Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-dsjbd Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T18:18:35.096Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

References

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  02 February 2023

Scott de Marchi
Affiliation:
Duke University, North Carolina
Michael Laver
Affiliation:
New York University
Get access

Summary

Image of the first page of this content. For PDF version, please use the ‘Save PDF’ preceeding this image.'
Type
Chapter
Information
The Governance Cycle in Parliamentary Democracies
A Computational Social Science Approach
, pp. 198 - 207
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2023

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Aksoy, Deniz. 2012. “Institutional Arrangements and Logrolling: Evidence from the European Union.” American Journal of Political Science 56: 538–52.Google Scholar
Aldrich, John H., Montgomery, Jacob M., and Sparks, David B.. 2014. “Polarization and Ideology: Partisan Sources of Low Dimensionality in Scaled Roll Call Analyses.” Political Analysis 22: 435–56.Google Scholar
Alvarez, R. Michael. 2016. Computational Social Science. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Andersson, Staffan, Bergman, Torbjörn, and Ersson, Svante. 2014. “The European Representative Democracy Data Archive, Release 3.” Main sponsor: Riksbankens Jubileumsfond (In2007-0149:1-E), www.erdda.se.Google Scholar
Ansolabehere, Stephen, Snyder, James M., Strauss, Aaron B., and Ting, Michael M.. 2005. “Voting Weights and Formateur Advantages in the Formation of Coalition Governments.” American Journal of Political Science 49: 550–63.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1997. “The Evolution of Strategies in the Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma.” In The Complexity of Cooperation: Agent-Based Models of Competition and Collaboration, ed. Axelrod, Robert. Princeton: Princeton University Press. 1429.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1980a. “Effective Choice in the Prisoner’s Dilemma.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 24: 325.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1980b. “More Effective Choice in the Prisoner’s Dilemma.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 24: 379403.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert. 1970. Conflict of Interest. Chicago: Markham.Google Scholar
Axelrod, Robert, and Hamilton, William D.. 1981. “The Evolution of Cooperation.” Science 211: 1390–96.Google Scholar
Bäck, Hanna. 2003. “Explaining and Predicting Coalition Outcomes: Conclusions from Studying Data on Local Coalitions.” European Journal of Political Research 42: 441–72.Google Scholar
Bakker, Ryan, De Vries, Catherine, Edwards, Erica, et al. 2015. “Measuring Party Positions in Europe: The Chapel Hill Expert Survey Trend File, 1999–2010.” Party Politics 21: 143–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bakker, Ryan, Hooghe, Liesbet, Jolly, Seth, et al. 2020. 2019 Chapel Hill Expert Survey. Chapel Hill: University of North Carolina.Google Scholar
Banks, Jeffrey S., and Duggan, John. 2006. “A General Bargaining Model of Legislative Policy-Making.” Quarterly Journal of Political Science 1: 4985.Google Scholar
Baron, David. 1991. “A Spatial Bargaining Theory of Government Formation in Parliamentary Systems.” American Political Science Review 85: 137–64.Google Scholar
Baron, David, and Ferejohn, John. 1989. “Bargaining in Legislatures.” American Political Science Review 83: 1182–202.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bassi, Anna. 2013. “A Model of Endogenous Government Formation.” American Journal of Political Science 57: 777–93.Google Scholar
Bednar, Jenna, and Page, Scott E.. 2018. “When Order Affects Performance: Culture, Behavioral Spillovers, and Institutional Path Dependence.” American Political Science Review 112: 8298.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, and Moe, Terry M.. 1985. “An Adaptive Model of Bureaucratic Politics.” American Political Science Review 79: 755–74.Google Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, and Swistak, Piotr. 2001. “The Evolution of Norms.” American Journal of Sociology 106: 1493–545.Google Scholar
Benoit, Kenneth, Conway, Drew, Lauderdale, Benjamin E., Laver, Michael, and Mikhaylov, Slava. 2016. “Crowd-Sourced Text Analysis: Reproducible and Agile Production of Political Data.” American Political Science Review 110: 278–95.Google Scholar
Benoit, Kenneth, and Laver, Michael. 2012. “The Dimensionality of Political Space: Epistemological and Methodological Considerations.” European Union Politics 13: 194218.Google Scholar
Benoit, Kenneth, and Laver, Michael. 2006. Party Policy in Modern Democracies. London: Routledge.Google Scholar
Benoit, Kenneth, Laver, Michael, and Mikhaylov, Slava. 2009. “Treating Words as Data with Error: Uncertainty in Text Statements of Policy Positions.” American Journal of Political Science 53: 495513.Google Scholar
Berger, Ulrich. 2007. “Brown’s Original Fictitious Play.” Journal of Economic Theory 135: 572–78.Google Scholar
Billings, Darse, Burch, Neil, Davidson, Aaron, et al. 2003. “Approximating Game-Theoretic Optimal Strategies for Full-Scale Poker.” Paper presented at the IJCAI.Google Scholar
Binmore, Ken. 1998. “The Complexity of Cooperation.” Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 1.Google Scholar
Binmore, Kenneth G., and Samuelson, Larry. 1992. “Evolutionary Stability in Repeated Games Played by Finite Automata.” Journal of Economic Theory 57: 278305.Google Scholar
Black, Duncan. 1958. The Theory of Committees and Elections. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Bowler, Shaun, McElroy, Gail, and Müller, Stefan. 2022. “Voter Expectations of Government Formation in Coalition Systems: The Importance of the Information Context.” European Journal of Political Research 61: 111–33.Google Scholar
Braumoeller, Bear F. 2003. “Causal Complexity and the Study of Politics.” Political Analysis 11: 209–33.Google Scholar
Brown, Noam, and Sandholm, Tuomas. 2019. “Superhuman AI for Multiplayer Poker.” Science 365: 885–90.Google Scholar
Brown, Noam, and Sandholm, Tuomas. 2017. “Libratus: The Superhuman AI for No-Limit Poker.” Paper presented at the IJCAI.Google Scholar
Browne, Eric, and Frendreis, John. 1980. “Allocating Coalition Payoffs by Conventional Norm: An Assessment of the Evidence from Cabinet Coalition Situations.” American Journal of Political Science 24: 753–68.Google Scholar
Browne, Eric, Frendreis, John, and Gleiber, Dennis. 1986a. “An Exponential Model of Cabinet Stability: The Durability, Duration, and Survival of Cabinet Governments.” American Journal of Political Science 30: 628–50.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Browne, Eric, Frendreis, John, and Gleiber, Dennis. 1986b. “The Study of Governmental Dissolutions in Western Parliamentary Democracies.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 11: 619–28.Google Scholar
Budge, Ian, Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andrea, et al. 2001. Mapping Policy Preferences: Parties, Electors and Governments: 1945-1998: Estimates for Parties, Electors and Governments 1945-1998. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Budge, Ian, Robertson, David, and Hearl, Derek. 1987. Ideology, Strategy and Party Change: Spatial Analyses of Post-War Election Programmes in 19 Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Carrubba, Clifford J., and Volden, Craig. 2000. “Coalitional Politics and Logrolling in Legislative Institutions.” American Journal of Political Science 44: 261–77.Google Scholar
Chiba, Daina, Martin, Lanny W., and Stevenson, Randolph T.. 2015. “A Copula Approach to the Problem of Selection Bias in Models of Government Survival.” Political Analysis 23: 4258.Google Scholar
Conitzer, Vincent, and Sandholm, Tuomas. 2002. “Complexity Results about Nash Equilibria.” arXiv preprint cs/0205074.Google Scholar
Converse, Phillip E. 1964. “The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics.” In Ideology and Discontent., ed. Apter, David E.. London: Free Press of Glencoe. 206–61.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary W. 2021. “Nonunitary Parties, Government Formation, and Gamson’s Law.” American Political Science Review 115: 917–30.Google Scholar
Cutler, Josh, de Marchi, Scott, Gallop, Max, Hollenbach, Florian M., Laver, Michael, and Orlowski, Matthias. 2016. “Cabinet Formation and Portfolio Distribution in European Multiparty Systems.” British Journal of Political Science 46: 3143.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Scott. 2022. “The Complexity of Polarization.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 119: e2115019119.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Scott. 2005. Computational and Mathematical Modeling in the Social Sciences. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Scott, Dorsey, Spencer, and Ensley, Michael J.. 2021. “Policy and the Structure of Roll Call Voting in the US House.” Journal of Public Policy 41: 384408.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Scott, and Laver, Michael. 2020. “Government Formation as Logrolling in High-Dimensional Issue Spaces.” The Journal of Politics 82: 543–58.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Scott, and Page, Scott E.. 2014. “Agent-Based Models.” Annual Review of Political Science 17: 120.Google Scholar
de Marchi, Scott, and Stewart, B.. 2020. “Wrestling with Complexity in Computational Social Science: Theory, Estimation and Representation.” In The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and International Relations, eds. Curini, Luigi, and Franzese, Robert. London: Sage Publications. 289310.Google Scholar
Denzau, Arthur T., and North, Douglass C.. 2000. “Shared Mental Models: Ideologies and Institutions.” In Elements of Reason: Cognition, Choice, the Bounds of Rationality, eds. Chong, Dennis, and Kuklinski, James H.. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. 2346.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, Eraslan, Hülya, and Merlo, Antonio. 2003. “A Structural Model of Government Formation.” Econometrica 71: 2770.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Krehbiel, Keith. 2003. “Institutionalism as a Methodology.” Journal of Theoretical Politics 15: 123–44.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Merlo, Antonio. 2000. “Government Turnover in Parliamentary Democracies.” Journal of Economic Theory 94: 4679.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Stevenson, Randy. 2000. “Cabinet Terminations and Critical Events.” American Political Science Review 94: 627–40.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Stevenson, Randy. 1999. “Cabinet Survival and Competing Risks.” American Journal of Political Science 93: 1051–68.Google Scholar
Diermeier, Daniel, and Van Roozendaal, Peter. 1998. “The Duration of Cabinet Formation Processes in Western Multi-Party Democracies.” British Journal of Political Science 28: 609–26.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Döring, Holge, and Manow, Philip. 2020. “Parlgov. Parliaments and Governments Database: Information on Parties, Elections and Cabinets in Modern Democracies.” www.parlgov.org/.Google Scholar
Dragu, Tiberiu, and Laver, Michael. 2019. “Coalition Governance with Incomplete Information.” The Journal of Politics 81: 923–36.Google Scholar
Dragu, Tiberiu, and Laver, Michael. 2017. “Legislative Coalitions with Incomplete Information.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences 114: 2876–80.Google Scholar
Druckman, James N., and Warwick, Paul V.. 2005. “The Missing Piece: Measuring Portfolio Salience in Western European Parliamentary Democracies.” European Journal of Political Research 44: 1742.Google Scholar
Ecker, Alejandro, and Meyer, Thomas M.. 2019. “Fairness and Qualitative Portfolio Allocation in Multiparty Governments.” Public Choice 181: 309–30.Google Scholar
Eggers, Andrew C., and Spirling, Arthur. 2016. “Party Cohesion in Westminster systems: Inducements, Replacement and Discipline in the House of Commons, 1836–1910.” British Journal of Political Science 46: 567–89.Google Scholar
Fortunato, David, et al. 2021. “Attributing Policy Influence under Coalition Governance.” American Political Science Review 115: 252–68.Google Scholar
Fowler, James H., and Laver, Michael. 2008. “A Tournament of Party Decision Rules.” Journal of Conflict Resolution 52: 6892.Google Scholar
Fréchette, Guillaume, Kagel, John H., and Morelli, Massimo. 2005a. “Behavioral Identification in Coalitional Bargaining: An Experimental Analysis of Demand Bargaining and Alternating Offers.” Econometrica 73: 1893–937.Google Scholar
Fréchette, Guillaume, Kagel, John H., and Morelli, Massimo. 2005b. “Gamson’s Law versus Non-Cooperative Bargaining Theory.” Games and Economic Behavior 51: 365–90.Google Scholar
Freixas, Josep, and Molinero, Xavier. 2009. “On the Existence of a Minimum Integer Representation for Weighted Voting Systems.” Annals of Operations Research 166: 243–60.Google Scholar
Friedman, Milton. 1953. “The Methodology of Positive Economics.” In Essays in Positive Economics, ed. Freidman, Milton. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Gallagher, Michael, Laver, Michael, and Mair, Peter. 2012. Representative Government in Modern Europe (5th ed.). Maidenhead: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Gamson, William A. 1961. “A Theory of Coalition Formation.” American Sociological Review 26: 373–82.Google Scholar
Ganzfried, Sam, and Sandholm, Tuomas. 2008. “Computing an Approximate Jam/Fold Equilibrium for 3-Player No-Limit Texas Hold’em Tournaments.” Paper presented at the Proceedings of the 7th International Joint Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems-Volume 2.Google Scholar
Gibson, Richard G., Burch, Neil, Lanctot, Marc, and Szafron, Duane. 2012. “Efficient Monte Carlo Counterfactual Regret Minimization in Games with Many Player Actions.” Paper presented at the NIPS.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, and Gaissmaier, Wolfgang. 2011. “Heuristic Decision Making.” Annual Review of Psychology 62: 451–82.Google Scholar
Gigerenzer, Gerd, and Selten, Reinhard. 2002. Bounded Rationality: The Adaptive Toolbox. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Golder, Sona N. 2010. “Bargaining Delays in the Government Formation Process.” Comparative Political Studies 43: 332.Google Scholar
Guo, Rongxing. 2019. “Win-Stay, Lose-Shift: A Survival Rule.” In Human-Earth System Dynamics, ed. Guo, Rongxing. Singapore: Springer. 121.Google Scholar
Heinrich, Johannes, and Silver, David. 2014. “Self-Play Monte-Carlo Tree Search in Computer Poker.” Paper presented at the Workshops at the Twenty-Eighth AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence.Google Scholar
Hoffmann, Robert. 2000. “Twenty Years on: The Evolution of Cooperation Revisited.” Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 3: 1390–96.Google Scholar
Jenke, Libby. “Introduction to the special issue: Innovations and current challenges in experimental methods.” Political Analysis 30.S1 (2022): S3-S7.Google Scholar
Johanson, Michael, Burch, Neil, Valenzano, Richard, and Bowling, Michael. 2013. “Evaluating State-Space Abstractions in Extensive-Form Games.” Paper presented at the Proceedings of the 2013 International Conference on Autonomous Agents and Multiagent Systems.Google Scholar
Judd, Kenneth, and Page, Scott E.. 2004. “Computational Public Economics.” Journal of Public Economic Theory 6: 195202.Google Scholar
Kadane, Joseph B. 1972. “On Division of the Question.” Public Choice 13: 4754.Google Scholar
Kahneman, Daniel, and Tversky, Amos, eds. 2000. Choices, Values and Frames. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Kayser, Mark A., Orlowski, Matthias, and Rehmert, Jochen. 2019. “Coalition Inclusion Prob-Abilities: A Party-Strategic Measure for Predicting Politics and Policy.” Working Paper. Hertie School of Governance, Berlin.Google Scholar
Keohane, Robert. 1999. “Ideology and Professionalism in International Institutions: Insights from the Work of Douglass C. North.” Alt, J., M. Levi y E. Ostrom [ed](1999): 228–46.Google Scholar
King, Gary. 2003. “The Future of Replication.” International Studies Perspectives. In Bueno de Mesquita, Bruce, Gleditsch, Nils Petter, James, Patrick, King, Gary, Metelits, Claire, Ray, James Lee, Russett, Bruce, Strand, Håvard, and Valeriano, Brandon. “Symposium on replication in international studies research.” International Studies Perspectives 4: 72107.Google Scholar
King, Gary. 1995. “Replication, Replication.” PS: Political Science & Politics 28: 444–52.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Pan, Jennifer, and Roberts, Margaret E.. 2013. “How Censorship in China Allows Government Criticism but Silences Collective Expression.” American Political Science Review 326–43.Google Scholar
King, Gary, Alt, James E., Elizabeth Burns, Nancy, and Laver, Michael. 1990. “A Unified Model of Cabinet Dissolution in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 34: 872902.Google Scholar
Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Hofferbert, Richard I., and Budge, Ian. 1994. Parties, Policies, and Democracy, Theoretical Lenses on Public Policy. Boulder: Westview Press.Google Scholar
Klingemann, Hans-Dieter, Volkens, Andrea, Bara, Judith, Budge, Ian, and McDonald, Michael. 2006. Mapping Policy Preferences II: Estimates for Parties, Electors, and Governments in Eastern Europe, European Union and OECD 1990-2003. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Klüver, Heike, and Bäck, Hanna. 2019. “Coalition Agreements, Issue Attention, and Cabinet Governance.” Comparative Political Studies 52: 19952031.Google Scholar
Kollman, Ken, Miller, John, and Page, Scott. 1998. “Political Parties and Electoral Landscapes.” British Journal of Political Science 28 139–58.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollman, Ken, Miller, John, and Page, Scott. 1992. “Adaptive Parties in Spatial Elections.” American Political Science Review 86: 929–37.Google Scholar
Lanctot, Marc, Waugh, Kevin, Zinkevich, Martin, and Bowling, Michael H.. 2009. “Monte Carlo Sampling for Regret Minimization in Extensive Games.” Paper presented at the NIPS.Google Scholar
Laver, M. 2003. “Government Termination.” Annual Review of Political Science 6: 2340.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael. 2020a. Agent-Based Models of Polarization and Ethnocentrism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael. 2020b. Agent-Based Models of Social Life: Fundamentals. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Benoit, Kenneth A.. 2015. “The Basic Arithmetic of Legislative Decisions.” American Journal of Political Science 59: 275–91.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Benoit, Kenneth A.. 2003. “The Evolution of Party Systems between Elections.” American Journal of Political Science 47: 215–33.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Ben Hunt, W.. 1992. Policy and Party Competition. New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, Benoit, Kenneth A., and Garry, John. 2003. “Estimating the Policy Positions of Political Actors Using Words as Data.” American Political Science Review 97: 311–31.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, de Marchi, Scott, and Mutlu, Hande. 2011a. “Negotiation in Legislatures over Government Formation.” Public Choice 147: 285304.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, de Marchi, Scott, and Mutlu, Hande. 2011b. “Negotiation in Legislatures over Government Formation.” Public Choice 147: 285304.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Schofield, Norman. 1998a. Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Schofield, Norman. 1998b. Multiparty Government: The Politics of Coalition in Europe. Ann Arbor paperback ed. Ann Arbor, MI: University of Michigan Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Sergenti, Ernest. 2012. Party Competition: An Agent-Based Model, Princeton Studies in Complexity. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1998. “Events, Equilibria and Government Survival.” American Journal of Political Science 42: 2854.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1996a. Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1996b. Making and Breaking Governments: Cabinets and Legislatures in Parliamentary Democracies. Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Laver, Michael, and Shepsle, Kenneth A.. 1994. Cabinet Ministers and Parliamentary Government, Political Economy of Institutions and Decisions. Cambridge [England]: New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Lowe, Will, Benoit, Kenneth, Mikhaylov, Slava, and Laver, Michael. 2011. “Scaling Policy Preferences from Coded Political Texts.” Legislative Studies Quarterly 36: 123–55.Google Scholar
Lupia, Arthur, and Strom, Kaare. 1995. “Coalition Termination and the Strategic Timing of Parliamentary Elections.” American Political Science Review 89: 648–65.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny, and Vanberg, Georg. 2020. “Models of Coalition Politics: Recent Developments and New Directions.” The SAGE Handbook of Research Methods in Political Science and International Relations: 244.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny, and Vanberg, Georg. 2015. “Coalition Formation and Policymaking in Parliamentary Democracies.” In Routledge Handbook of Comparative Political Institutions, eds. Gandhi, Jennifer, and Ruiz-Rufino, Rubén. London, New York: Routledge.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny, and Vanberg, Georg. 2014. “Parties and Policymaking in Multiparty Governments: The Legislative Median, Ministerial Autonomy, and the Coalition Compromise.” American Journal of Political Science 58: 979–96.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny, and Vanberg, Georg. 2011. Parliaments and Coalitions: The Role of Legislative Institutions in Multiparty Governance. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny, and Vanberg, Georg. 2003. “Wasting Time? The Impact of Ideology and Size on Delay in Coalition Formation.” British Journal of Political Science 33: 323–32.Google Scholar
Martin, Lanny W., and Stevenson, Randolph T.. 2001. “Government Formation in Parliamentary Democracies.” American Journal of Political Science 45: 3350.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Schofield, Norman. 1987. “Generalized Symmetry Conditions at a Core Point.” Econometrica 55: 923–33.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard D., and Schofield, Norman. 1986. “Structural Instability of the Core.” Journal of Mathematical Economics 15: 179–98.Google Scholar
Miller, John H., and Page, Scott. 2009. Complex Adaptive Systems. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Morelli, Massimo. 1999. “Demand Competition and Policy Compromise in Legislative Bargaining.” American Political Science Review 93: 809–20.Google Scholar
Müller, Wolfgang C., and Strøm, Kaare. 2003. Coalition Governments in Western Europe. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Müller, Wolfgang C., and Strøm, Kaare. 2000. Coalition Governments in Western Europe. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Munger, Michael C. 2020. “Ideology and the Direction of Causation in the Acquisition and Maintenance of Shared Belief Systems.” Kyklos 73: 392409.Google Scholar
Neller, Todd W., and Lanctot, Marc. 2013. “An Introduction to Counterfactual Regret Minimization.” Paper presented at the Proceedings of Model AI Assignments, The Fourth Symposium on Educational Advances in Artificial Intelligence (EAAI-2013).Google Scholar
Nowak, Martin A. 2006. Evolutionary Dynamics: Exploring the Equations of Life: Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Nowak, Martin A., and Sigmund, K.. 1993. “A Strategy of Win-Stay, Lose-Shift That Outperforms Tit-for-Tat in the Prisoners’ Dilemma Game.” Nature 364: 5658.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Osborne, Martin J, and Rubinstein, Ariel. 1994. A Course in Game Theory: Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Ostrom, Elinor. 2010. “Beyond Markets and States: Polycentric Governance of Complex Economic Systems.” American Economic Review 100: 641–72.Google Scholar
Page, Karen, and Nowak, Martin. 2002. “Unifying Evolutionary Dynamics.” Journal of Theoretical Biology 219: 9398.Google Scholar
Page, Scott E. 2008. The Difference: How the Power of Diversity Creates Better Groups, Firms, Schools, and Societies-New Edition: Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Papadimitriou, Christos H. 2007. “The Complexity of Finding Nash Equilibria.” Algorithmic Game Theory 2: 30.Google Scholar
Pearl, Judea. 2009. Causality: Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Penn, Elizabeth Maggie. 2006. “Alternate Definitions of the Uncovered Set and Their Implications.” Social Choice and Welfare 27: 8387.Google Scholar
Riker, William H. 1962. The Theory of Political Coalitions. New Haven: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Rogers, Alex, Dash, Rajdeep K., Ramchurn, Sarvapali D., Vytelingum, Perukrishnen, and Jennings, Nicholas R.. 2007. “Coordinating Team Players within a Noisy Iterated Prisoner’s Dilemma Tournament.” Theoretical Computer Science 377: 243–59.Google Scholar
Rubinstein, Ariel. 1982. “Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model.” Econometrica 50: 97109.Google Scholar
Schelling, Thomas. 1971. “Dynamic Models of Segregation.” Journal of Mathematical Sociology 1: 143–86.Google Scholar
Schmid, Martin, Burch, Neil, Lanctot, Marc, Moravcik, Matej, Kadlec, Rudolf, and Bowling, Michael. 2019. “Variance Reduction in Monte Carlo Counterfactual Regret Minimization (Vr-Mccfr) for Extensive Form Games Using Baselines.” Paper presented at the Proceedings of the AAAI Conference on Artificial Intelligence.Google Scholar
Schofield, Norman. 1983. “Generic Instability of Majority Rule.” Review of Economic Studies 50: 695705.Google Scholar
Shalizi, Cosma. 2010. “The Bootstrap: Statisticians Can Reuse Their Data to Quantify the Uncertainty of Complex Models.” American Scientist 98: 186–91.Google Scholar
Shu, Feng. 2020. “A Win-Switch-Lose-Stay Strategy Promotes Cooperation in the Evolutionary Games.” Physica A: Statistical Mechanics and Its Applications 555: 124605.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Simon, Herbert. 1955. “A Behavioral Model of Rational Choice.” Quarterly Journal of Economics 69: 99118.Google Scholar
Slapin, Jonathan B., and Proksch, Sven-Oliver. 2008. “A Scaling Model for Estimating Time Series Policy Positions from Texts.” American Journal of Political Science 52: 705–22.Google Scholar
Smith, Alastair. 2004. Election Timing. Cambridge, UK; New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Snyder, James M., Ting, Michael, and Ansolabehere, Stephen. 2005. “Legislative Bargaining under Weighted Voting.” American Economic Review 95: 9811004.Google Scholar
Spoon, Jae-Jae, and Klüver, Heike. 2017. “Does Anybody Notice? How Policy Positions of Coalition Parties Are Perceived by Voters.” European Journal of Political Research 56: 115–32.Google Scholar
Stokes, Donald E. 1963. “Spatial Models of Party Competition.” American Political Science Review 57: 368–77.Google Scholar
Strøm, Kaare, Müller, Wolfgang C., and Bergman, Torbjörn. 2008. Cabinets and Coalition Bargaining: The Democratic Life Cycle in Western Europe: Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Von Neumann, J. and Morgenstern, O. 2007. “Theory of Games and Economic Behavior.” In Theory of Games and Economic Behavior, eds. Kuhn, H.W., von Neumann, J., Morgenstern, O. and Rubinstein, A. Princeton: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul. 1994. Government Survival in Parliamentary Democracies. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul V., and Druckman, James N.. 2006. “The Portfolio Allocation Paradox: An Investigation into the Nature of a Very Strong but Puzzling Relationship.” European Journal of Political Research 45: 635–65.Google Scholar
Warwick, Paul V., and Druckman, James N.. 2001. “Portfolio Salience and the Proportionality of Payoffs in Coalition Governments.” British Journal of Political Science 31: 627–49.Google Scholar
Waugh, Kevin, David Schnizlein, Michael H. Bowling, , and Szafron, Duane. 2009. “Abstraction Pathologies in Extensive Games.” Paper presented at the AAMAS (2).Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • References
  • Scott de Marchi, Duke University, North Carolina, Michael Laver, New York University
  • Book: The Governance Cycle in Parliamentary Democracies
  • Online publication: 02 February 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009315449.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • References
  • Scott de Marchi, Duke University, North Carolina, Michael Laver, New York University
  • Book: The Governance Cycle in Parliamentary Democracies
  • Online publication: 02 February 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009315449.014
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • References
  • Scott de Marchi, Duke University, North Carolina, Michael Laver, New York University
  • Book: The Governance Cycle in Parliamentary Democracies
  • Online publication: 02 February 2023
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781009315449.014
Available formats
×