from PART I - THE GLORIOUS REVOLUTION AND THE ENGLISH STATE
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 05 May 2016
As noted in Chapter 1, North and Weingast's thesis that property rights became more secure after the Glorious Revolution has been disputed by subsequent scholars investigating rates of return on capital assets. In this chapter, I begin by reviewing their evidence.
I then consider when monopoly brokerage of property rights developed, showing that key elements emerged in the thirteenth century. After this point, enforcement of domestic property rights should have been reasonably secure. Thus, unlike North and Weingast, I do not predict an across-the-board improvement in property rights at the Revolution.
That said, some kinds of property were not governed by the system of monopoly brokerage built up around the common-law courts. First, the conciliar courts had long competed for litigation over foreign trading rights (Jha 2012; Harris 2013). Second, rights to develop property had long been conferred in a duopolistic market, with both courtiers and parliamentarians vying for business (Bogart 2005, 2011a; Bogart and Richardson 2011). In each of these markets, the Revolution marked a watershed.
Rates of Return on English Property
To assess North and Weingast's claim that property rights became more secure after the Revolution, Clark argues as follows. First, insecure private property rights tend “to deter investment in capital … unless the return on capital rises sufficiently to compensate for the enhanced risk” (1996 p. 566). Thus, second, if property rights became more secure after the Glorious Revolution, one should see a decline in the rate of return on capital. But, third, no such decline appears in the historical record.
To establish his third point, Clark examines a large sample of charities’ assets – such as land, tithes, houses, rent charges, and private bonds – over the period 1540–1837. Looking for correlations between political events and rates of return, he finds none in the seventeenth century, and concludes as follows: “Secure private property rights existed in England at least as early as 1600, and probably much earlier. As far as most private investors were concerned, nothing special happened in 1688 or, for that matter, in any period between 1600 and 1688” (p. 565).
Quinn undertakes a detailed study of a prominent London banker's portfolio before and after the Revolution. He finds that the Revolution “seems to have raised, not lowered, rates on private debt” (2001, p. 593).
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.