Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-fbnjt Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-03T00:56:09.144Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - Seasonal fluctuations and social division of labour: rural linen production in the Osnabrück and Bielefeld regions and the urban woollen industry in the Niederlausitz, c. 1770–c. 1850

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  16 October 2009

Jürgen Schlumbohm
Affiliation:
Max-Planck-Institut für Geschichte, Göttingen
Michael Sonenscher
Affiliation:
King's College, Cambridge
Get access

Summary

Seasonal fluctuations have been assumed to be one of the main characteristics of pre-industrial production processes. The rhythms of climate and the seasons regulated the economic cycle of societies dominated by agriculture. Natural rhythms rather than time discipline determined the flow of work. And the chronic imbalance of labour supply between the peak and slack times of the year are said to have limited production possibilities. Modern industry has been associated with regularity, continuity and, ultimately, the elimination of fluctuation in output caused by man or nature. A recent version of this characteristic division between traditional and modern societies has been set out by Franklin Mendels: ‘We can thus consider primitive agriculture and the assembly line as the end points of a linear evolution marked by a progressively increasing continuity and intensity of work over the centuries, an approach that makes it easier to place “proto-industrialisation” in its proper perspective.’

This essay demonstrates the extent to which this dichotomy and the notion of linear evolution are far too simple. Different regions manifested different production cycles and seasonal fluctuations which do not necessarily accord with what we think about their relative ‘progress’ or backwardness. Another characteristic separating modern from traditional production processes is supposed to have been the degree of social division of labour. But in the cases studied in this paper we notice that as late as around 1800 a very low degree of social division of labour in a region could be regarded as an economic advantage; and only from the point of view of capitalist industrialisation did it seem self-evident that ‘modernisation’ meant a growing division of labour.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1983

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×