Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-lj6df Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T21:55:35.573Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Introduction

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  24 March 2022

Nikhil Menon
Affiliation:
University of Notre Dame, Indiana

Summary

The Introduction lays out the argument of the book and the political stakes of economic planning for the Indian state. It illuminates how crucial planning was to the Nehruvian state’s self-definition, and how the experiment of Plans and Parliament was meant to represent a distinct path in the superpower-divided Cold War. Seen from western capitals, the Indian experiment offered a path for Asia that was in stark contrast to the communist totalitarianism of the People’s Republic of China and the Soviet Union. It opens with a brief, but broad, history of the ideas of economic planning and national development in India between the late nineteenth century and the establishment of the Planning Commission in 1950. Surveying the spread of these ideas, it reveals the surprising support planning had across the political spectrum. There is also a short description of the international context of central planning and state intervention in the economy (ranging from the Soviet Union, to post-war Britain and New Deal America) in order to situate the Indian path within it. Along with an engagement with the secondary literature on the subject, the introduction lays out the key themes that the rest of the book will pursue.

Type
Chapter
Information
Planning Democracy
Modern India's Quest for Development
, pp. 1 - 22
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2022

The recently elected prime minister of India addressed the nation from the sandstone ramparts of the Red Fort in Delhi, his turban’s long trail flapping in a dry dusty summer breeze. It was Independence Day 2014, and Narendra Modi’s debut on this storied stage. With the Mughal fort’s soaring minarets as a backdrop, Jama Masjid’s giant white marble dome looming to his left, and the Indian flag fluttering overhead, he put to rest months of rumour. The leader of the Bharatiya Janata Party (BJP) confirmed what the public had suspected. The end was near for India’s long experiment with economic planning. The curtain was coming down on the Planning Commission, an institution that had once been the beating heart of the country’s economy.

Born the same year, Modi and the Planning Commission shared another milestone together. In his first Independence Day address as India’s leader, Modi declared that the Planning Commission had once merited its place and made significant contributions. Now, however, he believed it had decayed beyond repair. ‘Sometimes it costs a lot to repair an old house’, he said, ‘but it gives us no satisfaction’. Afterwards, we realize ‘that we might as well build a new house’, Modi explained with a smile.1 He would build it by bulldozing a decrepit structure and raising a shiny new one, the NITI Aayog (National Institution for Transforming India).

Sixty-four years earlier, days after the inauguration of the Republic, President Rajendra Prasad delivered a speech in Parliament. The thickly moustached veteran of the Congress Party declared on 31 January 1950 that the primary objective of his government would be to raise standards of living. In order to do so, he announced, ‘It is my Government’s intention to establish a Planning Commission so that the best use can be made of such resources as we possess for the development of the nation.’2 The Planning Commission was born.

The Indian planning project was one of the postcolonial world’s most ambitious experiments. It was an arranged marriage between Soviet-inspired economic planning and Western-style liberal democracy, at a time when the Cold War portrayed them as ideologically contradictory and institutionally incompatible. With each Five-Year Plan, the Planning Commission set the course for the nation’s economy. The ambit ranged from matters broad (free trade or protectionism?) to narrow (how much fish should fisheries produce to ensure protein in the national diet?). The commission’s pronouncements set the gears of government in motion. Shaping entire sectors of the economy through incentives, disincentives, and decree, the Planning Commission’s views rippled across the land to every farm and factory. Despite this awesome power, economic planning in India was considerably different from the kind experienced in communist regimes. The Planning Commission was reined in by democratic procedure that necessitated consultation with ministries in an elected government, with people’s representatives in Parliament, and ultimately with the popular will, through citizens voting every five years.

During the formative decades of the republic, planning was an idea that governed the nation. It was the vehicle chosen for rapid economic transformation after nearly two centuries of colonial rule, and it also became the language through which the government’s aspirations for democratic state-building were expressed. It was a staple of national conversation. Five-Year Plans marked the calendar of governance. Politicians seldom tired of invoking the Plans, the media dutifully reported on their progress, they were debated in civil society, and ordinary citizens found themselves called to work ever more energetically towards the Plan’s success.

As India emerged from generations of colonial rule in 1947, it faced the following questions: Would life be any better for three hundred and fifty million Indians? And how would independent India define itself? Dr Bhimrao Ambedkar – arch critic of caste and architect of the constitution – articulated the fear that was on the minds of many. In his last speech to the Constituent Assembly in late 1949, Ambedkar warned that India was about to enter a ‘life of contradictions’. ‘In politics we will have equality’, he said, ‘and in social and economic life we will have inequality’. These conflicts demanded attention: fail to do so, and those denied ‘will blow up the structure of political democracy’.3 The Indian government seemingly agreed, at least about the economy. The First Five-Year Plan noted that the international context made ‘planning not only compatible with democracy, but essential for its very survival’.4

The Indian drama had the world watching. Files from the British Foreign Office and the American State Department revealed that they, too, shared Ambedkar’s fear. The fledgling nation was widely believed to be doomed. The extraordinary challenges posed by India’s diversity and poverty appeared insurmountable. The ugly orgy of ethnic violence and sectarian nationalism that erupted during Partition seemed a dark omen. Predictions ranged from India splintering into smaller nations, to believing it was on the brink of going ‘Red’ under the malevolent influence of Mao’s China or Stalin’s Soviet Union, to speculation that it was ripe for authoritarian takeover. Seen from Washington, D.C., and the capitals of Western Europe, the peril was not just to democracy in India but to the success of democracy globally. If breathless columns in the New York Times were to be believed, the fate of democracy in Asia hung in the balance. India was a ‘Bastion Against Communism’ and the ‘Best Hope of Democracy in the Far East’. Mao’s China and Nehru’s India were locked in a battle of ‘Communist Dictatorship versus Democratic Freedom’.5 From Chicago, reflecting on his visit to India, Martin Luther King Jr wrote that it would be a ‘boon to democracy if one of the great nations of the world’ could provide for its people ‘without surrendering to a dictatorship of either the “right” or “left”’.6 In New Delhi, the influential director of the Ford Foundation in India, Douglas Ensminger, noted in a confidential staff document: ‘the world has anxiously watched India’s experiences in planning and executing its plans through democratic means’.7 Writing for The Observer in Britain, Thomas Balogh – an Oxford economist who later entered the House of Lords and became a Baron – described ‘India’s Experiment’ in stark terms. His prediction was that it ‘may become crucial for the future of the free world’. The Indian government was trying to modernize a vast, materially backward country through consent – to achieve democratically that which had ‘hitherto been undertaken, on a comparable scale, only by Communist dictatorships’.8 Confronting similar afflictions, the eyes of decolonizing Asia and Africa anxiously tracked India’s moves.

By planning through what they deemed as democratic means, the inaugural Indian government was trying to bridge the stark and historic misalignment between its political and economic realms. Planning was meant to resolve what Ambedkar had called a ‘life of contradictions’ by providing Indians parity in their political and economic freedoms and capabilities. Jawaharlal Nehru – anticolonial leader and independent India’s inaugural prime minister – recognized the tension between the two but believed they could be eased through planning. ‘Planning, though inevitably bringing about a great deal of control and coordination and interfering in some measure with individual freedom, would, as a matter of fact, in the context of India today, lead to a vast increase of freedom’.9 Nehru was implicitly suggesting that the existence of civil liberties on paper would matter little if citizens lacked the material capabilities to enjoy them.10 The stakes could not be higher. As Ambedkar warned, and the international press recognized, failure to act could put liberal democracy itself in peril.

This book uses planning as a lens through which to understand the Indian state and the nature of Indian democracy after independence. It interprets planning as a mode of nation-building, state formation, and legitimation in the aftermath of empire. The history of planning, here, is a history of the state – its capacities and posture towards citizens. What follows is a history of the Nehruvian state told through the prism of planning, rather than an economic history of planning or an account of the Five-Year Plans per se.

The first half argues that planning triggered the development of knowledge infrastructures that dramatically expanded the state’s footprint, particularly its ability to discern and govern the economy. This new knowledge infrastructure – an elaborate national statistical system and pioneering computer programme – made the economy more legible to the state and has ever since been central to the country’s development ambitions. The legacy of this process endures in institutions like the Central Statistical Organization (CSO) and National Sample Survey (NSS), which remain essential to policymaking to this day. It was this context, of a planning-induced explosion in the state’s quantitative capacities, that pried open the space for a statistician like P. C. Mahalanobis to sway economic policy. More broadly, this section offers insights into how centralized planning contributed to the technocratic and high-modernist features of the Indian state.11 Scholars have observed how the colonial origin of India’s constitution helps to explain the extraordinary powers the state wields.12 The choice of economic system – central planning – dovetailed with that legal concentration of might, contributing to a centralized state that ultimately placed expertise ahead of deliberative processes.

While the first part of the book analyses how the drive for data accelerated a drift towards technocracy, the latter reveals the contortions necessary to square that with democracy. Interrogating the government’s claim of ‘democratic planning’, I explore the lengths to which the state went to make the public ‘Plan-conscious’ and highlight the failings and paradox of these efforts. Democratic planning was meant to be different from communist planning; persuasion and informed consent were its mantras. Significantly, on a practical level, the government was aware that enthusiastic popular participation in the Plans would be necessary for them to succeed. The Indian state simply lacked the ability to fulfil them otherwise. India’s democratic planning was an ideology that claimed to nurture Plan-conscious citizens and produce a new kind of state that would walk the tightrope between capitalism and communism during the Cold War. It was the domestic equivalent of what came to be a non-aligned foreign policy. In this democratic avatar, planning functioned as a grand narrative for the nation – diagnosing the country’s ills, charting the course to development, and inviting civic partnership. It was a political vision in which the tension between technocratic decision-making and representative democracy could, in theory, be harmonized. Travelling troupes of musical performers, documentary films, college planning forums, and even enigmatic organizations like the Bharat Sadhu Samaj (Indian Society of Ascetics), all promoted planning. These chapters underline how democratic planning was simultaneously a project that many officials believed in, a realist response to weak state capacity, and a language of state legitimation that deployed the rhetoric of democracy despite being almost entirely top-down.

This book is an exploration of how the story of planning became so central to the story of independent India. It does not pass judgment on the economic effectiveness of the Five-Year Plans or seek to explain monumental oversights in spheres such as public health and primary education. Instead, it analyses planning as a technology of governance and means of legitimation. Indian planning was an historic experiment that sought to fuse democracy and centralized economic planning precisely when the rhetoric of the Cold War pitted them as fundamentally antithetical to each other. It is a history of Third World development in an ex-colony, charting how an underdeveloped nation navigated the global Cold War while unaligned with either superpower bloc. More specifically, it demonstrates how planning was made technically feasible and politically viable in a poor, populous, and overwhelmingly illiterate country. These were questions relevant not only to India but to an entire cohort of nations in the Global South during the mid-twentieth century.

***

Development was long fundamental to arguments for why India needed to be free. An economic critique of colonialism was foundational for the Indian National Congress, dating back to early salvos launched by Dadabhai Naoroji, Mahadev Ranade, Gopal Krishna Gokhale, and Romesh Dutt in the late nineteenth and early twentieth centuries. Belief in the empire’s material exploitation and wilful mismanagement of the Indian economy were mainstays of nationalist rhetoric.13 By the 1940s, this had become the primary argument against the British. The nationalists’ call for independence was not solely based on the claim that Indians – rather than white Britons – should take the reins of state. Colonial rule was illegitimate because it was exploitative.14 Self-government was thus justified not simply on the political grounds of self-representation but also because it was the necessary condition for economic advancement.

In the decades leading up to independence, planning emerged as the language through which Indian aspirations were expressed. Japan’s economic acceleration after the Meiji Restoration of 1868 turned heads, offering a glimpse of what a modernizing central authority could accomplish. News of rapid industrial advances in the Soviet Union through its first Five-Year Plan (1928–1932) inspired many in India to nurture similar hopes. President Franklin Roosevelt’s New Deal policies of coordinated government spending and regulation, drastically expanding the state’s economic reach in 1930s America, struck Indian observers as proof that planning was necessary even in capitalist economies. Contemporary free-market economist Lionel Robbins observed, presumably with dismay, that planning had become ‘the grand panacea of our age’.15 The onward march of planning during the interwar period led to an inflated belief in the capacities of governments, producing what one scholar calls ‘an intoxicating, and even delusional, sense of “doability”’.16 To many in India’s nationalist mainstream, especially the charismatic leaders of a younger generation like Subhas Chandra Bose and Nehru, the lesson drawn from communist Russia and New Deal America was that planning could either avert or address capitalist crises like the Great Depression.17

The rising trust in planning was not limited to those inclined to socialism. It was a language spoken across the Indian political spectrum because it was seen to offer legitimacy and identity to the future Indian state.18 In 1934, an engineer and former administrator of princely Mysore penned a book titled Planned Economy for India. Mokshagundam Visvesvaraya, on whose birthday India marks Engineer’s Day, believed India should follow ‘every progressive country’ in establishing centralized economic planning. He envisioned enlisting the nation’s ‘shrewdest brains’ in enacting a Ten-Year Plan aimed at industrial advancement.19 ‘Sir MV’ – the knighted, punctilious, white-and-gold turbaned progenitor of Indian plans – was then on the board of Tata Iron and Steel. That same year, the Marwari industrial tycoon Ghanshyamdas Birla also made a plea for planning. In an address to the Federation of Indian Chambers of Commerce and Industry, a body he co-founded, Birla criticized the colonial state’s response to the Depression as ‘drifting without a Plan’. Noting that the word planning had ‘become popular on account of its good associations’, he made a case for ‘National Economic Planning’ to this gathering of businessmen. Arguing for massive public works programme to inject life into the economy, Birla observed that this ‘secret had been realized by most of the countries that have planned’. He was referring to contexts as diverse as Britain under the influence of economist John Maynard Keynes, the New Deal in the United States, and even Germany under Hitler.

To capitalists like Birla, such arguments for planning and economic self-sufficiency expressed an aspiration for a modern economy in which domestic enterprises could prosper while being protected from foreign competition. The direction this businessman motioned towards in the early 1930s was remarkably similar to the import-substitution-industrialization model that characterized independent India from mid-century until the market reforms of the 1990s, with momentous consequences for the country. ‘We do not aspire’, Birla wrote, ‘to build industries artificially on the strength of our export trade. Whatever industrial development there will be, will have to depend entirely on the home market.’ Another reason to back planning, for Birla, was that it helped to stave off the possibility of a communist revolution. Indian planners should guard against runaway wealth inequalities, he argued. The reason New Deal policies of redistribution were not resented in America was because even the rich knew that it was ultimately in their interest. There was ‘no surer method of inviting Bolshevism, communism, and anarchism than to create an unhealthy disparity’ in society. Planning was desirable even if it entailed new and seemingly onerous taxes because it was in the interest of the masses as well as of businessmen. ‘No one’, he added, ‘can grumble at this’.20

In February 1938, Bose, the newly elected Congress president – bespectacled, clad in kurta, dhoti, embroidered shawl, and Gandhi cap – addressed a crowd, also in white khadi caps, from a stage in Haripura. Set in Gujarat’s countryside, the meeting’s public art projected rural themes. On display were hundreds of vividly painted village scenes designed by an artist handpicked by Gandhi.21 Even the nationalist flag that had been ceremonially hoisted displayed a charkha (spinning wheel) at the tricolour’s heart. But during the speech, Bose expressed some decidedly un-rustic ideas. He spoke of the need for a ‘socialistic’ solution to India’s problems through a ‘planning commission’ that would begin a ‘comprehensive scheme of industrial development under state ownerships and state control’. A return to the pre-industrial era was no longer possible. It was a motif in several of his talks that year.

Occupied by these concerns, Bose established a National Planning Committee to generate momentum in advance of freedom’s arrival. He offered the top job over telegram to Nehru, a colleague and comrade who was then in London. Following up, he wrote a tender letter addressed to ‘My dear Jawahar’, while aboard a train from Bombay to Calcutta. It concluded with a plea: ‘I hope you will accept the Chairmanship of the Planning Committee. You must if it is to be a success. Love, Yours affectionately Subhas.’22

Although led by Nehru and managed by the London School of Economics-trained socialist economist K. T. Shah, the fifteen-member committee was no leftist club. It included four industrialists, five scientists, three economists, a representative of labour, and one sceptical Gandhian. Gandhi himself looked askance. In a handwritten note to Nehru, he conveyed that he had ‘never been able to understand or appreciate the labours of the committee’.23 Rabindranath Tagore, the Nobel-winning litterateur of flowing beard and robe, was much more enthusiastic. The distance between these elder statesmen on economic matters was expected. As Nehru would write when imprisoned years later, Tagore was ‘the aristocratic artist, turned democrat with proletarian sympathies’, and Gandhi was ‘a man of the people, almost the embodiment of the Indian peasant’ representing ‘renunciation and asceticism’.24 Tagore reached out to Nehru to say that, after a long discussion with astrophysicist and committee member Meghnad Saha about planning, he was now ‘convinced about its importance’.25 His secretary followed up a few days later; Gurudeva (Tagore) was ‘rather captivated’ by the idea of planning and wanted to meet Nehru to emphasize the urgency of the National Planning Committee’s work. Underlining Gurudeva’s distance from the Mahatma, the secretary also revealed that Tagore wanted a ‘modernist’ to be elected Congress president the following year. Tagore believed that ‘there are only two genuine modernists in the High Command – you (Nehru) and Subhasbabu’. The poet sought to get Bose re-elected as leader of the Congress because avant-garde ideas like planning needed backing so that the committee’s recommendations ‘would be warmly accepted by the All India Congress and not just shelved’.26

The National Planning Committee’s office was housed, often rent-free, in a succession of Bombay’s architectural landmarks. It started out in the Venetian-Gothic Secretariat building, then shifted to the Neoclassical Town Hall before departing to the ground floor of the Gothic Bombay University building. After the war, J. R. D. Tata made room for them in the Art Deco property of his insurance company, the New India Assurance Building. The committee survived on grants from Congress ministries in different states, donations by Indian businessmen, and loans from K. T. Shah and Tata. In recognition of his contribution, Tata was even invited to two meetings of the planning committee.27

From its very first meeting, the committee’s deliberations were marred by elbowing between industrialists, socialists, and Gandhians on questions such as the extent of state control and the relative roles of factories and cottage industries. In a letter to a friend in 1939, Nehru wrote about the work he was doing in Bombay with the National Planning Committee, describing it as ‘hard and exhausting business’ on account of the sparring within. He could not leave even for a day, he rued, because in his absence it would descend into dysfunction.28 Nehru played peacemaker and the creation of myriad subcommittees delayed the inevitable collisions. Barely had the work begun when World War II, the Quit India movement, and the colonial backlash of mass incarceration brought it to a screeching halt. It was hard to make progress when several members, including Nehru, were in prison.

During World War II, the colonial state dramatically expanded in size engaging in wartime controls that most observers recognized as forms of economic planning.29 The colonial government began to argue that some of these controls would need to be maintained even in the future when transitioning back to a peacetime economy. Besides such considerations, there was the matter of optics. In a volatile political context, where it was increasingly apparent that decolonization of some sort was imminent, colonial administrators were keen to mirror nationalist thinking wherever possible. By this point, colonial policies could only gain traction among the Indian elite if it could appear to ‘dress itself in nationalist colours, and in addition to accept socialism’.30 The resultant Planning and Development Department produced a report that echoed the National Planning Committee in its emphasis on industrialization, interventionism, and protectionism.31

The medicine prescribed in the colonies was the same one that war-torn Britain opted for itself. The surprising results of the 1945 elections threw Winston Churchill’s Conservative government out of power in London, replacing it with a Labour Party led by Clement Attlee. The Labour manifesto had railed against ‘anti-planners’ whose ‘desire to sweep away public controls’ to favour war-profiteers and the wealthy. Planning, it suggested, contrasted with ‘the chaos of economic do-as-they-please anarchy’. The programme included public ownership of major sectors of the economy, especially ‘basic industries’ including iron and steel, inland transportation, fuel, and power. The manifesto did not shy away from its political implications either: ‘The Labour Party is a Socialist Party, and proud of it’. The government at the apex of the British Empire was declaring its belief in a planned economy.

As the war drew to a close, planning was the flavour of the season in India as well. Across the ideological gamut, almost everyone seemed to have developed a taste for it and their own unique recipes. Birla was once again a vociferous champion, this time in a pamphlet on planning, which endorsed state monopoly of key industries, continued economic controls, and wide-reaching centralized coordination.32 In 1944, in particular, plans abounded. Apart from the colonial state’s own report on planning, Indians were introduced to the industrialists’ Bombay Plan, the communist M. N. Roy’s People’s Plan, the Muslim League’s own Planning Committee, and a Gandhian Plan with a foreword by Gandhi.33 The best publicized of this crop, the Bombay Plan, was one sponsored by prominent businessmen, including magnates like J. R. D. Tata, Birla, Purshotamdas Thakurdas, and Lala Shri Ram.34 Many of them were donors to the Congress’ National Planning Committee. It germinated in a Tata boardroom and was primarily authored by John Matthai, a Malayali economist and government employee turned Tata adviser. The Bombay Plan or Tata–Birla Plan, as it came to be known, tipped its hat to the National Planning Committee’s role as pioneers and frankly stated the need for planning and an extensive role for the government in an independent Indian economy. In its details, and in its backers’ interest, the document made sure to highlight the need to shield domestic industries from foreign competition, carefully contoured the state’s role in the economy, and nodded in the direction of addressing extreme wealth disparities.

There is debate over how enthusiastic these industrialists really were about economic planning. Some scholars view the Bombay Plan as evidence of industrialists’ belief in state-led capitalist development and their support for centralized economic planning (provided it walled off overseas competitors). It was the result of a moment of nationalist optimism and widespread belief in statist economic arrangements – a phase when the interests of businessmen overlapped with that of the party leading the anti-colonial charge. Unconvinced of this, others have argued that it was a defensive rearguard action by capitalists who wanted to push the conversation away from some of the more properly socialist positions within the Indian National Congress. While they certainly appreciated being sheltered from foreign competition, they were not genuinely on board with the state regulation that planning entailed. The point of the Bombay Plan, in this view, was for businessmen to make a public show of their patriotism and commitment to broadly equitable development. This helped ingratiate them with the nationalist leadership and, by using the jargon of plans and state control in limited sectors, erect a bulwark against radical or stridently socialistic policies.35

The Indian National Congress, for its part, imagined development as above politics. So defined, it became possible to settle political debates without recourse to politics. By assigning the choice of economic strategy to a planning organization – a body of experts – thorny questions could be ironed out quietly and without referring them to popular opinion. For instance, the debate between Gandhians and socialist modernizers such as Bose and Nehru about the desirability of mechanized industrialization was solved, according to Partha Chatterjee, by ‘constituting planning as a domain outside the “squabbles and conflicts of politics”’.36 More broadly, as Jawaharlal Nehru looked ahead to independence, he saw (or hoped for) a state in which politics itself would be dwarfed by the work of development. Plans were to be the chief priority and politics was to shrink to the role of mere administration. Development would be the narrative of independent India.37 To India’s first prime minister, planning was a refuge: ‘something apart from what might be called political ideologies and political conflicts’.38

As the British hastily departed from a fractured subcontinent, independent India set out to fulfil a promise it had made through decades of anticolonial struggle – sparking the national economy. To that end, in March 1950, the Planning Commission was created. An official body based in New Delhi, its chairperson was the prime minister and it included cabinet ministers like the Minister of Finance, senior bureaucrats, and invited experts.39 The mission was to plan the Indian economy and steer it through successive Five-Year Plans. India instituted a mixed economy: a large public sector in which the Planning Commission controlled investment decisions and resource allocation as well as a much larger economy of private enterprise, heavily regulated by controls and licences.

Officially, the commission was an advisory body. In the months leading up to its establishment, some of those involved in the process – like Gandhian labour leader Gulzarilal Nanda and the Congress Working Committee – tried to push for a stronger version, one with more muscle in relation to the ministries and bearing enforcement authority. These proposals were quashed in the cabinet by Deputy Prime Minister Vallabhbhai Patel and other concerned ministers, some of whom feared a reaction from business leaders.40 While the cabinet’s decision limited the Planning Commission’s purview, the issue refused to go away. In the summer of 1950, the body’s powers became a national controversy when Finance Minister John Matthai resigned, publicly rebuking the government for treating the Commission as a ‘parallel cabinet’ to which the ministries would have to bend the knee.41

The prime minister scrambled to douse the fire. The threat to the Planning Commission’s legitimacy, so soon after its birth, worried Nehru enough for him to make it the subject of his public addresses. Soon after another interview in which Matthai aired grievances, Nehru was in the former minister’s home state of Kerala (Travancore-Cochin at the time). To a packed, rain-soaked crowd in Trivandrum University’s stadium, he downplayed their differences and promised that the Commission did not reflect an authoritarian bent. Either the subject was not enough of a popular issue or the audience was composed of fans because the event concluded with the crowd surging to the rostrum in a ‘mighty ovation’ and carrying the prime minister on their shoulders to his car.42 It is an episode that captures how the Planning Commission rode the wave of Nehru’s popularity. Despite Nehru’s placations, though, the question of relative powers would bubble up repeatedly in the following years.

Even with the rocky start, the body wielded enormous power. Its potency stemmed from its authority to draw up an economic roadmap for the country and back it with all the resources and policy instruments available to the Government of India. The presence of both the prime minister and senior Cabinet officials (like the finance minister) as members meant that its recommendations to ministries or state governments acquired the unofficial stamp of Cabinet approval. For much of the 1950s, there were also other significant overlaps in key personnel between the Union Government and the Planning Commission that shored up the latter’s writ. For example, the chief economic advisor at the Ministry of Finance was also the head of the Economics Division at the Commission.43 The Cabinet Secretary performed the duties of Principal Secretary to the Planning Commission as well.44

Figure 0.1. Planning Commission meeting on 1 June 1952. Nehru is in the centre with C. D. Deshmukh to his right. Gulzarilal Nanda and Tarlok Singh are to Nehru’s left.

Photo by James Burke, Life.

The language of Plans quickly became pervasive in the lives of Indian citizens. In a Shankar’s Weekly cartoon from May 1950, a range of plans crowd the frame: a Defence Plan in the form of a canon, a Congress Plan and Economic Plan as flying carpets, a Rehabilitation Plan in the shape of a tent sheltering people huddled beneath, and a Transport Plan as a human cannonball. There is even a Plan for Plans, depicted as a potted plant sprouting numerous other plans. Alongside these were less ambitious plans – a Children’s Plan, Daughter’s Plan, Wife’s Plan, Shopping Plan, and a Plan for an Evening Out. As the artist dryly concluded, ‘there is nobody without a plan’.45

Figure 0.2. Poking fun at the Government’s enthusiasm for plans and popular participation.

Cartoon by Shankar in Shankar’s Weekly (7 May 1950).

Between the atom bomb dropping on Hiroshima and the fall of the Berlin Wall, planning stalked the global policy landscape. Far from an Indian oddity, it drew legitimacy from an international push during World War II, spilling over into a transnational planning moment in the middle decades of the twentieth century. Varying combinations of planning, protectionism, and state-led democratic development were being fused with anti-imperialism and the fight against the perceived threat of neocolonialism.46 Economist Lionel Robbins recognized the deep historical links between disintegrating empires and planning. To him, as one historian put it, decolonization and planning were both ‘formally homologous and structurally reinforcing’.47 Even outside the command economies of China and the Soviet Union, plans and planning bodies were found in far flung nations – from South Korea, Japan, Vietnam, and Malaysia in East Asia to France, Mexico, and Argentina in the western hemisphere to Ghana, Sudan, and Tanzania in Africa. By 1965, thirty-five African nations had development plans. Observing the ‘very ubiquity of development plans’, one economist wrote that African states, including those with conservative governments, saw ‘economic planning as a logical historical development from the independence effort’.48 Another remarked that during the 1960s in Africa, ‘“having a plan” became almost a sine qua non of political independence’.49 A historian of development corroborated that observation, writing of the 1950s and 1960s: ‘development concepts, however different their details, shared a faith in the state as an actor and in planning as a method, making it tempting to describe the history of development as a history of planning’.50 In those mid-century decades, planning represented a spectrum of statist economic arrangements rather than specific policies – seemingly applicable across totalitarian regimes, social democracies, and welfare states. Significantly, though, unlike in communist USSR and China, there were hard limits to the state’s power in democratic India. Planning would have to be done differently here.

***

The challenges faced in writing histories of independent India are captured by how difficult it is to access Nehru’s unpublished papers during his term as prime minister. When I conducted the research for this book, I had to seek special permission from a legal heir of Nehru. At the time, that was the office of Sonia Gandhi, then the Congress Party president. In late 2014, Sonia Gandhi waived this requirement. However, scholars still have to petition no less than the Prime Minister’s Office for permission, where such requests are assessed on a case-by-case basis.51

During visits to the National Archives of India, I was surprised to find a fragmentary and insubstantial collection of documents on planning – wholly incommensurate with the influence wielded by the Planning Commission. The shelves of the Planning Commission or Yojana Bhavan Library were also stacked with dusty volumes of books and pamphlets, but none of the departmental files or correspondence that feature prominently in the historian’s diet. A high-ranking former member of the Planning Commission had no answer either; on the contrary, it took him by surprise. The likely explanation is grim. As another scholar who pursued this missing cache of documents reluctantly concluded – despite leveraging contacts in ministerial offices and accessing documentary stashes at various ministries – it is probable that ‘most old files had simply been thrown away or burned’ because ‘after a point, clerks decided to simply destroy them’.52 The path around this gaping absence in the government’s own archival records is to triangulate using private papers, correspondence, periodicals, and memoirs available at numerous archives in India, Britain, and the United States.

Despite the knots, historians are untangling the decades following the fateful ‘stroke of the midnight hour’ on 15 August 1947. Given the cataclysmic nature of Partition, with its unprecedented migrations and frenzied violence, it is natural that this has attracted the most historical attention.53 The years following this are still mainly the province of political scientists, anthropologists, and economists – with historians recently making more frequent forays.54 Wide-ranging surveys of the postcolonial period have helped to define the broad contours of the Nehruvian state and consolidated our understanding of it.55 This was nearly a two-decade phase following independence during which Nehru – the most prominent leader in a Congress party that held power in New Delhi and most state capitals – was prime minister, and that saw the establishment of a constitutional democracy with a powerful centre, a planned economy, and non-aligned Cold War foreign policy. There has now been a new wave of historical scholarship on the Nehruvian state, coinciding with and possibly influenced by, the drastic downturn in the electoral fortunes of the party to which Jawaharlal Nehru belonged.56

Studies of planning in India, however, have been dominated by social scientists. Some of these were near contemporary accounts, often technical and dating back decades. A few were by scholars who were involved in the planning process themselves.57 Since then, works by political scientists and economists have fruitfully explored questions of political economy, state capacity, growth strategy, and outcomes.58 While undoubtedly valuable, these accounts have their limitations. This literature has little to say about the fundamental tension between Indian planning’s technocratic nature and its aspirations for public participation. What they miss are explanations of how planning was used to legitimate the state, how the language of planning infused popular culture, and what the entire project of ‘democratic planning’ was. We also do not know enough about how planning shaped the Nehruvian state – the knowledge infrastructure undergirding it, debates within the Commission and between it and other ministries, and the relationship with global expertise and the Cold War.

Over the last few decades, historians have begun to address these themes.59 Medha Kudaisya and Benjamin Zachariah contributed analyses of the ideology, institutional conflicts, and policy choices involved in economic planning from its interwar beginnings.60 Vivek Chibber and Nasir Tyabji have examined the relationship between capitalists and the state during the Nehruvian era.61 David Engerman has made a landmark intervention in the study of Cold War development politics, exposing how foreign aid from America and the Soviet Union shaped debates between competing economic visions in India.62 This book, by contrast, addresses a different set of themes. It steps away from policy content and high politics – the ebb and flow of the Five-Year Plans themselves – first, to reveal how the data infrastructure necessary to mount Plans (through statistics and computers) significantly shaped the development of the state itself; and, second, to uncover how planning functioned as a mode of political legitimation (through the project of democratic planning).

Among more theoretical analyses of Indian development and planning, Partha Chatterjee’s is especially noteworthy.63 In an oft-cited essay, he argued that planning functioned as a mechanism by which experts outside the political sphere could settle political debate and policy disagreements.64 He also identified a tension between ‘rational’ planning and the less reason-driven realm of politics, despite which planning needed representative politics to be legitimate, and politicians needed planning to paper over conflicting economic visions. Deeply perceptive, the essay is also predominantly theoretical, given its focus on capital accumulation and the ‘passive revolution’ of capital.

This book builds on those insights by demonstrating how these dynamics operated in practice, and their effects on the state and its stance towards citizens. I anchor this analysis in a set of specific contexts – national statistics, computers, organizations such as the government’s Song and Drama Division, and voluntary bodies such as the Bharat Sadhu Samaj. The initial chapters address the ways in which experts and expertise shaped the contours of state power. The desire for planning to be data-driven quickly led to the installation of new intellectual infrastructures. Hence, those most capable of navigating this domain of data – technocrats and scientific institutions – were further legitimized, embedded, and empowered within the state.

The latter part of this book responds to Chatterjee’s brief observation about the opposition between the rational science of planning and the political pressures of representation, and the necessary ‘paradox’ of their coexistence. It does so through an exploration of the government’s democratic planning campaign – an experiment that represented a new political ideology and different path in the Cold War. These chapters explore how the Nehruvian state was conscious of the tension between technocracy and democracy but tried to portray them as essentially compatible. In fact, it sought to creatively resolve this seeming paradox through the ideology and rhetoric of democratic planning. Despite shielding planning from politics as much as it could, the government still wanted to advertise a technocratic process as fundamentally democratic. Focusing on the rhetoric of ‘democratic planning’ and ‘Plan-consciousness’ – while remaining sceptical of its claims – I investigate the programmes launched and contortions necessary to make that pitch.

Looking beyond the subcontinent, this story is entangled in the global arc of twentieth-century ideas of development and the Cold War.65 Instead of tracing the reach of foreign influence, the narrative that follows places a Third World site – India – at the centre and looks outward. Expertise did not just radiate benevolently from western capitals to poorer nations; the sources of new disciplinary knowledge were polycentric and its motivations complex. While India was a recipient of expertise from abroad, several of the most influential individuals and institutions were home- grown. They made their own contributions to the body of knowledge on economic development – for example, in the design of sample surveys, and in demonstrating the utility of extensive household surveys to measuring national living standards and poverty.66

* * *

In Part I, I trace the creation of a modern social scientific and technological framework to undergird India’s aspirations for development. Planning necessitated state efforts in quantitative description and numerical mastery of the economy, which provoked rapid growth in the government’s knowledge infrastructure. The installation of a national statistical grid, and the pursuit of newly invented computer technology, were responses to the need for the legibility that planning required in the economic realm. This apparatus was crucial to governing the economy. Providing the numbers that could stand in for the nation, planning contributed to defining the national economy, making it more visible to the state and more amenable to intervention. As sociologist Michael Mann has argued, modern democratic states operate through ‘infrastructural power’, which enable them to implement political choices and organize the economic realm.67 In India, we see the flexing of such power, in the erection of a vast data complex. A thread that runs through the initial chapters is the figure of P. C. Mahalanobis and the Indian Statistical Institute (ISI). Their shared narrative illustrates the argument of Part I – that planning catalysed a hunger for data that led to a swelling of the state’s knowledge capacities, with consequences for policymaking at the highest level. Further, they underscored the technocratic mode in which planning operated within the postcolonial state.

Chapter 1 reveals how India’s statistical infrastructure was built and establishes its link to planning. I track the early career of Mahalanobis and the institution he founded in Calcutta (the Indian Statistical Institute) to describe the ascent of statistics as an academic discipline in India, and its growing association with applied economics. This was the period that produced organizations such as the Central Statistical Organization and the National Sample Survey, both of which persist and remain significant to policymaking. It was during this phase that India first began periodic assessments of national income (a precursor to Gross Domestic Product (GDP)) and nationwide sample surveys that delivered high-definition snapshots of the economy. The chapter argues that this national statistical framework – pioneering among developing nations and a global trailblazer in large sample surveys – emerged as a response to the quantitative needs of centralized economic planning.

The next chapter lays out how this planning-induced expansion in the state’s capacities led to the formalization of planning’s relationship with statistics. Changes at both the Planning Commission and the Indian Statistical Institute bear witness to this. It placed a statistician and a statistical institute in a position where they could, in turn, shape Plans. Chapter 2 traces a boomerang’s arc: planning’s influence on statistics led to statistics’ influence on planning. It explains how the Indian Statistical Institute transitioned from a small scholarly body in the outskirts of Calcutta and on the fringes of mainstream academia in the 1930s, to a nodal agency in Indian economic planning by the mid-1950s. And it describes the way in which Mahalanobis used the close proximity of national statistics and economic planning at this moment to carve a position for himself at the Planning Commission. This culminated in him and the Institute drafting India’s pivotal Second Five-Year Plan (1956–1961), the economic blueprint for decades thereafter. The tactics used included courting experts on both sides of the Iron Curtain and developing the Institute as a destination to host a stream of foreign economists, statisticians, and policy experts to burnish its profile. The very possibility that a statistician could transform into an economic planner reveals the wide latitude granted to experts and expertise in a technocratic state.

The burst of information generated by new statistical projects made the question of calculation paramount. The mass of data that the National Sample Survey yielded and the increasing complexity of planning models made the state’s data processing needs evident. Chapter 3 reveals the campaign to bring India its first computers. Unlike other parts of the world, computers were not sought for military purposes in India. Instead, India pursued them because they were seen as a solution to central planning’s most knotty puzzle, that of big data. The chapter follows the decade-long quest to import computers from the United States, Europe, and the USSR, unearthing the Cold War politics in which it inevitably became embroiled. Overall, Part I demonstrates the building of a technocratic, data-hungry, high-modernist state and its attempts to make the economic realm more legible.68

Pivoting from the capacity-building side of India’s planning story, the second half of Planning Democracy explores the government’s unsuccessful efforts at reconciling that technocracy with democracy. The Indian state did this by billing its political project as ‘democratic planning’. The project was meant to define Indian nationhood, citizenship, and a path between capitalist democracy and authoritarian command economies. Caught in the crosshairs of a global Cold War, India responded through non-aligned foreign policy and its domestic counterpart – the combination of liberal democratic institutions and centralized economic planning. By expecting citizens to participate in this, the government was not simply asking for their consent on an economic policy; it was also beseeching citizens to step up to the task of building a new kind of state through mass participation (and sharing the blame for failure). During the Nehruvian period, the most expansive social vision for planning was to fashion a productive and informed citizenry and build a movement towards the Plan’s fulfilment. Even when deployed as propaganda, the message of democratic planning was significant to the government as a mode of legitimation and a means of Plan fulfilment. After all, given the state’s limited capacity during this period, voluntary efforts by citizens were simply necessary if the economy was to grow in accordance to the Plans’ timetable.

In Chapter 4, I chart the Indian government’s ambition to make planning democratic by convincing its citizenry of the need for planning and securing their participation. The government sought to spur grassroots enthusiasm by planting it – a campaign that was self-undermining by its very nature. It examines why public participation in planning mattered to the Indian government and uncovers the many channels through which the state sought to spread the gospel of planning. The means employed by government to instil ‘Plan-consciousness’ included publicity teams on bullock carts and boats, a Khushwant Singh-edited Plan magazine named Yojana, plays by leading Hindi playwrights like Ramesh Mehta, musical and drama troupes, and state propaganda films screened for mass audiences through the Films Division. The chapter concludes with a discussion of how this Plan-consciousness even seeped into commercial Hindi cinema or Bollywood.

If democratic planning was to become a mass movement, as the government hoped, it would require the voluntary participation of Indian citizens. In Chapter 5, I examine how, in the absence of spontaneous participation, the state supported voluntary organizations to spread the message of the Five-Year Plans and offered services towards their fulfilment. It analyses the paradox of the state intervening to stimulate voluntary support for its policies. The chapter traces efforts to involve youths through College and University Planning Forums, and other social groups through the Bharat Sewak Samaj (Service to India Society). It also analyses a curious experiment – the enigmatic Bharat Sadhu Samaj (Indian Society of Ascetics). A brainchild of Gulzarilal Nanda, the devout Minister of Planning, its goal was to publicize the Plans using Hinduism as a resource. The attempt revealed how the Nehruvian state propagated Five-Year Plans – the very symbol of secular technocracy and scientific modernity – using saffron-robed Hindu monks and ascetics. The long-term fallout of this project was the Sadhu Samaj’s drift towards Hindu nationalism. Ultimately, this religious venture underlines the awkward relationship and largely failed wedding of the technocratic and democratic dimensions of planning.

The book concludes with a discussion of the gradual decline of the Planning Commission’s potency from the late 1960s, culminating in its eventual demise in 2014, despite one political party promising to resurrect it from the dead. Through this period, economic planning remained fundamental to how the Indian economy functioned, even as the Planning Commission steadily shed powers it once enjoyed to other arms of government. While the Planning Commission diminished, the knowledge and data infrastructures it had helped to create endured. It remained the basis of policymaking at the highest levels – unless, as is increasingly the case, it revealed governments in an unflattering light. Independent India’s search for technocratic solutions to economic problems continues, as does the challenge of fusing technocracy to democracy.

Figure 0

Figure 0.1. Planning Commission meeting on 1 June 1952. Nehru is in the centre with C. D. Deshmukh to his right. Gulzarilal Nanda and Tarlok Singh are to Nehru’s left.

Photo by James Burke, Life.
Figure 1

Figure 0.2. Poking fun at the Government’s enthusiasm for plans and popular participation.

Cartoon by Shankar in Shankar’s Weekly (7 May 1950).

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Introduction
  • Nikhil Menon, University of Notre Dame, Indiana
  • Book: Planning Democracy
  • Online publication: 24 March 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009043892.001
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Introduction
  • Nikhil Menon, University of Notre Dame, Indiana
  • Book: Planning Democracy
  • Online publication: 24 March 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009043892.001
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Introduction
  • Nikhil Menon, University of Notre Dame, Indiana
  • Book: Planning Democracy
  • Online publication: 24 March 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009043892.001
Available formats
×