Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dk4vv Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T21:02:57.613Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false
This chapter is part of a book that is no longer available to purchase from Cambridge Core

4 - Reputation

Sheryllynne Haggerty
Affiliation:
University of Nottingham
Get access

Summary

As to asking an Anticipation on a Cargo Not Arrived, we would sooner have our Bills protested.

If there was one clear signal to start asking questions about a merchant's financial viability, it was one of their bills of exchange being protested for non-payment. This usually meant that the payer did not have enough funds with the drawee, and whilst this did not necessarily mean the payer was insolvent, it certainly started rumours. Joshua Johnson noted in 1771 that Hanbury & Co. had protested Barnes & Ridgate's bills, which had hurt their credit. A merchant's ability to get credit was so tied up with reputation, that it was his reputation, hence the term credibility. Credit was an ‘intensely social fact’ [emphasis in original], but also an emotive one. A reputation could take years to construct, yet a small piece of gossip, a sniff of scandal, a rumour of a bill protested, and the merchant's reputation could be deconstructed in seconds. As William Gordon noted in 1763, ‘a merchant ought constantly to have in view, the support of his personal credit, which if is but once blown upon, is not without great difficulty achieved’.

It is therefore very unlikely that William Wilson in the quotation above would really sooner have had his bills protested. His correspondent in Philadelphia, Arthur Jones, had asked him about the prospects of a cargo of wheat he was sending to Wilson at Alexandria (Virginia). Wilson was not prepared to comment in advance for fear that he would be wrong and his judgment subsequently questioned.

Type
Chapter
Information
'Merely for Money'?
Business Culture in the British Atlantic, 1750–1815
, pp. 97 - 131
Publisher: Liverpool University Press
Print publication year: 2012

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×