Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-ndw9j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-06T05:01:00.577Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  09 November 2023

François Bourguignon
Affiliation:
École d'économie de Paris and École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris
Jean-Philippe Platteau
Affiliation:
Université de Namur, Belgium

Summary

Type
Chapter
Information
Institutional Challenges at the Early Stages of Development
Lessons from a Multi-Country Study
, pp. 323 - 340
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

References

Abbas, H. (2005). Pakistan’s Drift into Extremism – Allah, the Army, and America’s War on Terror, M.E. Sharpe, New York and London.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D. (2003). Why not a political Coase theorem? Social conflict, commitment, and politics, Journal of Comparative Economics 31, pp. 620–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Johnson, S. (2005). Unbundling institutions. Journal of Political Economy, 113(5), pp. 949–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J. A. (2000). Political losers as a barrier to economic development, American Economic Review 90, pp. 126–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J. A. (2006a). Economic Origins of Dictatorship and Democracy, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J. A. (2006b). Economic backwardness in political perspective, American Political Science Review 100(1), pp. 115–31.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J. A. (2008a). Persistence of power, elites, and institutions, American Economic Review 98(1), pp. 267–93.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J. A. (2008b). The persistence and change of institutions in the Americas, Southern Economic Journal 75(2), pp. 282–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acemoglu, D., and Robinson, J. A. (2012). Why Nations Fail: The Origins of Power, Prosperity and Poverty, Profile Books, London.Google Scholar
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., and Robinson, J. A. (2001). The colonial origins of comparative development: An empirical investigation, American Economic Review 91(5), pp. 1369–401.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. (1976). The economics of caste and of the rat race and other woeful tales, Quarterly Journal of Economics 90(4), pp. 599617.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Akerlof, G. (2017). The importance of legitimacy, The World Bank Economic Review 30(Supplement 1), pp. S157–65.Google Scholar
Aldashev, G., Chaara, I., Platteau, J.-P., and Wahhaj, Z. (2012). Formal law as a magnet to reform custom, Economic Development and Cultural Change 60(1), pp. 795828.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amsden, A. H. (1989). Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Amsden, A. H. (1992). Asia’s Next Giant: South Korea and Late Industrialization, Oxford University Press on Demand, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Anderson, S., François, P., and Kotwal, A. (2015). Clientelism in Indian villages, American Economic Review 105(6), pp. 1780–816.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
André, C., and Platteau, J.-P. (1998). Land relations under unbearable stress: Rwanda caught in the Malthusian trap, Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 34(1), pp. 147.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Aoki, M. (2001). Towards a Comparative Institutional Analysis, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arab News. (2022, 27 March). Japan condemns Houthi attacks on Saudi Arabia’s oil facilities. Arab News. [online], available at: www.arabnews.com/node/2051236/world.Google Scholar
Auriol, E., and Platteau, J.-P. (2017a). The explosive combination of religious decentralisation and autocracy: The case of Islam, Economics of Transition 25(2), pp. 313–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auriol, E., and Platteau, J.-P. (2017b). Religious co-option under autocracy: A theory inspired by history, Journal of Development Economics 127(July), pp. 395412.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auriol, E., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (2021). The Quran and the Sword, EDI Working Paper Series, Oxford Policy Management, Oxford.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1984). The Evolution of Cooperation, Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Axelrod, R. (1997). The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J.-M., and Platteau, J.-P. (1996). Halting Degradation of Natural Resources: Is There a Role for Rural Communities? Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Baland, J.-M., and Platteau, J.-P. (1997). Wealth inequality and efficiency on the commons, Part I: The unregulated case, Oxford Economic Papers 49(3), pp. 451–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J.-M., and Platteau, J.-P. (1998). Wealth inequality and efficiency on the commons, Part II: The regulated case, Oxford Economic Papers 50(1), pp. 122.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (2020). Economic development and institutions: An introduction, in Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Development and Institutions, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford, pp. 120.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Balassa, B. (1988). The lessons of East Asian development: An overview. Economic Development and Cultural Change, 36(S3), S273–S290.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Banerjee, A., and Pande, R. (2007). Parochial Politics: Ethnic Preferences and Politician Corruption, Working Paper, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Bardhan, P., and Mookherjee, D. (2020). Clientelistic politics and economic development: An overview, in Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Development and Institutions, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford, pp. 84102.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bardhan, P., Mitra, S., Mookherjee, D., and Nath, A. (2020). How Do Voters Respond to Welfare vis-a-vis Infrastructure Programs? Evidence for Clientelism in West Bengal, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Barrera, O., Guriev, S., Henry, E., and Zuravskaya, E., (2020). Facts, alternative facts, and fact checking in times of post-truth politics, Journal of Public Economics, 182, pp. 119.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R., and Lee, J. H. (2018). BarroLeeDataSet. [online], available at: www.barrolee.com/.Google Scholar
Basu, K. (2000). Prelude to Political Economy: A Study of the Social and Political Foundations of Economics, Oxford University Press, Oxford.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Basu, K., Jones, E., and Schlicht, E. (1987). The growth and decay of custom: The role of the New Institutional Economics in economic history, Explorations in Economic History 24(1), pp. 121.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bates, R. H. (1989). Beyond the Miracle of the Market: The Political Economy of Agrarian Development in Kenya, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Bauer, P. T., and Yamey, B. S. (1957). The Economics of Under-Developed Countries, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Bayart, J.-F. (1993). The State in Africa: The Politics of the Belly, Pearson Education.Google Scholar
Berry, A., and William, C. (1979). Agrarian Structure and Productivity in Developing Countries, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD and London.Google Scholar
Bertho, F. (2013). Présentation de la Base de Données “Institutional Profiles Database 2012 (IPD 2012)”, Document de Travail de la DG Trésor Cahier 2013/07.Google Scholar
Besley, T., and Coate, S. (1998). Sources of inefficiency in a representative democracy: A dynamic analysis, American Economic Review 88(1), pp. 139–56.Google Scholar
Besley, T., and Persson, T. (2009). The origin of state capacity: Property rights, taxation, and politics, American Economic Review 99(4), pp. 1218–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Besley, T., and Persson, T. (2010). State capacity, conflict, and development, Econometrica 78(1), pp. 134.Google Scholar
Binmore, K. (1992). Funs and Games: A Text on Game Theory, D.C. Heath and Co., Lexington, MA.Google Scholar
Binswanger, H. P., and Rosenzweig, M. R. (1986). Behavioural and material determinants of production relations in agriculture, Journal of Development Studies 22(3), pp. 503–39.Google Scholar
Binswanger, H. P., and McIntire, J. (1987). Behavioural and material determinants of production relations in land-abundant tropical agriculture, Economic Development and Cultural Change 36(1), pp. 7399.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Binswanger, H. P., McIntire, J., and Udry, C. (1989). Production relations in semi-arid African agriculture, in Bardhan, P. (ed), The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp. 122–44.Google Scholar
Bisin, A., and Verdier, T. (2011). The economics of cultural transmission and socialization, in Benhabib, J., Bisin, A., and Jackson, M. O. (eds), The Handbook of Social Economics, Elsevier, vol. 1, pp. 339416.Google Scholar
Bisin, A., and Verdier, T. (2001). The economics of cultural transmission and the dynamics of preferences, Journal of Economic Theory 97, pp. 298319.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bolton, P., and Dewatripont, M. (2005). Contract Theory, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Boserup, E. (1965). The Conditions of Agricultural Growth: The Economics of Agrarian Change under Population Pressure, Allen and Unwin, London.Google Scholar
Boserup, E. (1981). Population and Technology, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Bossavie, L., Görlach, J.-S., Özden, C., and Wang, H. (2021). Temporary Migration for Long-term Investment, Policy Research Working Paper No.9740, World Bank.Google Scholar
Bourguignon, F. (1990). Growth and inequality in the dual model of development: The role of demand factors, The Review of Economic Studies 57(2), pp. 215–28.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F., Houssa, R., Platteau, J-P, and Reding, P. (Eds.) (2023). State Capture and Rent Seeking in Benin, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F., and Platteau, J.-P. (2021a). Should a poverty-averse donor always reward better governance? Economic Journal 131(637), pp. 1919–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F., and Platteau, J.-P. (2021b). Aid Effectiveness: Revisiting the Trade-Off Between Needs and Governance, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Bourguignon, F., and Verdier, T. (2000). Oligarchy, democracy, inequality and growth, Journal of Development Economics 62, pp. 285313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bourguignon, F., and Verdier, T. (2012). The simple analytics of elite behaviour under limited state capacity, in Amsden, A. H., DiCaprio, A., and Robinson, J. A. (eds), The Role of Elites in Economic Development, UNU-WIDER Studies in Development Economics, Oxford University Press, pp. 251–80.Google Scholar
Bourguignon, F., and Wangwe, S. (Eds.) (2023). State and Business in Tanzania’s Development, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowen, J. R. (2003). Islam, Law and Equality in Indonesia – An Anthropology of Public Reasoning, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bowie, A. (1991). Crossing the Industrial Divide: State, Society, and the Politics of Economic Transformation in Malaysia, Columbia University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Bowles, S. (2004). Microeconomics: Behavior, Institutions, and Evolution, Russell Sage Foundation, New York, and Princeton University Press, Princeton.Google Scholar
Brandt, V. S. (1980). The agricultural sector in contemporary South Korea. Asian Affairs: An American Review, 7(3), pp. 182–94.Google Scholar
Broka, C., Guirkinger, C., and Platteau, J.-P. (2021). Rapport des Données Baseline 2020 sur les Contraintes à la Production d’Ananas au Benin, Mimeo, University of Namur, Belgium.Google Scholar
Busia, K.-A. (2020). The Position of the Chief in the Modern Political System of Ashanti: A Study of the Influence of Contemporary Social Changes on Ashanti Political Institutions, Routledge, London (originally published by Oxford University Press, 1951).Google Scholar
Chabal, P., and Daloz, J.-P. (1999). Africa Works: Disorder as Political Instrument, James Currey, Oxford, and Indiana University Press, Bloomington, IN.Google Scholar
Chan, S. (2002). Economic performance and democratic transition: Stylized paradoxes and the Taiwan experience, in Chow, P. C. Y. (ed), Taiwan’s Modernization in Global Perspective, Praeger, Westport, CT and London, pp. 173–93.Google Scholar
Chang, D. (1965). US aid and economic progress in Taiwan, Asian Survey 5(3), pp. 162–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Chaudhury, N., Hammer, J., Kremer, M., Muralidharan, K., and Halsey Rogers, F. (2006). Missing in action: Teacher and health worker absence in developing countries, Journal of Economic Perspectives 20(1), pp. 91116.CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chayanov, A. V. (1966). The Theory of Peasant Economy, Irwin, Homewood, IL.Google Scholar
Cheema., A., Khwaja, A. I., and Qadir, A. (2005). Decentralization in Pakistan: Context, content and causes, Faculty Research Working Papers Series, RWP05-034, Harvard University, John F. Kennedy School of Government.Google Scholar
Cheng, T.-J. (2001). Transforming Taiwan’s economic structure in the 20th century, The China Quarterly 165, pp. 1936.Google Scholar
Cheng, T.-J., and Chu, Y.-H. (2002). State–business relationship in Taiwan: A political economy perspective, in Chow, P. C. Y. (ed), Taiwan’s Modernization in Global Perspective, Praeger, Westport, CT and London, pp. 195214.Google Scholar
Cho, Y. J. (1996). Government intervention, rent distribution and economic development in Korea, in Aoki, M., Kim, H.-K., and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds), The Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development, Oxford University Press and World Bank.Google Scholar
Choo, H., Bark, S. I., and Yoon, S. B. (1996). Korea: Poverty in a tiger country, in Øyen, E., Miller, S. M., and Samad, S. A. (eds), Poverty: A Global Review (Handbook on International Poverty Research), Scandinavian University Press, pp. 8699.Google Scholar
Chow, P. C. Y. (2002). Taiwan’s modernization: Its achievements and challenges, in Chow, P. C. Y. (ed), Taiwan’s Modernization in Global Perspective, Praeger, Westport, CT and London, pp. 328.Google Scholar
Chu, W. W. (1999). Industrial Growth and Small and Medium-Sized Enterprises: The Case of Taiwan, Mimeo, Academia Sinica.Google Scholar
Chun, S.-H. (2018). The Economic Development of South Korea: From Poverty to a Modern Industrial State, Routledge, New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cohen, I., Dal Bo, E., Finan, F., Omala, K., and Schönholzer, D. (2021). Teacher Rotation and Student Outcomes: Experimental Evidence from Uganda, EDI Project, Randomised Control Trials, Working Paper, Oxford Policy Management, Oxford.Google Scholar
Collins, S. and Park, W.-A. (1989). An overview of Korea’s external debt, in Sachs, J., and Collins, S. (eds), Developing Country Debt and Economic Performance, Volume 3: Country Studies – Indonesia, Korea, Philippines, Turkey, University of Chicago Press, Chicago, IL.Google Scholar
Colson, E. (1947). Tradition and Contract: The Problem of Order, Aldine, Chicago, IL.Google Scholar
Corey-Boulet, R. (2019, May 14). As Benin gears up for legislative elections, the opposition is left out. World Politics Review.Google Scholar
Cruz, A., Ferreira, I., Flentø, J., and Tarp, F. (Eds.) (2023). Mozambique at a Fork in the Road, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dal Bo, E., and Finan, F. (2020). At the intersection: A review of institutions in economic development, in Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Development and Institutions, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford, pp. 2383.Google Scholar
Dal Bo, E., Dal Bo, P., and Eyster, E. (2017). The demand for bad policy when voters under appreciate equilibrium effects, The Review of Economic Studies 85(2), pp. 964–98.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, I., and Kanbur, R. (2005). Bridging communal divides: Separation, patronage, integration, in Barrett, C. B. (ed), The Social Economics of Poverty: On Identities, Communities, Groups, and Networks, Routledge, London and New York, pp. 146–70.Google Scholar
Dasgupta, I., and Kanbur, R. (2007). Community and class antagonism, Journal of Public Economics 91, pp. 1816–42.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Davidson, B. (1992). The Black Man’s Burden: Africa and the Curse of the Nation-State, James Currey, Oxford.Google Scholar
Davidson, E., de Santos, A., Lee, Y., Martinez, N., Smith, C., and Tassew, T. (2014). Bangladesh: Inclusive Growth Diagnostic, USAID.Google Scholar
Dawson, J. (1998). Institutions, investment and growth: Nex cross-country and panel data evidence, Economic Inquiry 36, pp. 603–19.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dawson, J. W. (2003). Causality in the freedom–growth relationship. European Journal of Political Economy, 19(3), pp. 479–95.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Delgado, C. L. (1992). Why domestic food prices matter to growth strategy in semi-open West African agriculture, Journal of African Economies 1(3), pp. 446–71.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dercon, S. (ed), (2005). Insurance Against Poverty, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Dercon, S., and Krishnan, P. (1996). Income portfolios in rural Ethiopia and Tanzania: Choices and constraints, Journal of Development Studies 32(6), pp. 850–75.Google Scholar
Devarajan, S., and Khemani, S. (2016). If Politics Is the Problem, How Can External Actors Be Part of the Solution?, Policy Research Working Paper No. WPS7761, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Dewatripont, M., and Roland, G. (1992a). The virtues of gradualism and legitimacy in the transition to a market economy, The Economic Journal 102, pp. 291300.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewatripont, M., and Roland, G. (1992b). Economic reform and dynamic political constraints, Review of Economic Studies 59, pp. 703–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dewatripont, M., and Roland, G. (1995). The design of reform packages under uncertainty, American Economic Review 85(5), pp. 1207–23.Google Scholar
Dincecco, M. (2017). State Capacity and Economic Development, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dincecco, M., and Katz, G. (2016). State capacity and long-run economic performance, Economic Journal 126(590), pp. 189218.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A. (1996). The Making of Economic Policy, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A. (2002). Incentives and organization in the public sector: An interpretative review, Journal of Human Resources 37(4), pp. 696727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A. (2003). Some lessons from transaction–cost politics for less-developed countries, Economics and Politics 15(2), pp. 107–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A. (2004). Lawlessness and Economics: Alternative Modes of Governance, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford.Google Scholar
Dixit, A. (2007). Evaluating recipes for development success, The World Bank Research Observer 22(2), Fall.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Dixit, A. (2018). Anti-corruption institutions: Some history and theory, in Basu, K., and Cordella, T. (eds), Institutions, Governance and the Control of Corruption, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 1549.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Drèze, J., (2020). Policy Beyond Evidence, World Development, Vol. 127.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Durlauf, S. (2020). Institutions, development and growth; Where does evidence stand?’ in Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Development and Institutions, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford.Google Scholar
Easterly, W. (2001). The Elusive Quest for Growth, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Economist (2021). Education after COVID-19: Studying Ceara, 18–31 December, pp. 33–34.Google Scholar
Economist (2022a, January 29). Put Down Your Truncheons, p. 47.Google Scholar
Economist (2022b, April 2). Kenyan Voters Face an Invidious Choice in August, p. 36.Google Scholar
Ellis, S. (1999). The Mask of Anarchy: The Destruction of Liberia and the Religious Dimension of an African Civil War, New York University Press, New York.Google Scholar
Ensminger, J. (1992). Making a Market: The Institutional Transformation of an African Society, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Ensminger, J. (1997). Changing property rights: Reconciling formal and informal rights to land in Africa, in Drobak, J. N., and Nye, J. V. C. (eds), The Frontiers of the New Institutional Economics, Academic Press, San Diego, CA, pp. 165–96.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, M. (1992). Solidarity networks in preindustrial societies: Rational peasants with a moral economy, Economic Development and Cultural Change 41(1), pp. 147–74.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, M. (1996). The enforcement of commercial contracts in Ghana, World Development 24(3), pp. 427–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fafchamps, M. (2004). Market Institutions in Sub-Saharan Africa: Theory and Evidence, MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Fafchamps, M. (2020). Formal and informal market institutions: Embeddedness revisited, in Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Development and Institutions, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford, pp. 375413.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Feder, G. (1985). The relation between farm size and farm productivity, Journal of Development Economics 18(2/3), pp. 297313.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fei, J. and Ranis, G. (1975). A model of growth and employment in the open dualistic economy: The cases of Korea and Taiwan, The Journal of Development Studies 11(2), pp. 3263.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Fei, J. C. H., Ranis, G., and Kuo, S. W. Y. (1979). Growth with Equity: The Taiwan Case, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Felipe, J., and Usu, N. (2008). Rethinking the Growth Diagnostics Approach: Questions from the Practitioners, ADB Economics, Working Paper Series, No. 132, Asian Development Bank.Google Scholar
Fernandez, R., and Rodrick, D. (1991). Resistance to reform: Status quo bias in the presence of individual-specific uncertainty, American Economic Review 81(5), pp. 1146–55.Google Scholar
Frank, C. R. Jr., Kim, K. S., and Westphal, L. E. (1975). Foreign Trade Regimes and Economic Development: South Korea, NBER Books.Google Scholar
Fukuyama, F. (2012). The Origins of Political Order – From Prehuman Times to the French Revolution. London: Profile Books.Google Scholar
Gazdar, H. (2000). State, Community, and Universal Education: A Political Economy of Public Schooling in Rural Pakistan, Asia Research Centre and London School of Economics, draft paper.Google Scholar
Geertz, C. (1973). The Interpretation of Cultures, Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Genicot, G., and Ray, D. (2020). Aspirations and economic behavior,’ Annual Review of Economics 12, pp. 715–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gerschenkron, A., (1962). Economic Backwardness in Historical Perspective. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Giblin, J. L. (2005). Some complexities of family and state in Colonial Njombe, in Maddox, G. H., and Giblin, J. L. (eds), In Search of a Nation – Histories of Authority and Dissidence in Tanzania, James Currey, Oxford, Kapsel Educational Publications, Dar es Salaam, and Ohio University Press, Athens, OH, pp. 128–48.Google Scholar
Gollin, D. (2014). The Lewis Model: A 60-year retrospective, Journal of Economic Perspectives 28(3), pp. 7188.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Golub, S. S., and Mbaye, A. A., (2023). Benin’s informal trading with Nigeria, in Bourguignon, et al. (eds), State Capture and Rent Seeking in Benin, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Chapter 8.Google Scholar
Granovetter, M. (1985). Economic action and social structure: The problem of embeddedness, American Journal of Sociology 91(3), pp. 481510.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A., and Tabellini, G. (2010). Cultural and institutional bifurcation: China and Europe compared, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 100(2), pp. 110.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A., and Tabellini, G. (2017). The clan and the corporation: Sustaining cooperation in China and Europe, Journal of Comparative Economics 45(1), pp. 135.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (1989). Reputation and coalitions in medieval trade: Evidence on the Maghribi traders, Journal of Economic History 49(4), pp. 857–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (1992). Institutions and international trade: Lessons from the commercial revolution, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings 82(2), pp.128–33.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (1993). Contract enforceability and economic institutions in early trade: The Maghribi Traders’ Coalition, American Economic Review 83(3), pp. 525–48.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (1994). Cultural beliefs and the organization of society: A historical and theoretical reflection on collectivist and individualist societies, Journal of Political Economy 102(5), pp. 912–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (1998). Historical and comparative institutional analysis, American Economic Review 88(2), pp. 8089.Google Scholar
Greif, A. (2002). Institutions and impersonal exchange: From communal to individual responsibility, Journal of Institutional and Theoretical Economics 158(1), pp. 168204.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Greif, A. (2006). Genoa and the Maghribi Traders: Historical and Comparative Institutional Analysis, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Greif, A., and Laitin, D. (2004). A theory of endogenous institutional change, American Political Science Review 98(4), pp. 633–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guirkinger, C., and Platteau, J.-P. (2015). Transformation of the family farm under rising land pressure: A theoretical essay, Journal of Comparative Economics 43(1), February, pp. 112–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guirkinger, C., and Platteau, J.-P. (2017). Transformation of African farm households: A short survey of economic contributions, Journal of Demographic Economics 83, pp. 4150.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guirkinger, C., and Platteau, J.-P. (2020). The dynamics of family systems: Lessons from past and present times, in Baland, J.-M., Bourguignon, F., Platteau, J.-P., and Verdier, T. (eds), The Handbook of Economic Development and Institutions, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ and Oxford, pp. 449519.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Guirkinger, C., Goetghebuer, T., and Platteau, J.-P. (2015). Productive inefficiency in extended agricultural households: Evidence from Mali, Journal of Development Economics 116, pp. 1727.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gulesci, S., Jindani, S., La Ferrara, E., Smerdon, D., Sulaiman, M., and Young, P. (2021). A Stepping Stone Approach to Understanding Harmful Norms, CEPR Discussion Paper No. DP15776.Google Scholar
Gurnah, A. (2002). By the Sea, Bloomsbury Publishing PLC (French translation: Près de la Mer, Denoël).Google Scholar
Haggard, S., and Moon, C.-I. (1990). Institutions and economic policy: Theory and a Korean case study, World Politics 42(2), pp. 210–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Haggard, S., Kim, B.-K., and Moon, C.-I. (1991). The transition to export-led growth in South Korea: 1954–1966, The Journal of Asian Studies 50(4), pp. 850–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hamilton, G. (1997). Organization and market processes in Taiwan’s capitalist economy, in Orru, M., Woolsey Biggart, N., and Hamilton, G. (eds), The Economic Organization of East Asian Capitalism, Sage, Thousand Oaks, CA, pp. 237–93.Google Scholar
Hamilton, G. (1998). Culture and organization in Taiwan’s market economy, in Hefner, R. W. (ed), Market Cultures – Society and Morality in the New Asian Capitalisms, Westview Press, Boulder, CO, pp. 4177.Google Scholar
Haqqani, H. (2005). Pakistan – Between Mosque and Military, Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Harrison, L. E., and Huntington, S. P. (2000). Culture Matters: How Values Shape Human Progress, Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Hasnain, Z. (2008). The politics of service delivery in Pakistan: Political parties and the incentive for patronage, 1988–1999, The Pakistan Development Review 47(2), pp. 129–51.Google Scholar
Hassan, M., and Raihan, S. (2017). Navigating the Deals World. Deals and Development: The Political Dynamics of Growth Episodes, 96.Google Scholar
Hassan, M., and Raihan, S. (2018). Navigating the deals world: The politics of economic growth in Bangladesh, in Pritchett, L., Sen, K., and Werker, E. (eds), Deals and Development: The Political Dynamics of Growth Episodes, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Hattori, T., and Sato, Y. (1997). A comparative study of development mechanisms in Korea and Taiwan: Introductory analysis, The Developing Economies 35(4), pp. 341–57.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hausmann, R., Rodrik, D., and Velasco, A. (2005). Growth Diagnostics, The John F. Kennedy School of Government, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Hausmann, R., Klinger, B., and Wagner, R. (2008). Doing Growth Diagnostics in Practice: A “Mindbook”, CID Working Paper No. 177, Harvard University, Cambridge, MA.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y. (1997). Development Economics: From the Poverty to the Wealth of Nations, Clarendon Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y., and Kikuchi, M. (1981). Asian Village Economy at the Crossroads: An Economic Approach to Institutional Change, University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo (Japan).Google Scholar
Hayami, Y., and Kikuchi, M. (1982). Asian Village Economy at the Crossroads, University of Tokyo Press, Tokyo, and Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD.Google Scholar
Hayami, Y., and Ruttan, V. (1985). Agricultural Development: An International Perspective, Johns Hopkins University Press, Baltimore, MD and London.Google Scholar
Helme, G., and Levitsky, S. (2004). Informal institutions and comparative politics: A research agenda, Perspectives on Politics 2(4), pp. 725–40.Google Scholar
Heybey, B., and Murrell, P. (1999). The relationship between economic growth and the speed of liberalization, Journal of Policy Reform 3(2), pp. 121–37.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hicks, J. R. (1932). The Theory of Wages, Macmillan, London.Google Scholar
Hidalgo, C., and Hausmann, R. (2009). The building blocks of economic complexity, Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences of the United States of America 106(26), pp. 10570–75.Google ScholarPubMed
Hirschman, A. O. (1958). The strategy of economic development (No. HD82 H49).Google Scholar
Hirshman, A. O. (1958). The Strategy of Economic Development, Yale University Press, New Haven, CT and London.Google Scholar
Ho, S. P. S. (1978). Economic Development of Taiwan, 1860–1970, Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Ho, S. P. S. (1979). Decentralized industrialization and rural development from Taiwan, Economic Development and Cultural Change 28(1), pp. 7796.Google Scholar
Ho, S. P. S. (1980). Small-Scale Enterprises in Korea and Taiwan, World Bank Staff Working Paper, No. 384, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Hoff, K., and Sen, A. (2005). The extended family system and market interactions, in Barrett, C. B. (ed), The Social Economics of Poverty: On Identities, Communities, Groups, and Networks, Routledge, London and New York, pp. 171–87.Google Scholar
Hoff, K., and Sen, A. (2006). The Kin System as a poverty trap, in Bowles, S., Durlauf, S. N., and Hoff, K. (eds), Poverty Traps, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ, Chap. 4.Google Scholar
Huang, S. W. (1993). Structural change in Taiwan’s agricultural economy, Economic Development and Cultural Change 42(1), pp. 4365.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Il, S.-K., and Koh, Y. (2010). The Korean Economy, Six Decades of Growth and Development, Korea Development Institute, Seoul.Google Scholar
Iliffe, J. (2005). Breaking the chain at its weakest link – TANU and the Colonial Office, Maddox, G. H., and Giblin, J. L. (eds), In Search of a Nation – Histories of Authority and Dissidence in Tanzania, James Currey, Oxford, Kapsel Educational Publications, Dar es Salaam, and Ohio University Press, Athens, OH, pp. 168–97.Google Scholar
Iliffe, J. (1995 [2007]). Africans – The History of a Continent, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Johnson, C. (1987). Political institutions and economic performance: The government–business relationship in Japan, South Korea, and Taiwan, in Deyo, F. C. (ed), The Political Economy of the New Asian Industrialism, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY.Google Scholar
Johnston, B., and Kilby, P. (1975). Backward linkages: Fertilizer and farm equipment, in Johnston, B., and Kilby, P. (eds), Agriculture and Structural Transformation: Economic Strategies in Late-Developing Countries, Oxford University Press, New York, pp. 299327.Google Scholar
Jomo, K. S., and Gomez, E. T. (1997). Rents and development in multiethnic Malaysia, in Aoki, M., Kim, H.-K., and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds), The Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development, Oxford University Press and World Bank, pp. 342–72.Google Scholar
Jones, B. (2009). Beyond the State in Rural Uganda, Edinburgh University Press, Edinburgh.Google Scholar
Jones, E. L. (1981). The European Miracle: Environments, Economies and Geopolitics in the History of Europe and Asia, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Kakar, S. (1978). The Inner World: A Psychoanalysis Study of Childhood and Society in India, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Kanbur, R. (2017). W. Arthur Lewis and the roots of Ghanaian economic policy, in Aryeetey, E., and Kanbur, R. (eds), The Economy of Ghana Sixty Years after Independence, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 1627.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kao, C.-S. (1991). Personal trust in the large businesses in Taiwan: A traditional foundation for contemporary economic activities, in Hamilton, G. (ed), Business Networks and Economic Development in East and Southeast Asia, Centre of Asian Studies, University of Hong Kong, Hong Kong, pp. 234–73.Google Scholar
Kaufmann, D., Kraay, A., and Mastruzzi, M. (2010). The Worldwide Governance Indicators: Methodology and Analytical Issues, Policy Research Working Papers, No. 5430, The World Bank.Google Scholar
Kennedy, P. (1988). African Capitalism – The Struggle for Ascendency, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Khemani, S. (2015). Buying votes versus supply in public services: Political incentives to under-invest in pro-poor policies, Journal of Development Economics 177, pp. 8493.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Khemani, S. (2019). What is State Capacity?, Policy Research Working Paper, No. 8734, World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Khemani, S. (2020). Political economy of reform, in Dixit, A., and Hamilton, J. (eds), Oxford Research Encyclopedia of Economics and Finance, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 128.Google Scholar
Kikuchi, M., and Hayami, Y. (1978). Agricultural growth against a land resource constraint: A comparative history of Japan, Taiwan, Korea, and the Philippines, The Journal of Economic History 38(4), pp. 839–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, E. M., and Park, G.-S. (2011). The Chaebol, in Kim, B.-K., and Vogel, E. (eds), The Park Chung Hee Era, Harvard University Press, Boston MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, K. S. (1991). The Korean Miracle (1962–1980) revisited: Myths and realities in strategy and development, Working Paper No. 166, Kelloggs Institute.Google Scholar
Kim, K.-H. (2004). Reflections on the problem of colonial modernity and “collaboration” in modern Korean history, Journal of International and Area Studies 11(3), pp. 95111.Google Scholar
Kim, S. (2021). Land reform and postcolonial poverty in South Korea, 1950–1970, Agricultural History 95(2), pp. 276310.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kim, H.-A. (2011). State building; The military junta’s path to modernity through administrative reforms, in Kim, B.-K., and Vogel, E. (eds), The Park Chung Hee Era, Harvard University Press, Boston MA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kirkpatrick, C., and Barrientos, A. (2004). The Lewis Model after 50 years, The Manchester School 72(6), pp. 679–90.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Koh, B. C. (1993). The war’s impact on the Korean peninsula, The Journal of American–East Asian Relations 2(1), pp. 5776.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kong, T. Y. (2000). The Politics of Economic Reform in South Korea: A Fragile Miracle, Routledge.Google Scholar
Koo, A. Y. C. (1971). Agrarian reform, production and employment in Taiwan, in International Labor Office (ILO), Agrarian Reform and Employment, Geneva.Google Scholar
Koo, Y. (2013). Evolution of industrial policies and economic growth in Korea: Challenges, crises and responses, European Review of Industrial Economics and Policy (ERIEP) 7. [online], available at: http://revel.unice.fr/eriep/index.html?id=3598.Google Scholar
Kuo, W. (1975). Effects of land reform, agricultural pricing policy and economic growth on multiple crop diversification, Philippines Economic Journal 14(1/2).Google Scholar
Kuran, T. (1995). Private Truths, Public Lies: The Social Consequences of Preference Falsification, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA and London.Google Scholar
Kuran, T. (2004a). The economic ascent of the Middle East’s religious minorities: The role of Islamic legal pluralism, Journal of Legal Studies 33, pp. 475515.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuran, T. (2004b). Islam and Mammon: The Economic Predicaments of Islamism, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuru, A. (2009). Secularism and State Policies Toward Religion: The United States, France, and Turkey, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kuznets, S. (1955). Economic growth and income inequality, The American Economic Review, 45(1), 128.Google Scholar
Kuznets, S. (1966). Modern Economic Growth: Rate, Structure and Spread, Yale University Press, London.Google Scholar
Landes, D. (1998). The Wealth and Poverty of Nations: Why Some Are So Rich and Some So Poor?, Little, Brown and Co., London.Google Scholar
Lau, L. J. (1997). The role of government in economic development: Some observations from the experience of China, Hong Kong and Taiwan, in Aoki, M., Kim, H.-K., and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds), The Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development, Oxford University Press and World Bank, pp. 4173.Google Scholar
Ledeneva, A. (1998). Russia’s Economy of Favours: Blat, Networking and Informal Exchange, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Ledeneva, A. (2008). Blat and Guanxi: Informal practices in Russia and China, Comparative Studies in Society and History 50(1), pp. 118–44.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lee, N.-Y. (2011). The automobile industry, in Kim, B.-K., and Vogel, E. (eds), The Park Chung Hee Era, Harvard University Press, Boston MA.Google Scholar
Lee, T.-H., and Chen, T.-E. (1979). Agricultural growth in Taiwan, 1911–1972, in Hayami, Y., Ruttan Vernon, W., and Southworth, H. M. (eds), Agricultural Growth in Japan, Taiwan, Korea, and Philippines, University Press of Hawaii, Honolulu, HI.Google Scholar
Levy, B. (2007). State capacity, accountability, and economic development in Africa, Commonwealth and Comparative Politics 45(4).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. (2011). Bangladesh: Politics, Economy and Civil Society, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1965). Politics in West Africa, Oxford University Press, Oxford.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour, The Manchester School, reprinted in Agarwala, A. N., and Singh, S. P. (eds), The Economics of Underdevelopment, Oxford University Press, Oxford, 1958, pp. 400–49.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1954). Economic development with unlimited supplies of labour, Manchester School of Economic and Social Studies, 22, 139–91.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1955), The Theory of Economic Growth, Richard D. Irwin, Homewood, IL.Google Scholar
Lewis, W. A. (1968). Reflections on unlimited labour, Discussion Paper No. 5, Development Research Project, Woodrow Wilson School, Princeton University, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Li, J. S. (2003). The benefits and costs of relation-based governance: An explanation of the East Asian Miracle and Crisis, Review of International Economics 11(3), pp. 651–73.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Li, K.-T. (1995). The Evolution of Policy Behind Taiwan’s Development Success, World Scientific Publishing, Singapore, New Jersey, London, and Hong Kong.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lizzeri, A., and Persico, N. (2004). Why did the elites extend the suffrage? Democracy and the scope of government, with an application to Britain’s age of reform, Quarterly Journal of Economics 119(2), pp. 707–65.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Luo, J.-D. (1997). The Significance of networks in the initiation of small businesses in Taiwan, Sociological Forum 12, pp. 297317.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lyon, S. M. (2019). Political Kinship in Pakistan, Lexington Books, London and New York.Google Scholar
Mahmud, W., Ahmed, S., and Mahajan, S. (2010). Economic reforms, growth and governance: The political economy aspects of Bangladesh’s development surprise, in Brady, D., and Spence, M. (eds), Leadership and Growth, Commission on Growth and Development,The World Bank, Washington, pp. 227–54.Google Scholar
Majumdar, S., and Mukand, S. (2004). Policy gambles, American Economic Review 94(4), pp. 1207–22.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Malik, A., Mirza, R., and Platteau, J.-P. (2021). “Devolution Under Autocracies: Evidence from Pakistan”, in Faguet, J.-P., and Sarmistha, P. (eds), Decentralized Governance: Crafting Effective Democracies Around the World, Palgrave, Chap. 7.Google Scholar
Malik, A., Mirza, R., and Platteau, J.-P. (2022). Political Dynasties and Development under Competitive Clientelism: Evidence from Pakistan, Mimeo.Google Scholar
Manusher Jonno Foundation (MJF). (2015). Rural Land Market in Bangladesh: A Situation Analysis, MJF, Uttaran, and Care Bangladesh. [online], available at: www.thedailystar.net/rural-land-market-in-bangladesh-a-situation-analysis-61897.Google Scholar
Markevich, A., and Zuravskaya, E. (2018). The economic impact of the abolition of Russian serfdom: Evidence from the Russian Empire, American Economic Review 108(4–5), pp. 1074–117.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martimort, D. (1996). Exclusive dealing, common agency, and Multiprincipals Incentive Theory, RAND Journal of Economics 27, pp. 131.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Martin, N. (2016). Politics, Landlords and Islam in Pakistan, Routledge, London and New York.Google Scholar
Marx, B., Bazzi, S., and Hilmy, M. (2020). Islam and the State: Religious Education in the Age of Mass Schooling, NBER Working Paper No. 27073 (also CEPR Discussion Paper No. 14689).Google Scholar
Mauro, P. (1995). Corruption and growth, Quarterly Journal of Economics 110, pp. 681712.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mehmood, S., and Seror, A. (2019). Judicial Independence, Religion, and Politics: Theory and Evidence, EDI Project, Case Studies, Working Paper, Oxford Policy Management, Oxford.Google Scholar
Meier, G. M., and Baldwin, R. E. (1957). Economic Development, John Wiley & Sons, New York.Google Scholar
Migot-Adholla, S. E., Hazell, P., Blarel, B., and Place, F. (1991). Indigenous land rights systems in sub-Saharan Africa: A constraint on policy?’ World Bank Economic Review 5(1), pp. 155–75.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Milgrom, P., and Roberts, J. (1992). Economics, Organization and Management, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.Google Scholar
Mill, J. S. (1848 [1965]). Principles of Political Economy, Augustus M. Kelley, New York (Reprints of Economic Classics, based on the 7th edition, 1871).Google Scholar
Mohmand, S. K. (2019). Crafty Oligarchs, Savvy Voters: Democracy Under Inequality in Rural Pakistan, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Monson, J. (2005). The tribal past and the politics of nationalism in Mahenge District, 1940–60,’ in Maddox, G. H., and Giblin, J. L. (eds), In Search of a Nation – Histories of Authority and Dissidence in Tanzania, James Currey, Oxford, Kapsel Educational Publications, Dar es Salaam, and Ohio University Press, Athens, OH, pp. 103–13.Google Scholar
Mukandala, R. (2023). The civil service and economic development in Tanzania, in Bourguignon, F. and Wangwe, S. (eds), State and Business in Tanzania’s Development,Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, Chapter 4.Google Scholar
Myint, H. (1958). The “classical theory” of international trade and the underdeveloped countries, The Economic Journal 68(270), pp. 317–37. Reprinted in Myint, H. (1971) Economic Theory and the Underdeveloped Countries, Oxford University Press, London and Toronto, pp. 118–46.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
North, D. (1990). Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance,Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nunn, N. (2008). The long-term effects of Africa’s slave trades, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 123(1), 139–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nurkse, R. (1953). Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries, Oxford University Press, New York.Google Scholar
OECD (2013). OECD Investment Reviews: Tanzania, OECD, Paris.Google Scholar
Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (1997). Toward a comparative institutional analysis of the government–business relationship, in Aoki, M., Kim, H.-K., and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds), The Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development, Oxford University Press and World Bank, pp. 373406.Google Scholar
Olken, B. A., and Pande, R. (2012). Corruption in developing countries, Annual Review of Economics 4(1), pp. 479509.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Onoma, A. K. (2010). The contradictory potential of institutions: The rise and decline of land documentation in Kenya, in Mahoney, J., and Thelen, K. (eds), Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 6393.Google Scholar
Orru, M. (1991). The institutional logic of small-firm economies in Italy and Taiwan, Studies in Comparative International Development 26, pp. 328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ostrom, E. (1990). Governing the Commons: The Evolution of Institutions for Collective Action, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, A., and Johnston, B. (1995). Rural development and dynamic externalities in Taiwan’s structural transformation, Economic Development and Cultural Change 44(1), pp. 181209.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Park, Y. J. (1990). Korean patterns of women’s labor force participation during the period 1960–1980, Korea Journal of Population and Development 19(1), pp. 7190.Google ScholarPubMed
Partnership for Growth. (2011). Tanzania Growth Diagnostics: A Joint Analysis for the Governments of the United Republic of Tanzania and the United States of America’.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (1983). Classical economics and agrarian reforms in underdeveloped areas: The radical views of the two Mills, Journal of Development Studies 19(4), pp. 435–60.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (1991). Traditional systems of social security and hunger insurance: Past achievements and modern challenges, in Ahmad, E., Drèze, J., Hills, J., and Sen, A. K. (eds), Social Security in Developing Countries, Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp. 112–70.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (1994a). Behind the market stage where real societies exist, Part I: The role of public and private order institutions, Journal of Development Studies 30(3), pp. 533–77.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (1994b). Behind the market stage where real societies exist, Part II: The role of moral norms, Journal of Development Studies 30(4), pp. 753817.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (1997). Mutual insurance as an elusive concept in traditional rural societies, Journal of Development Studies 33(6), pp. 764–96.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2000). Institutions, Social Norms, and Economic Development, Harwood, Amsterdam.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2004). The gradual erosion of the social security function of customary land tenure arrangements: The case of tribal societies in sub-Saharan Africa, in Dercon, S. (ed), Insurance Against Poverty, Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp. 247–78.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2006). Solidarity norms and institutions in agrarian societies: Static and dynamic considerations, in Kolm, S., Mercier-Ythier, J., and Varet, G. (eds), Handbook on Gift-Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism, North Holland and Elsevier, Amsterdam, Vol. 1, pp. 819–86.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2008). The causes of institutional inefficiency: A development perspective, in Brousseau, E., and Glachant, J.-M. (eds), New Institutional Economics. A Guidebook, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 437–56.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2011). Culture and development: An overview, in Platteau, J.-P., and Peccoud, R. (eds), Culture, Institutions, and Development: New Insights Into an Old Debate, Routledge, London, pp. 319.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2014). Redistributive pressures in sub-Saharan Africa: Causes, consequences, and coping strategies, in Akyeampong, E., Bates, R. H., Nunn, N., and Robinson, J. A. (eds), African Development in Historical Perspective, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge, pp. 153207.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2017). Islam Instrumentalised: Religion and Politics in Historical Perspective, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge (reviewed in Journal of Economic Literature 56(4), December 2018, pp. 1601–1603).Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P. (2022). Enlightened autocrats: Lessons from bold experiments in the lands of Islam, in Basu, K., and Cordella, T. (eds), Institutions, Governance and the Control of Corruption, Palgrave Macmillan, London, pp. 235–86.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.P. (2022). Enlightened autocrats: Lessons from bold experiments in the lands of Islam, in Basu, K., Ghatak, M., Kletzer, K., Mundle, S., and Verhoogen, E. (eds), Development, Distribution, and Markets, Oxford University Press, Oxford, pp. 235–86.Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P., and Oliveros, D. U. (2021). Cognitive bias in insurance: Evidence from India, World Development 44(August).Google Scholar
Platteau, J.-P., and Wahhaj, Z. (2013). Interactions between modern law and custom, in Ginsburgh, V., and Throsby, D. (eds), Handbook of the Economics of Art and Culture, vol. 2, Elsevier and North-Holland, pp. 633–78.Google Scholar
Polanyi, Karl (1957) The Great Transformation, Rineholt, New York.Google Scholar
Prakash, N., Rockmore, M., and Uppal, Y. (2019). Do criminally accused politicians affect economic outcomes? Evidence from India, Journal of Development Economics 141, Article 102370.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Price, R. M. (1975). Society and Bureaucracy in Contemporary Ghana, University of California Press, Berkeley, CA.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Querubin, P. (2012). Political reform and elite persistence: Term limits and political dynasties in the Philippines. In APSA 2012 Annual Meeting Paper.Google Scholar
Querubin, P. (2016). Family and politics: Dynastic persistence in the Philippines, Quarterly Journal of Political Science, 11(2), pp. 151–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Raihan, S. and Bourguignon, F. (2023). An Institutional Diagnostic of Bangladesh: Introduction, in Raihan, et al. (eds), Is the Bangladesh Paradox Sustainable? Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Chapter 1.Google Scholar
Raihan, S., Bourguignon, F., and Salam, U. (2020). Is Bangladesh Paradox Sustainable? An Institutional Diagnostic, EDI. [online], available at: https://edi.opml.co.uk/research/bangladesh-institutional-diagnostic/.Google Scholar
Raihan, S., Bourguignon, F., and Salam, U. (Eds.) (2023). Is the Bangladesh Paradox Sustainable? Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Ranis, G. (2004). Labor Surplus Economies, Center Discussion Paper No. 900, Economic Growth Center, Yale University, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Ranis, G. and Fei, J. (1961). A theory of economic development, American Economic Review 51(4), pp. 533–65.Google Scholar
Rasmusen, E. (1989). Games and Information: An Introduction to Game Theory, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Ray, D. (1998). Development Economics, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.Google Scholar
Reno, W. (1995). Corruption and State Politics in Sierra Leone, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.Google Scholar
Rhyu, S.-Y., and Lew, S.-J. (2011). Pohang Iron and Steel Company, in Kim, B.-K., and Vogel, E. (eds), The Park Chung Hee Era, Harvard University Press, Boston MA.Google Scholar
Riaz, A. (2016). Bangladesh: A Political History Since Independence, I.B. Tauris, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Rodrik, D. (2004). Institutions and Economic Performance: Getting Institutions Right, CESifo DICE Report, Institut für Wirtschaftsforschung, München Universität, 2(2), pp. 10–15.Google Scholar
Rosenzweig, M. R., Binswanger, H. P., and McIntire, H. (1988). From land abundance to land scarcity – The effects of population growth on production relations in agrarian economies, in Lee, R. D., Arthur, W. B., Kelley, A. C., Rodgers, G., and Srinivasan, T. N. (eds), Population, Food and Rural Development, Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp. 77100.Google Scholar
Sahlins, M. (1965). On the sociology of primitive exchange, in Banton, M. (ed), The Relevance of Models for Social Anthropology, Tavistock Publications, London, pp. 139236.Google Scholar
Sayigh, Y. (2019). Owners of the Republic: An Anatomy of Egypt’s Military Economy, Carnegie Middle East Center, Beirut, and Carnegie Endowment for International Peace, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
Schneidewind, D. K. (2016). Economic Miracle Market South Korea: A Blueprint for Economic Growth in Developing Nations, Springer.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schotter, A. (1981). The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schultz, T. W. (1964). Transforming Traditional Agriculture, Yale University Press, New Haven, CT.Google Scholar
Scott, J. C. (1976) The Moral Economy of the Peasant: Rebellion and Subsistence in Southeast Asia, Yale University Press, New Haven, CT and London.Google Scholar
Scott, J. (1972) Comparative Political Corruption, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ.Google Scholar
Sedjo, R. A. (1976). Korean historical experience and the labor-surplus model, The Journal of Developing Areas 10(2), pp. 213–22.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. (1960). Choice of Techniques, Basil Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Sen, A. K. (1966). Peasants and dualism with and without surplus labor, Journal of Political Economy 74(5), pp. 425–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Sen, A. (1975). The concept of efficiency, Contemporary Issues in Economics, pp. 196210.Google Scholar
Sen, B. (2018). The Rise of Landless Tenancy in Rural Bangladesh: Analysis of the Recent Evidence. Dhaka: Presentation Made at the 2018 Bangladesh Institute of Development Studies Research Almanac, pp. 11–12.Google Scholar
Sen, B., Dorosh, P., and Mansur, A. (2021). Moving out of agriculture in Bangladesh: The role of farms, non-farm and mixed households, World Development 144(August).CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Seth, M. J. (2002). Education fever: Society, politics, and the pursuit of schooling in South Korea, University of Hawaii Press, Hawaii.Google Scholar
Seth, M. J. (2013). An Unpromising Recovery: South Korea’s Post-Korean War Economic Development: 1953–1961, Education About Asia, 18(3), p. 42.Google Scholar
Seth, M. J. (2020). A Concise History of Modern Korea: From the Late Nineteenth Century to the Present, vol. 2, Rowman and Littlefield, Lanham, MD.Google Scholar
Shah, A. (2014). The Army and Democracy: Military Politics in Pakistan, Harvard University Press, Cambridge, MA and London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shapley, L. S., and Shubik, M. (1969). On the core of an economic system with externalities, American Economic Review 59(4), pp. 678–84.Google Scholar
Sheikh, M. Z. H., and Ahamed, Z. S. (2019). Military, Authoritarianism and Islam: A Comparative Analysis of Bangladesh and Pakistan, Politics and Religion, pp. 1–28.Google Scholar
Shipton, P. (1988). The Kenyan land tenure reform: Misunderstandings in the public creation of private property, in Downs, R. E., and Reyna, S. P. (eds), Land and Society in Contemporary Africa, University Press of New England, Hanover, NH and London, pp. 91135.Google Scholar
Siddiqa, A. (2017). Military Inc.: Inside Pakistan’s Military Economy, Penguin Random House, India.Google Scholar
Siddiqui, B. M., Di Maro, V., Mulaj, F., Maqueda, M. R., and Chen, D. (2021). Using machine learning to promote fairness and efficiency in Indian courts, EDI Working Paper, Oxford.Google Scholar
Smith, T. C. (1959). The Agrarian Origins of Modern Japan, Stanford University Press, Stanford, CA.Google Scholar
Sokoloff, K. L., and Engerman, S. L. (2000). History lessons: Institutions, factor endowments, and paths of development in the New World, Journal of Economic Perspectives 14(3), pp. 217–32.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Stewart, F. (1977). Relevant Aspects of the Technology Problem in the Case of Developing Economies, Université de Montréal, Centre de recherche en développement économique.Google Scholar
Stiglitz, J. (1989). Rational peasants, efficient institutions, and a theory of rural organization: Methodological remarks for development economics, in Bardhan, P. (ed), The Economic Theory of Agrarian Institutions, Clarendon Press, Oxford, pp. 1829.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1986). The Economics of Rights, Cooperation and Welfare, Blackwell, Oxford.Google Scholar
Sugden, R. (1989). Spontaneous order, Journal of Economic Perspectives 3(4), pp. 8597.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Teorell, J., Sundström, A., Holmberg, S., Rothstein, B., Alvarado Pachon, N., and Dall, C. M. (2021). The Quality of Government Standard Dataset, 21 January version, The Quality of Government Institute (www.qog.pol.gu.se), University of Gothenburg. doi: 10.18157/qogstdjan21.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thorbecke, E. (1979). Agricultural development, in Galenson, W. (ed), Economic Growth and Structural Change in Taiwan: The Postwar Experience of the Republic of China, Cornell University Press, Ithaca, NY and London, pp. 132205.Google Scholar
Tignor, R. L. (2006). W. Arthur Lewis and the Birth of Development Economics, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tilly, C. (1985). War making and state making as organized crime. In Evans, P. P., Evans, P. B., Rueschemeyer, D., and Skocpol, T. (eds), (1985). Bringing the State Back In. Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Udry, C. (1994). Risk and insurance in a rural credit market: An empirical investigation in Northern Nigeria, Review of Economic Studies, 61, 495526.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Voigtländer, N., and Voth, H.-J. (2013). How the West “invented” fertility restriction, American Economic Review 103(6), pp. 2227–64.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vromen, J. J. (1995). Economic Evolution: An Enquiry into the Foundations of New Institutional Economics, Routledge, London and New York.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, R. (1982). The system of administrative and political corruption: Canal irrigation in South India, Journal of Development Studies 18(3), pp. 287328.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, R. (1985). The market for public office: Why the Indian state is not better at development, World Development 13(4), pp. 467–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, R. (1988). The management of irrigation systems: How to evoke trust and avoid prisoners’ dilemma, World Development 16(4), pp. 489500.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, R. (1990a). Governing the Market: Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East Asian Industrialization, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wade, R. (1990b). Employment, water control and water supply institutions: India and South Korea, in Gooneratne, W., and Hirashima, S. (eds), Irrigation and Water Management in Asia, Sterling Publishers, New Delhi.Google Scholar
Wang, W.-Y. (2002). Economic implications of the rule of law: The case of Taiwan, in Chow, P. C. Y. (ed), Taiwan’s Modernization in Global Perspective, Praeger, Westport, CT and London, pp. 103–14.Google Scholar
Wilder, A. (2009). The Politics of Civil Service Reform in Pakistan, Journal of International Affairs, 63(1), pp. 1937.Google Scholar
Wilson, J. Q. (2019). Bureaucracy: What Government Agencies Do and Why They Do It, Basic Books, New York.Google Scholar
Woo-Cumings, M. (1997). The political economy of growth in East Asia: A perspective on the state, market, and ideology, in Aoki, M., Kim, H.-K., and Okuno-Fujiwara, M. (eds), The Role of Government in East Asian Economic Development, Oxford University Press and World Bank, pp. 323–41.Google Scholar
World Bank (2007). Bangladesh Paradox: Does Governance Matter to Growth, Country Report, The World Bank, Washington.Google Scholar
World Bank (2017). World Development Report: Governance and the Law, The World Bank, Washington, DC.Google Scholar
World Justice Project (2019). Rule of Law Index 2019 report.Google Scholar
Wu, J. (2005). Understanding and Interpreting Chinese Economic Reform, Thomson South-Western, Mason, OH.Google Scholar
Yang, M. M. C. (1970). Socio-economic Results of Land Reform in Taiwan. East–West Center Press, Honolulu, HI.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yoo, J. (2017). Korea’s rapid export expansion in the 1960s: How it began, KDI Journal of Economic Policy 39(2): 123.Google Scholar
Yoon, Y., and Mudida, R. (2020). Social and economic transformation in Tanzania and South Korea: Ujamaa and Saemaul Undong in the 1970s compared, Seoul Journal of Economics 20(33), pp. 195231.Google Scholar
Young, A. (1994). Lessons from the East Asian NICS: A contrarian view, European Economic Review 8(3–4), pp. 964–73.Google Scholar
Young, A. (1995). The tyranny of numbers: Confronting the statistical realities of the East Asian growth experience, The Quarterly Journal of Economics 110(3), pp. 641–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Young, P. (1998). Individual Strategy and Social Structure, Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zahab, M. A. (2020). Pakistan: A Kaleidoscope of Islam, Hurst Publishers, London.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Zürcher, E. (2012). The Young Turk Legacy and Nation Building: From the Ottoman Empire to Atatürk’s Turkey, I.B. Tauris, London.Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • François Bourguignon, École d'économie de Paris and École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris, Jean-Philippe Platteau, Université de Namur, Belgium
  • Book: Institutional Challenges at the Early Stages of Development
  • Online publication: 09 November 2023
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • François Bourguignon, École d'économie de Paris and École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris, Jean-Philippe Platteau, Université de Namur, Belgium
  • Book: Institutional Challenges at the Early Stages of Development
  • Online publication: 09 November 2023
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • François Bourguignon, École d'économie de Paris and École des Hautes Études en Sciences Sociales, Paris, Jean-Philippe Platteau, Université de Namur, Belgium
  • Book: Institutional Challenges at the Early Stages of Development
  • Online publication: 09 November 2023
Available formats
×