Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-cd9895bd7-dzt6s Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-12-22T19:09:27.129Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

3 - Daboya weavers: relations of production, dependence and reciprocity

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  04 August 2010

Esther N. Goody
Affiliation:
New Hall, Cambridge
Get access

Summary

The weaving yard is a rectangular open area sloping down to the river bank, with the three Bakarambasipe compounds framing one long side, and waste ground on the other. The two weaving sheds are set back-to-back in the centre, the warps of the looms in the first shed stretching 10, 20, 30 yards up the rise, those of the second extending down the slope. The clacking of shuttles, each with its own tempo, sets a complex, restless rhythm to which the elders – sewing, silent and almost immobile on the mosque porch – seem oblivious. ‘It must be some kind of a factory’ is one's first thought.

In terms of the scale of production, and the fact that cloth is mainly sold to traders rather than directly to consumers, one may speak of the Daboya textile industry rather than artisan or petty-commodity production. But what sort of an industry is it? What is the nature of the division of labour? How is this articulated? Is specialization organized by a merchant-middleman as in the classic putting-out systems? By an entrepreneur who distributes raw materials, pays the equivalent of wages for the finished component, and then passes this on to the next specialist, thus owning the product at all its stages of production and finally selling it to retailer or consumer? Or is specialization mediated by the market – with the components of each stage of production bought and sold by a series of producers? These are the two obvious Western proto-industrial models for organizing the cooperation between specialists made necessary by the division of labour.

Type
Chapter
Information
From Craft to Industry
The Ethnography of Proto-Industrial Cloth Production
, pp. 50 - 84
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1982

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×