Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-t5tsf Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T11:14:26.621Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

10 - Should marketing boards stabilise prices through forward purchases?

from Part Three - Risk and adjustment

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2010

L. Alan Winters
Affiliation:
University of Birmingham
Get access

Summary

Stabilisation or hedging

The focus of discussion in international commodity policy in the decade immediately following the first OPEC price rise in 1973–4 was the negotiation of international commodity agreements (ICAs), in particular under the auspices of the UNCTAD Integrated Programme for Commodities. This process was almost totally unsuccessful, in part because the debate between the developed and the developing countries became politicised, and in part because the developed countries suspected, with some justice, that the so-called New International Economic Order (NIEO) would involve a move away from markets. The objective of stabilising prices at a level which was ‘fair to consumers and remunerative to producers’ suggested that these prices were likely to be higher on average than those which had prevailed under free market conditions.

Developed country suspicions about price stabilising agreements were enhanced by the performance of those agreements which were already operating. Five agreements were in place during this period, although not all were operational all the time. Two (cocoa and sugar) were completely ineffective. The coffee agreement was widely perceived as primarily a price-raising agreement – a coffee OPEC but both enforced and moderated by consumer representation. The tin agreement, which could claim a long history of successful stabilisation, was under-resourced in the 1980s and committed to defending what became (through the appreciation of the dollar) an absurdly high price – its spectacular collapse in 1985 was seen by many as the death knell of international stabilisation. Only the natural rubber agreement, the sole child of the UNCTAD programme, functioned reasonably efficiently.

Type
Chapter
Information
Open Economies
Structural Adjustment and Agriculture
, pp. 222 - 239
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×