Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-jkksz Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-29T17:56:33.748Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Institutions and economic growth

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  27 March 2010

Jean-Laurent Rosenthal
Affiliation:
University of California, Los Angeles
Get access

Summary

In the early Middle Ages, improved land was scarce and unimproved land abundant. As a result, lords and villages chose different property rights to govern these two types of land. Property rights to improved land were precisely assigned, giving rise to what we call private property. In contrast, it was not worthwhile to define property rights to unimproved land clearly, for enforcing such rights would have required monitoring unwarranted by the low value of the land. Thus, unimproved land fell under a regime of common rights. This system was efficient as long as it was possible to improve land when relative prices shifted. Yet poorly defined property rights would come to stand in the way of improvements in general and water control in particular. In order to earn a return on their land improvement schemes, water control projectors had to divide costs and benefits between themselves and the owners of the land. Carrying out such a division required an agreement on existing property rights (establishing who owned the marsh) as well as agreement on a rule that translated the original distribution of property rights into a share of the profits (benefits minus costs). Presumably, marshes could have been improved and still remain common. However, in the eighteenth and nineteenth centuries it was generally thought that development was incompatible with common rights. To complicate matters, by the year 1700, altering property rights from common to private required state approval. Hence, the regulation of common land that had begun largely as private contracts between medieval lords and their serfs had become a public institution.

Type
Chapter
Information
The Fruits of Revolution
Property Rights, Litigation and French Agriculture, 1700–1860
, pp. 21 - 36
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1992

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×