: 274–89.Google Scholar
Marglin, Stephen A. 1967. Public Investment Criteria: Benefit-Cost Analysis for Planned Economic Growth. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Margolis, Julius. 1969. “Secondary Benefits, External Economies, and Justification of the Public Interest.” In The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPB System. A Compendium of papers submitted to the Subcommittee on Economy in Government of the Joint Economic Committee. Vol. 1, 284–91. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Marschak, Jacob. 1950. “Rational Behavior, Uncertainty Prospects, and Measurable Utility.” Econometrica 18: 111–41.Google Scholar
Marshall, Alfred. [1920] 1946. The Principles of Economics, 8th ed. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
McCauley, Douglas J. 2006. “Selling Out on Nature.” Nature 443(7): 2728.Google Scholar
McCloskey, Deirdre. 1983. “The Rhetoric of Economics.” Journal of Economic Literature 21(2): 481517.Google Scholar
McDean, Harry C. 1983. “Professionalism, Policy, and Farm Economists in the early Bureau of Agricultural Economics.” Agricultural History 57: 6482.Google Scholar
McDonald, John F. 2013. “Pigou, Knight, Diminishing Returns, and Optimal Pigouvian Congestion Tolls.” Journal of the History of Economics Thought 35(3): 353–72.Google Scholar
McFadden, Daniel. 1999. “Rationality for Economists?Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19: 73105.Google Scholar
McFadden, Daniel. 2013. “The New Science of Pleasure: Consumer Choice Behavior and the Measurement of Well-Being.” In Handbook of Choice Modelling, ed. by Hess, S. and Daly, A.J., 748. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
McFadden, Daniel, and Leonard, Gregory K.. 1993. “Issues in the Contingent Valuation of Environmental Goods.” In Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment, ed. by Jerry, A. Hausman, 165216. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
McGee, W.J. 1909. “Water Resources.” Report of the National Conservation Commission, vol. I, 3949. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
McKean, Roland N. 1958. Efficiency in Government through Systems Analysis: With Emphasis on Water Resources Development. New York: John Wiley & Sons.Google Scholar
McKean, Roland N. 1963. “Cost-Benefit Analysis and British Defence Expenditure.” Scottish Journal of Political Economy 10: 1735.Google Scholar
Meade, J.E. 1952. “External Economies and Diseconomies in a Competitive Situation.” Economic Journal 62: 5467.Google Scholar
Meadows, Donella H., Meadows, Dennis L., Randers, Jorgen, and Behrens, William W.. 1972. The Limits to Growth: A Report for the Club of Rome’s Project on the Predicament of Mankind. New York: Universe Books.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2009. The Hesitant Hand: Taming Self-Interest in the History of Economic Ideas. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2014a. “The Curious Treatment of the Coase Theorem in the Environmental Economics Literature, 1960–1979.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 8(1): 3957.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2014b. “1966 and All That: Codification, Consolidation, Creep, and Controversy in the Early History of the Coase Theorem.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 36(3): 271303.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2020a. “‘Exceptional and Unimportant’? Externalities, Competitive Equilibrium, and the Myth of a Pigovian Tradition.” History of Political Economy 52(1): 135–70.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2020b. “The Coase Theorem at Sixty.” Journal of Economic Literature 58(4): 1045–128.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2020c. “Embracing at Arm’s Length: Ronald Coase’s Uneasy Relationship with the Chicago School.” Oxford Economic Papers 72(4): 1072–90.Google Scholar
Medema, Steven G. 2021. “Taking Root: The Early Reception of Coase’s Argument.” Mimeo. Durham, NC: Duke University.Google Scholar
Meine, Curt. 2010. Aldo Leopold: His Life and Work. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Merewitz, Leonard. 1966. “Recreational Benefits of Water Resource Development.” Water Resources Research 2: 625–40.Google Scholar
Merewitz, Leonard. 1968. “Estimation of Recreational Benefits at Selected Water Development Sites in California.” Annals of Regional Science 2: 249–73.Google Scholar
Meyer, John M. 1997. “Gifford Pinchot, John Muir, and the Boundaries of Politics in American Thought.” Polity 30(2): 267–84.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. [1848] 1987. Principles of Political Economy with some of Their Applications to Social Philosophy, ed. by Ashley, William. Fairfield: Augustus M. Kelley.Google Scholar
Mill, John Stuart. 1874. Nature, the Utility of Religion, and Theism. London: Longmans, Green, Reader, and Dyer.Google Scholar
Millennium Ecosystem Assessment. 2005. Ecosystems and Human Well-Being: Synthesis. Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
Miller, Char. 1992. “The Greening of Gifford Pinchot.” Environmental History Review 16(3): 120.Google Scholar
Miller, Char. 2001. Gifford Pinchot and the Making of Modern Environmentalism. Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
Milliman, Jerome W. 1956. “Commonality, the Price System, and Use of Water Supplies.” Southern Economic Journal 22(4): 426–37.Google Scholar
Mills, Edwin S. 1966. “Economic Incentives in Air Pollution Control.” In The Economics of Air Pollution, ed. by Wolozin, Harold, 4050. New York: W.W. Norton & Co.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip. 2002. Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Mirowski, Philip, and Wade Hands, D.. 1998. “A Paradox of Budgets: The Postwar Stabilization of American Neoclassical Demand Theory.” In From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism, edited by Morgan, Mary S. and Rutherford, Malcolm. History of Political Economy 30(S): 260–92. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Mishan, E.J. 1971. “Evaluation of Life and Limb: A Theoretical Approach.” Journal of Political Economy 79(4): 687705.Google Scholar
Missemer, Antoine. 2017. “Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen and Degrowth.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 24(3): 493506.Google Scholar
Missemer, Antoine. 2018. “Natural Capital as an Economic Concept: History and Contemporary Issues.” Ecological Economics 143: 9096.Google Scholar
Missemer, Antoine, Gaspard, Marion, and Ferreira da Cunha, Roberto. 2022. “From Depreciation to Exhaustible Resources: On Harold Hotelling’s First Steps in Economics.” History of Political Economy 54(1): 109–35.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Robert Cameron, and Carson, Richard T.. 1989. Using Surveys to Value Public Goods: The Contingent Valuation Method. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Mitchell, Wesley C., Kuznets, Simon, and Reid, Margaret G.. 1944. Prices and the Cost of Living in Wartime – An Appraisal of the Bureau of Labor Statistics Index of the Cost of Living in 1941–1944. Report of the President’s Committee on the Cost of Living. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Mohai, Paul, Pellow, David, and Timmons Roberts, J.. 2009. “Environmental Justice.” Annual Review of Environment and Resources 34: 405–30.Google Scholar
Mohring, Herbert, and Harwitz, Mitchell. 1962. Highway Benefits: An Analytical Framework. Evanston: Northwestern University Press.Google Scholar
Montgomery, W. David. 1972. “Markets in Licenses and Efficient Pollution Control Programs.” Journal of Economic Theory 5: 395418.Google Scholar
Moore, Jamie, and Moore, Dorothy. 1989. The Army Corps of Engineers and the Evolution of Federal Flood Plain Management Policy. Boulder: Institute of Behavioral Sciences.Google Scholar
Morey, Edward R. 1984. “Confuser Surplus.” American Economic Review 74(1): 163–73.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary S. 1990. The History of Econometric Ideas. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Morgan, Mary S., and Rutherford, Malcolm, eds. 1998. From Interwar Pluralism to Postwar Neoclassicism. History of Political Economy 30(S). Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Moscati, Ivan. 2007. “Early Experiments in Consumer Demand Theory: 1930–1970.” History of Political Economy 39(3): 359401.Google Scholar
Moulin, Hervé. 2002. “Axiomatic Cost and Surplus Sharing.” In Handbook of Social Choice and Welfare, Vol. 1, ed. by Arrow, Kenneth J., Sen, Amartya K., and Suzumura, Kotaro, 289357. Amsterdam: North-Holland.Google Scholar
Muir, John. [1875] 1980. “Wild Wool.” In Wilderness Essays, ed. by Buske, Frank, 227–42. Salt Lake City: Peregrine Smith.Google Scholar
Muir, John. [1901] 1980. “The Yellowstone National Park.” In Wilderness Essays, ed. by Buske, Frank, 178219. Salt Lake City: Peregrine Smith.Google Scholar
Muir, John. [1912] 1989. The Yosemite. San Francisco: Sierra Club Books.Google Scholar
Muller, Nicholas Z., Mendelsohn, Robert, and Nordhaus, William. 2011. “Environmental Accounting for Pollution in the United States Economy.” American Economic Review 101(5): 1649–75.Google Scholar
Muniesa, Fabian, and Callon, Michel. 2007. “Economic Experiments and the Construction of Markets.” In Do Economists Make Markets? On the Performativity of Economics, ed. by MacKenzie, Donald, Muniesa, Fabian, and Siu, Lucia, 163–89. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Musgrave, Richard A. 1957. “A Multiple Theory of Budget Determination.” Finanzarchiv 17(3): 333–43.Google Scholar
Mushkin, Selma J. 1962. “Health as an Investment.” Journal of Political Economy 70(5): 129–57.Google Scholar
Narassimhan, Easwaran, Gallagher, Kelly S., Koester, Stefan, and Rivera Alejo, Julio. 2018. “Carbon Pricing in Practice: A Review of Existing Emissions Trading Systems.” Climate Policy 18(8): 967–91.Google Scholar
Nash, Roderick. 1982. Wilderness and the American Mind, 3rd ed. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
National Academies of Science, Engineering, and Medicine (NAS). 2017. Valuing Climate Damages: Updating Estimation of the Social Cost of Carbon Dioxide. https://nap.nationalacademies.org/catalog/24651/valuing-climate-damages-updating-estimation-of-the-social-cost-of.Google Scholar
National Park Service (NPS), Land and Recreational Planning Division. 1949. The Economics of Public Recreation: An Economic Study of the Monetary Evaluation of Recreation in the National Parks. Washington, DC: National Park Service.Google Scholar
Natural Capital Committee. 2015. The State of Natural Capital: Protecting and Improving Natural Capital for Prosperity and Wellbeing London: Natural Capital Committee. https://assets.publishing.service.gov.uk/government/uploads/system/uploads/attachment_data/file/516725/ncc-state-natural-capital-third-report.pdf.Google Scholar
Naylor, D. Keith. 2005. “Pinchot, Gifford.” In The Encyclopedia of Religion and Nature, ed. by Taylor, Bron R. and Kaplan, Jeffrey. New York: Thoemmes Continuum, 1280–81.Google Scholar
Neel, Susan Rhoades. 1994. “Newton Drury and the Echo Park Dam Controversy.” Forest & Conservation History 38(2): 5666.Google Scholar
Nelson, Robert H. 2010. The New Holy Wars: Economic Religion vs. Environmental Religion in Contemporary America. University Park: Pennsylvania State Press.Google Scholar
Nerlove, Marc. 1958. The Dynamics of Supply: Estimation of Farmers’ Response to Price. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press.Google Scholar
Newton, Julianne Lutz. 2006. Aldo Leopold’s Odyssey. Washington, DC: Island Press.Google Scholar
Niedercorn, John H., and Kain, John F.. 1963. “An Econometric Model of Metropolitan Development.” Papers in Regional Science 11(1): 123–43.Google Scholar
Nishibayashi, Shogo. 2019. “A.V. Kneese’s Water Quality Management Research (1960s), within the History of Environmental Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 41(3): 411–31.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D. 1992. “An Optimal Transition Path for Controlling Greenhouse Gasses.” Science 258(5086): 1315–19.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D. 2007. “A Review of the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change.” Journal of Economic Literature 45(3): 686702.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D. 2017. “Revisiting the Social Cost of Carbon.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 114(7): 1518–23.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D. 2018. “Evolution of Modeling of the Economics of Global Warming: Changes in the DICE Model, 1992–2017.” Climatic Change 148: 623–40.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D., and Kokkelenberg, Edward C., eds. 1999. Nature’s Numbers: Expanding the National Economic Accounts to Include the Environment. Panel on Integrated Environmental and Economic Accounting. National Research Council. Washington, DC: National Academies Press.Google Scholar
Nordhaus, William D., and Tobin, James. 1973. “Is Growth Obsolete?” In The Measurement of Economic and Social Performance, ed. by Moss, Milton, 509–64. New York: National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
O’Neill, John. 1992. “The Varieties of Intrinsic Value.” The Monist 75(2): 119–37.Google Scholar
Office of Management and Budget (OMB). 1992. Budget Circular A-94. www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/legacy_drupal_files/omb/circulars/A94/a094.pdf.Google Scholar
Office of Management and Budget (OMB). 1993. Budget Circular A-4. www.white-house.gov/wp-content/uploads/legacy_drupal_files/omb/circulars/A4/a-4.pdf.Google Scholar
Office of Science Technology and Policy (OSTP), Office of Management and Budget, and Department of Commerce. 2022. National Strategy to Develop Statistics for Environmental-Economic Decisions. Public Comment Draft. Washington, DC: The White House. www.whitehouse.gov/wp-content/uploads/2022/08/Natural-Capital-Accounting-Strategy.pdf.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Vincent, and Ostrom, Elinor. 1965. “A Behavioral Approach to the Study of Intergovernmental Relations.” Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science 359: 137–46.Google Scholar
Outdoor Recreation Resources Review Commission (ORRRC). 1961. A Progress Report to the President and to the Congress.Google Scholar
Panhans, Matthew T., and Singleton, John D.. 2017. “The Empirical Economist’s Toolkit: From Models to Methods.” In The Age of the Applied Economist: The Transformation of Economics since the 1970s, ed. by Backhouse, Roger E. and Cherrier, Béatrice. History of Political Economy 49(S): 127–57. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Papandreou, Andreas A. 1994. Externality and Institutions. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Parsons, George R. 2017. “Travel Cost Models.” In A Primer on Nonmarket Valuation, 2nd ed, ed. by Champ, Patricia A., Boyle, Kevin J., and Brown, Thomas C., 187233. Dordrecht, The Netherlands: Springer.Google Scholar
Payne, John W., Bettman, James R., and Schkade, David A.. 1999. “Measuring Constructed Preferences: Toward a Building Code.” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 19: 243–70.Google Scholar
Pearce, David. 2002. “An Intellectual History of Environmental Economics.” Annual Review of Energy and the Environment 27: 5781.Google Scholar
Persky, Joseph. 1993. “Retrospectives: Consumer Sovereignty.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 7(1): 183–91.Google Scholar
Phaneuf, Daniel J., and Requate, Till. 2017. A Course in Environmental Economics: Theory, Policy and Practice. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Pigou, A.C. [1932] 1962. The Economics of Welfare, 4th ed. London: Macmillan & Co.Google Scholar
Pinchot, Gifford. 1891. “Government Forestry Abroad.” Publications of the American Economic Association 6(3): 757.Google Scholar
Pinchot, Gifford. 1910. The Fight for Conservation. New York: Doubleday, Page, & Co.Google Scholar
Pinchot, Gifford. 1947. Breaking New Ground. New York: Harcourt, Brace, & Co.Google Scholar
Pindyck, Robert. 2013. “Climate Change Policy: What Do the Models Tell Us?Journal of Economic Literature 51(3): 860–72.Google Scholar
Pisani, Donald J. 2003. “Federal Reclamation and the American West in the Twentieth Century.” Agricultural History 77(3): 391419.Google Scholar
Plassmann, Florenz, and Tideman, T. Nicolaus. 2004. “Frank Knight’s Proposal to End Distinctions among Factors of Production and His Objection to the Single Tax.” History of Political Economy 36(3): 505–19.Google Scholar
Plater, Zygmunt J.B. 2013. The Snail Darter and the Dam: How Pork Barrel Politics Endangered a Little Fish and Killed a River. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1993. “Contingent Valuation: A View of the Conference and Associated Research.” In Contingent Valuation: A Critical Assessment, ed. by Hausman, Jerry A., 467–78. Amsterdam: North Holland.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R. 1996. “Rational Individual Behaviour in Markets and Social Choice Processes: The Discovered Preference Hypothesis.” In The Rational Foundations of Economic Behaviour, ed. by Arrow, Kenneth J., Colombatto, Enrico, Perlman, Mark, and Schmidt, Christian, 225–50. New York: St. Martin’s Press.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R., and Zeiler, Kathryn. 2005. “The Willingness to Pay-Willingness to Accept Gap, the ‘Endowment Effect,’ Subject Misconceptions, and Experimental Procedures for Eliciting Valuations.” American Economic Review 95(3): 530–45.Google Scholar
Plott, Charles R., and Zeiler, Kathryn. 2007. “Exchange Asymmetries Incorrectly Interpreted as Evidence of Endowment Effect Theory and Prospect Theory?American Economic Review 97(4): 1538.Google Scholar
Porter, Theodore M. 1991. “Objectivity and Authority: How French Engineers Reduced Public Utility to Numbers.” Poetics Today 12(2): 245–65.Google Scholar
Porter, Theodore M. 1995. Trust in Numbers: The Pursuit of Objectivity in Science and Public Life. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Portney, Paul R. 1994. “The Contingent Valuation Debate: Why Economists Should Care.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 8(4): 317.Google Scholar
Potter, Neal, and Christy, Francis T., Jr. 1962. Trends in Natural Resource Commodities. Baltimore: The Johns Hopkins Press for Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Price, Reginald C. 1948. “Review Comments on the Tentative Report and Appendix of the American Society of Civil Engineers’ Committee on Cost Allocations for Multiple Purpose Water Projects.” Memorandum, April 14. RCP 35.Google Scholar
Proceedings of the Endangered Species Committee, United States Department of the Interior. 1979. http://lawdigitalcommons.bc.edu/darter_materials.Google Scholar
Rader, Benjamin G. 1966. The Academic Mind and Reform: The Influence of Richard T Ely in American Life. Lexington: University Press of Kentucky.Google Scholar
Raiffa, Howard. 1969. “Preferences for Multi-Attributed Alternatives.” Memorandum RM-5868-DOT/RC. Prepared for U.S. Department of Transportation, Federal Railroad Administration, Office of High Speed Ground Transportation. The RAND Corporation, Santa Monica, California.Google Scholar
Randall, Alan. 1972. “Market Solutions to Externality Problems: Theory and Practice.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 54(2): 175–83.Google Scholar
Randall, Alan, and Stoll, John R.. 1980. “Consumer’s Surplus in Commodity Space.” American Economic Review 70(3): 449–55.Google Scholar
Randall, Alan, Ives, Berry, and Eastman, Clyde. 1974. “Bidding Games for Valuation of Aesthetic Environmental Improvements.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 1: 132–49.Google Scholar
Regan, Mark M. 1958. “Sharing Financial Responsibility of River Basin Development.” Journal of Farm Economics 40(5): 1690–702.Google Scholar
Regan, Mark M., and Greenshields, E.L.. 1951. “Benefit-Cost Analysis of Resource Development Programs.” Journal of Farm Economics 33(4): 866–78.Google Scholar
Regan, Mark M., and Weitzell, E.C.. 1947. “Evaluation of Soil and Water Conservation Measures and Programs.” Journal of Farm Economics 29(4): 1275–94.Google Scholar
Reich, Charles A. 1964. “The New Property.” Yale Law Journal (April): 733–87.Google Scholar
Rennert, Kevin, Frank Errickson, Brian C. Prest, Lisa Rennels, et al. 2022. “Comprehensive Evidence Implies a Higher Social Cost of CO2.” Nature. https://doi.org/10.1038/s41586-022-05224-9.Google Scholar
Renshaw, Edward F. 1958Economics of Pollution Control.” Sewage and Industrial Wastes 30(5): 680–88.Google Scholar
Renshaw, Edward F. 1963. “The Management of Ground Water Reserves.” Journal of Farm Economics 45(2): 285–95.Google Scholar
Resources for the Future (RFF). 1954. The Nation Looks at Its Resources: Report of the Mid-Century Conference on Resources for the Future. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Resources for the Future (RFF). 1970. “New Guidelines for Water.” Resources (Jan.): 15–17.Google Scholar
Resources for the Future (RFF). 1977. Resources for the Future: The First 25 Years. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Resources for the Future (RFF). 2001. “In Appreciation of Allen V. Kneese.” Resources (May). www.resources.org/archives/in-appreciation-dr-allen-v-kneese/.Google Scholar
Revesz, Richard L. 2018. “Regulation and Distribution.” New York University Law Review 93: 1489–578.Google Scholar
Reynolds, D.J. 1956. “The Cost of Road Accidents.” Journal of the Royal Statistical Society 119: 393408.Google Scholar
Rice, Dorothy P., and Cooper, Barbara S.. 1967. American Journal of Public Health 57(11): 1954–66.Google Scholar
Ridker, Ronald G. 1967. The Economics of Air Pollution. New York: Prager.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1935. An Essay on the Nature and Significance of Economic Science. 2nd ed. London: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Robbins, Lionel. 1938. “Interpersonal Comparisons of Utility: Comment.” Economic Journal 48: 635–41.Google Scholar
Robertson, Morgan M. 2006. “The Nature that Capital Can See: Science, State, and Market in the Commodification of Ecosystem Services.” Environment and Planning D: Society and Space 24: 367–87.Google Scholar
Rodgers, Andrew Denny, III. 1951. Bernhard Eduard Fernow: A Story of North American Forestry. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Rolston, Holmes, III. 2002. “Naturalizing Callicott.” In Land, Value, Community: Callicott and Environmental Philosophy, ed. by Ouderkirk, Wayne and Hill, Jim, 107–22. Albany: State University of New York Press.Google Scholar
Roosevelt, Theodore. 1908. “Conservation as a National Duty.” Speech, May 13th. https://voicesofdemocracy.umd.edu/theodore-roosevelt-conservation-as-a-national-duty-speech-text/.Google Scholar
Røpke, Inge. 2004. “The Early History of Modern Ecological Economics.” Ecological Economics 50: 293314.Google Scholar
Rothenberg, Jerome. 1967. Economic Evaluation of Urban Renewal: Conceptual Foundation of Benefit-Cost Analysis. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Rowe, Robert D., d’Arge, Ralph C., and Brookshire, David S.. 1980. “An Experiment on the Economic Value of Visibility.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 7: 119.Google Scholar
Roy, René. 1949. “De la theorie des choix aux budgets de familles.” Econometrica 17(July): 179–86.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2000. “Understanding Institutional Economics: 1918–1929.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 22(3): 277308.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2001. “Institutional Economics: Then and Now.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 15(3): 173–94.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm. 2011. “The USDA Graduate School: Government Training in Statistics and Economics, 1921–1945.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 33(4): 419–47.Google Scholar
Rutherford, Malcolm, and Tyler DesRoches, C.. 2008. “The Institutionalist Reaction to Keynesian Economics.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 30(1): 2948.Google Scholar
Sabin, Paul. 2013. The Bet: Paul Ehrlich, Julian Simon, and Our Gamble over Earth’s Future. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Sager, Lutz. 2019. “The Global Consumer Incidence of Carbon Pricing: Evidence from Trade.” GRI Working Paper No. 320. www.cccep.ac.uk/wp-content/uploads/2019/04/working-paper-320-Sager.pdf.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1947. Foundations of Economic Analysis. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1952. “Spatial Price Equilibrium and Linear Programming.” American Economic Review 42: 283303.Google Scholar
Samuelson, Paul A. 1954. “The Pure Theory of Public Expenditure.” Review of Economics and Statistics 36(4): 387–89.Google Scholar
Sandel, Michael J. 1996. Democracy’s Discontent: America in Search of a Public Philosophy. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Sandmo, Angmar. 2015. “The Early History of Environmental Economics.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 9(1): 4363.Google Scholar
Sassatelli, Roberta. 2007. Consumer Culture: History, Theory and Politics. Los Angeles: Sage Publications.Google Scholar
Sax, Joseph L. 1980. Mountains without Handrails: Reflections on the Natural Parks. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Schabas, Margaret. 2005. The Natural Origins of Economics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1968. “The Life You Save May Be Your Own.” In Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis, ed. by Chase, Samuel B., Jr., 127–76. Washington, DC: Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas C. 1992. “Some Economics of Global Warming.” American Economic Review 82(1): 114.Google Scholar
Schkade, David A., and Payne, John W.. 1994. “How People Respond to Contingent Valuation Questions: A Verbal Protocol Analysis of Willingness to Pay For an Environmental Regulation.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 26(1): 88109.Google Scholar
Schmid, Allan A. 1967. “Nonmarket Values and Efficiency of Public Investments in Water Resources.” American Economic Review 57(2): 158–68.Google Scholar
Schmithüssen, Franz. 2013. “Three Hundred Years of Applied Sustainability in Forests.” Unasylva 64: 311.Google Scholar
Schröter, Matthias, Albert, Christian, Marques, Alexandra, Tobon, Wolke, et al. 2016. “National Ecosystem Assessments in Europe: A Review.” BioScience 66(10): 813–28.Google Scholar
Schröter, Matthias, Zanden, Emma H., Oudenhoven, Alexander P.E., Remme, Roy P., et al. 2014. “Ecosystem Services as a Contested Concept: A Synthesis of Critique and Counter-Arguments.” Conservation Letters 7: 514–23.Google Scholar
Schultz, Theodore W. 1961. “Investment in Human Capital.” American Economic Review 51(1): 117.Google Scholar
Schumacher, Ernest F. 1973. Small is Beautiful: A Study of Economics as If People Mattered. New York: Harper and Row.Google Scholar
Scitovsky, Tibor. 1954. “Two Concepts of External Economies.” Journal of Political Economy 62: 143–51.Google Scholar
Scodari, Paul F., and Fisher, Ann. 1988. “How Uncle Sam Values Mortality Risk Reductions.” In Highway Safety: At the Crossroads, ed. by Stammer, Robert E., 182–98. New York: American Society for Civil Engineers.Google Scholar
Scott, Anthony. 1955. “The Fishery: The Objectives of Sole Ownership.” Journal of Political Economy 63(2): 116–24.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 1987. On Ethics and Economics. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.Google Scholar
Sen, Amartya. 2009. The Idea of Justice. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press.Google Scholar
Sent, Esther-Mirjam. 2007. “Some Like It Cold: Thomas Schelling as a Cold Warrior.” Journal of Economic Methodology 14: 455–71.Google Scholar
Siehl, George H. 2008. “The Policy Path to the Great Outdoors: A History of the Outdoor Recreation Review Commissions.” Discussion Paper 08-44. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Simon, Julian L. 1981. The Ultimate Resource. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Simon, Nathalie B., Dockins, Chris, Maguire, Kelly B., Newbold, Stephen C., Krupnick, Alan J., and Taylor, Laura O.. 2020. “What’s in a Name? A Search for Alternatives to ‘VSL’.” Review of Environmental Economics and Policy 13(1): 155–61.Google Scholar
Simpson, David R., Toman, Michael A., and Ayres, Robert U.. 2005. Scarcity and Growth Revisited. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Singleton, John D. 2015. “Sorting Charles Tiebout.” In Market Failure in Context, ed. by Marciano, Alain and Medema, Steven G.. History of Political Economy 47(S): 199226. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Adam. [1776] 1965. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations, ed. by Cannan, Edwin. New York: Modern Library.Google Scholar
Smith, Bruce L.R. 1966. The RAND Corporation: Case Study of a Nonprofit Advisory Corporation. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Gerald Alonzo. 1982. “Natural Resource Economic Theory of the First Conservation Movement (1895–1927).” History of Political Economy 14(4): 483–95.Google Scholar
Smith, James Allen. 1991. The Idea Brokers: Think Tanks and the Rise of the New Policy Elite. New York: Free Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Mark C. 1994. Social Science in the Crucible: The American Debate over Objectivity and Purpose, 1918–1941. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry, ed. 1979. Scarcity and Growth Reconsidered. New York: RFF Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry, ed. 1984. Environmental Policy under Reagan’s Executive Order: The Role of Benefit-Cost Analysis. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina Press.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry. 1988. “The Influence of Resource and Environmental Problems on Applied Welfare Economics.” In Environmental Resources and Applied Welfare Economics: Essays in Honor of John V. Krutilla, ed. by Kerry Smith, V., 344. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry. 1992. “Arbitrary Values, Good Causes, and Premature Verdicts.” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 22(1): 7189.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry. 2004. “Krutilla’s Legacy: Twenty-First-Century Challenges for Environmental Economics.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(5): 1167–78.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry. 2006. “Fifty Years of Contingent Valuation.” In Handbook of Contingent Valuation, ed. by Alberini, Anna and Kahn, James R., 765. Cheltenham, UK: Edward Elgar.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry. 2011. “Inventing Price Systems and Substitutes for Them.” History of Political Economy 43(2): 347–52.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry. 2015. “Krutilla’s Conservation Reconsidered.” Mimeo.Google Scholar
Smith, V. Kerry, and Spencer Banzhaf, H.. 2004. “A Diagrammatic Exposition of Weak Complementarity and the Willig Condition.” American Journal of Agricultural Economics 86(2): 455–66.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. 1979. “Incentive Compatible Experimental Processes for the Provision of Public Goods.” In Research in Experimental Economics, ed. by Smith, Vernon L., 59168. Greenwich: JAI Press.Google Scholar
Smith, Vernon L. 1982. “Markets as Economizers of Information: Experimental Examination of the ‘Hayek Hypothesis’.” Economic Inquiry 20(2): 165–79.Google Scholar
Smout, T.C. 2000. Nature Contested: Environmental History in Scotland and Northern England since 1600. Edinburgh: Edinburgh University Press.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1971. “The Economist’s Approach to Pollution and Its Control.” Science 173: 498503.Google Scholar
Solow, Robert M. 1993. “Sustainability: An Economist’s Perspective.” In Economics of the Environment, Selected Readings, ed. by Dorfman, Robert and Dorfman, Nancy S., 3rd ed., 179–87. New York: Norton.Google Scholar
Spengler, Joseph J. 1968. “The Economics of Safety.” Law and Contemporary Problems 33(3): 619–38.Google Scholar
Spillman, W.J. 1918. “Work of the Office of Farm Management Relating to Land Classification and Land Tenure.” American Economic Review papers and proceedings 8(1): 6571.Google Scholar
Stapleford, Thomas A. 2009. The Cost of Living in America: A Political History of Economic Statistics, 1880–2000. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stapleford, Thomas A. 2011a. “Reconceiving Quality: Political Economy and the Rise of Hedonic Price Indexes.” In Histories on Econometrics, ed. by Boumans, Marcel, Dupont-Kieffer, Arian, and Qin, Duo. History of Political Economy 43(S): 309–28. Durham: Duke University Press.Google Scholar
Stapleford, Thomas A. 2011b. “Aftershocks from a Revolution: Ordinal Utility and Cost-of-Living Indexes.” Journal of the History of Economic Thought 33(2): 187222.Google Scholar
Stavins, Robert. 2011. “The Problem of the Commons: Still Unsettled after 100 Years.” American Economic Review 101: 81108.Google Scholar
Steiguer, J. Edward de. 2006. The Origins of Modern Environmental Thought. Tucson: University of Arizona Press.Google Scholar
Steiner, Peter O. 1969a. “The Public Sector and the Public Interest.” In The Analysis and Evaluation of Public Expenditures: The PPB System. Vol. 1. A Compendium of papers submitted to the Subcommittee on Economy in Government of the Joint Economic Committee, 13–45. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Steiner, Peter O. 1969b. Public Expenditure Budgeting. Washington, DC: Brookings.Google Scholar
Stern, Nicholas. 2007. The Economics of Climate Change: The Stern Review. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1946. Production and Distribution Theories. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Stigler, George J. 1947. The Theory of Price. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, Joseph E., Sen, Amartya, and Fitoussi, Jean-Paul. 2010. Mismeasuring Our Lives: Why GDP Doesn’t Add Up. New York: The New Press.Google Scholar
Sturn, Richard. 2010. “‘Public Goods’ Before Samuelson: Interwar Finanzwissenschaft and Musgrave’s Synthesis.” European Journal of the History of Economic Thought 17(2): 279312.Google Scholar
Suh, Jooyeoun, and Folbre, Nancy. 2017. “Time, Money, and Inequality.” Oeconomia 7(1): 324.Google Scholar
Svorenčík, Andrej. 2015. The Experimental Turn in Economics: A History of Experimental Economics. Dissertation, University of Utrecht.Google Scholar
Takayama, Takashi, and Judge, George G.. 1964. “Equilibrium among Spatially Separated Markets: A Reformulation.” Econometrica 32(4): 510–24.Google Scholar
Taussig, F.W. 1919. “Price Fixing as Seen by a Price Fixer.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 33: 205–41.Google Scholar
Taylor, Henry C. 1905. An Introduction to the Study of Agricultural Economics. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Taylor, Henry C. 1907. “Economic Problems in Agriculture by Irrigation.” Journal of Political Economy 15(4): 209–28.Google Scholar
Taylor, Henry C. 1919. Agricultural Economics. New York: Macmillan.Google Scholar
Taylor, Henry C. 1922. “The Development of the American Farm Economic Association.” Journal of Farm Economics 4: 9299.Google Scholar
Taylor, Henry C., and Dewees Taylor, Anne. 1952. The Story of Agricultural Economics in the United States, 1840–1932. Ames: Iowa State College Press.Google Scholar
Teele, R.P. 1904. “The Organization of Irrigation Companies.” Journal of Political Economy 12: 161–78.Google Scholar
Teele, R.P. 1926. “The Financing of Non-Governmental Irrigation Enterprises.” Journal of Land and Public Utility Economics 2(4): 427–40.Google Scholar
Teele, R.P. 1927. “The Federal Subsidy in Land Reclamation.” Journal of Land & Public Utility Economics 3(4): 337–42.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard. 1980. “Toward a Positive Theory of Consumer Choice.” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1(1): 3960.Google Scholar
Thaler, Richard, and Rosen, Sherwin. 1976. “The Value of Life Saving.” In Household Production and Consumption, ed. by Terleckyj, Nestor E., 265–98. New York: Columbia University Press for NBER.Google Scholar
The Ford Foundation. 1949. Report of the Study for the Ford Foundation on Policy and Program. Detroit: Ford Foundation.Google Scholar
The Ford Foundation. 1953. The Ford Foundation Annual Report for 1952. www.fordfoundation.org/about/library/annual-reports/1952-annual-report/.Google Scholar
The Ford Foundation. 1954. The Ford Foundation Annual Report: 1953. New York: Ford Foundation.Google Scholar
The President’s Materials Policy Commission. 1952. Resources for Freedom. A Report to the President. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Thelen, David P. 1972. The New Citizenship: Origins of Progressivism in Wisconsin, 1885–1900. Colombia: University of Missouri Press.Google Scholar
Thurstone, Louis L. 1931. “The Indifference Function.” Journal of Social Psychology 2(2): 139–67.Google Scholar
Tiebout, Charles M. 1956. “A Pure Theory of Local Expenditures.” Journal of Political Economy 64(5): 416–24.Google Scholar
Tietenberg, Tom. 2006. Emissions Trading: Principles and Practice, 2nd ed. Washington, DC: Resources for the Future.Google Scholar
Tietenberg, Tom. 2010. “Cap-and-Trade: The Evolution of an Economic Idea.” Agricultural and Resource Economics Review 39(3): 359–67.Google Scholar
Tol, Richard S.J. 1997. “On the Optimal Control of Carbon Dioxide Emissions: An Application of FUND.” Environmental Modeling and Assessment 2(3): 151–63.Google Scholar
Tol, Richard S.J. 2002. “Estimates of the Damage Costs of Climate Change, Part I: Benchmark Estimates.” Environmental and Resource Economics 21: 4773.Google Scholar
Trentmann, Frank. 2016. Empire of Things: How We Became a World of Consumers, from the Fifteenth Century to the Twenty-First. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Trice, Andrew H., and Wood, Samuel E.. 1958. “Measurement of Recreation Benefits.” Land Economics 34(3): 195207.Google Scholar
Turner, Frederick Jackson. [1893] 1920. “The Significance of the Frontier in American History.” In The Frontier in American History, ed. by Taylor, Frederick Jackson. New York: Henry Holt and Company, 138.Google Scholar
Twight, Ben W. 1990. “Bernhard Fernow and Prussian Forestry in America.” Journal of Forestry 88(2): 2125.Google Scholar
UK National Ecosystem Assessment. 2011. UK National Ecosystem Assessment: Synthesis of the Key Findings. Cambridge: UNEP-WCMC. http://uknea.unep-wcmc.org/Resources/tabid/82/Default.aspxGoogle Scholar
United Church of Christ (UCC). 1987. Toxic Wastes and Race in the United States. Report of the Commission for Racial Justice. http://uccfiles.com/pdf/ToxicWastes&Race.pdf.Google Scholar
United Nations (UN). 2014. System of Environmental-Economic Accounting 2012: Central Framework. New York: United Nations. https://seea.un.org/sites/seea.un.org/files/seea_cf_final_en.pdf.Google Scholar
United Nations (UN). 2021. System of Environmental-Economic Accounting: Ecosystem Accounting. White cover publication, pre-edited text subject to official editing. https://seea.un.org/ecosystem-accounting.Google Scholar
United States Bureau of Economic Analysis (US BEA). 1994. “Integrated Economic and Environmental Satellite Accounts.” Survey of Current Business 74: 3349.Google Scholar
United States Department of Agriculture (USDA). 1929. Annual Report of the Department of Agriculture. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
United States Senate. 1957. Evaluation of Recreation Benefits from Reservoirs. Hearings before a subcommittee of the Committee of Public Works, March 12–14.Google Scholar
Valavanis, Stefan. 1958. “Traffic Safety from an Economist’s Point of View.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 72(4): 477–84.Google Scholar
Van Hise, Charles. 1909. “Address of Dr. Charles Van Hise.” Report of the National Conservation Commission, vol. I, 178–80. Washington, DC: Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Viner, Jacob. 1932. “Cost Curves and Supply Curves.” Zeitschrift Für National-ökonomie 3(1): 2346.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip. 1993. “The Value of Risks to Life and Health.” Journal of Economic Literature 31: 1912–46.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip. 2009a. “The Devaluation of Life.” Regulation and Governance 3: 103–27.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip. 2009b. “Reply to the Comments on ‘The Devaluation of Life’.” Regulation and Governance 3: 306–9.Google Scholar
Viscusi, W. Kip. 2011. “What’s to Know? Puzzles in the Literature on the Value of Statistical Life.” Journal of Economic Surveys 26(5): 763–68.Google Scholar
von Neumann, John, and Morganstern, Oskar. 1944. Theory of Games and Economic Behavior. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Wahl, Richard W. 1995. “Redividing the Waters: The Reclamation Act of 1902.” Natural Resources and Environment (Summer): 3138.Google Scholar
Wallis, W.A., and Friedman, Milton. 1942. “The Empirical Derivation of Indifference Functions.” In Studies in Mathematical Economics and Econometrics in Honor of Henry Schultz, ed. by Lange, Oskar, McIntyre, Francis, and Yntema, Theodore, 175–89. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Walsh, Richard G., Johnson, Donn M., and McKean, John R.. 1992. “Benefit Transfer of Outdoor Recreation Demand Studies, 1968–1988.” Water Resources Research 28(3): 707–13.Google Scholar
Warde, Paul. 2011. “The Invention of Sustainability.” Modern Intellectual History 8(1): 153–70.Google Scholar
Water Resources Council (WRC). 1962. Policies, Standards, and Procedures in the Formulation, Evaluation, and Review of Plans for Use and Development of Water and Related Land Resources. Senate Document 97.Google Scholar
Water Resources Council (WRC). 1964. Supplement No. 1, Evaluation Standards for Primary Outdoor Recreation Benefits. (Supplement to Policies, Standards, and Procedures in the Formulation, Evaluation, and Review of Plans for Use and Development of Water and Related Land Resources.) Senate Document 97.Google Scholar
Water Resources Council (WRC) Special Task Force. 1969. Procedures for Evaluation of Water and Related Land Resource Projects. Report to the Water Resources Council by the Special Task Force. April.Google Scholar
Water Resources Council (WRC) Special Task Force. 1971a. Proposed Principles and Standards for Planning Water and Land Resources. Washington, DC: Water Resources Council.Google Scholar
Water Resources Council (WRC) Special Task Force. 1971b. Procedures for Planning Water and Land Resources: Findings and Recommendations of the Special Task Force. Washington, DC: US Government Printing Office.Google Scholar
Waugh, Frederick V. 1929. Quality as a Determinant of Vegetable Prices. New York: Columbia University Press.Google Scholar
Weintraub, E. Roy. 1991. Stabilizing Dynamics: Constructing Economic Knowledge. Cambridge, UK: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1959. “On the Sovereignty of Consumer, Citizen, and Stockholder.” Southern Economic Journal 26(2): 156–58.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1961. Economics of Public Health: Measuring the Economic Impacts of Diseases. Philadelphia: University of Pennsylvania Press.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1964. “Collective-Consumption Services of Individual-Consumption Goods.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 78(3): 471–77.Google Scholar
Weisbrod, Burton A. 1966. “Income Redistribution Effects and Benefit-Cost Analysis.” In Problems in Public Expenditure Analysis, ed. by Chase, Samuel B., Jr., 177209. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Weitzman, Martin L. 1974a. “Prices vs. Quantities.” Review of Economic Studies 41(4): 477–91.Google Scholar
Weitzman, Martin L. 1974b. “Free Access vs. Private Ownership as Alternative Systems for Managing Common Property.” Journal of Economic Theory 8(2): 225–34.Google Scholar
Weitzman, Martin L. 2007. “A Review of the Stern Review on the Economics of Climate Change.” Journal of Economic Literature 45(3): 703–24.Google Scholar
Wennergren, E. Boyd. 1964. “Valuing Non-Market Priced Recreational Resources.” Land Economics 43: 303–14.Google Scholar
Whittington, Dale, and Kerry Smith, V.. 2020. “The Ex-Ante Economic Analysis of Investments in Large Dams: A Brief History.” Water Economics and Policy 6(4): https://doi.org/10.1142/S2382624X20500101Google Scholar
Willig, Robert D. 1976. “Consumer’s Surplus without Apology.” American Economic Review 66(4): 589–97.Google Scholar
Winch, Donald. 1972. “Marginalism and the Boundaries of Economic Science.” History of Political Economy 4(2): 325–43.Google Scholar
Winch, Donald. 2006. “The Problematic Theory of the Consumer in Orthodox Economic Thought.” In The Making of the Consumer: Knowledge, Power, and Identity in the Modern World, ed. by Trentmann, Frank, 3151. Oxford: Berg.Google Scholar
Wohl, Martin. 1968. “A Conceptual Framework for Evaluating Traffic Safety System Measures.” RAND report RM-5632-DOT.Google Scholar
Wold, Herman O.A. 1949. “Discussion” [of Roy (1949)]. Econometrica 17(July): 187–88.Google Scholar
Wolfe, Linnie Marsh. [1945] 2003. Son of the Wilderness: The Life of John Muir. Madison: University of Wisconsin Press.Google Scholar
Wolfe, Roy I. 1964. “Perspective on Outdoor Recreation: A Bibliographical Survey.” Geographical Review 54(2): 203–39.Google Scholar
Wolloch, Nathaniel. 2017. Nature in the History of Economic Thought: How Natural Resources Became and Economic Concept. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
World Bank. 2022. “Carbon Pricing Dashboard.” https://carbonpricingdashboard.worldbank.org/.Google Scholar
Worster, Donald. 1994. Nature’s Economy: A History of Ecological Ideas, 2nd ed. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Worster, Donald. 2008. A Passion for Nature: The Life of John Muir. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1913. “Review of Pigou’s Wealth and Welfare.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 27(4): 672–86.Google Scholar
Young, Allyn A. 1928. “Increasing Returns and Economic Progress.” Economic Journal 38: 527–42.Google Scholar
Zeckhauser, Richard. 1989. “Distinguished Fellow: Reflections on Thomas Schelling.” Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(2): 153–64.Google Scholar
Zimmermann, Michel, and Pye, Steve. 2018. “Inequality in Energy and Climate Policies: Assessing Distributional Impact Consideration in UK Policy Appraisal.” Energy Policy 123: 594601.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×