from Part III - Elections, Parties and Political Competition
Published online by Cambridge University Press: 05 February 2018
In Liberia's 1927 election, C.D.B. King, the candidate of the True Whig Party, faced T.J.R. Faulkner, the opposition leader of the People's Party. It was a lopsided victory for the incumbent True Whigs, as their candidate won an official tally of 243,000 votes, compared to just 9,000 for the People's Party. There was just one problem. Formal rules on voter eligibility were so strict that only 15,000 people were legally allowed to cast ballots in Liberia by 1927 (Kieh Jr. 2003: 202). The election was certainly rigged. Either each eligible voter had cast an average of seventeen ballots apiece (and most of them in favour of the True Whigs), or hundreds of thousands of ineligible voters were allowed to vote.
It is no surprise that African elections in 1927 were arenas of competition that had little regard for formal rules. Such events are rare today. Increased importance has been given to formal electoral laws, although official regulations are certainly not ironclad guarantors of electoral behaviour. Degrees of electoral manipulation were commonplace in the intervening decades – throughout the era of paternalistic colonialism, ‘Big Men’ and one-party states, and finally the third wave of democracy that swept across the continent in the 1990s (Huntington 1991). There are endless examples of African elites contravening electoral institutions in order to illegitimately gain an upper hand (Chaturvedi 2005; Calingaert 2006; Aalen and Tronvoll 2009; Beaulieu and Hyde 2009; Collier and Vincente 2012; Cheeseman 2015). However, the interaction between formal and informal rules is markedly different than it was when the True Whigs blatantly stole an election with an obviously implausible vote tally. Today, only amateurs steal elections by brazenly breaking the law.
In this chapter, I aim to demonstrate how African electoral manipulation has shifted into a new realm of ‘strategic rigging’, whereby incumbents may bend, re-interpret or change election laws, but always with a critical focus on being perceived as democratic, and in accordance with codified institutions. Elite behaviour in response to institutional change provides an important insight into the role of formal political institutions in Africa: institutions constrain elite action, but may also incentivise new forms of rule-bending or -breaking, in pursuit of the same goals – such as new, but no less insidious, forms of manipulation.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.