Published online by Cambridge University Press: 20 December 2023
The next step in the logical chain at the heart of post-Keynesian theory is an account of how the economy comes to settle at an equilibrium that is dictated by how much producers can expect to sell, and has no inherent automatic mechanism to ensure that that equilibrium either be at full employment of resources or tend towards it over time. This is where the theory departs most drastically from the framework of general equilibrium, which largely represents what counts as mainstream economics nowadays. In order to present it fully, we must first understand the implications of Say's law, which underpins most mainstream characterizations of equilibrium. We then need to understand the conditions under which Keynes first came to reject Say's law, which is the version of the principle of effective demand that is known as Marshallian in post-Keynesian theory, as it relies heavily on the theoretical framework developed by Marshall. But the notion of the economy settling at an under-employment equilibrium because of constraints of demand was also developed, separately, by Kalecki, starting from what could be called a Marxian standpoint. The difference between the two approaches is said primarily (but not exclusively) to be in the form of aggregate supply, which is assumed (Lavoie 2014: 262). Again, proceeding in chronological order of publication, we turn first to the Marshallian (or Keynesian) formulation of the rejection of Say's law.
Say's law
There are different versions of this proposition, but the one that most synthetically represents it is that supply creates its own demand, and that therefore there cannot be situations of excess supply. A corollary, then, is that there can never be a condition of involuntary unemployment of factors of production (labour in particular). The possibility of demand falling short of supply had been the object of an epistolary debate between Robert Malthus, who had suggested such a possibility, and David Ricardo, who instead denied that such a condition could ever arise. The most complete restatement of Say's law is given by John Stuart Mill, however, and can be represented as follows.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.