Published online by Cambridge University Press: 30 April 2022
Introduction
Wellbeing has been conceptualised in several ways. Most have argued that wellbeing should be conceived in terms of people's satisfaction with their life, or perhaps ‘happiness’, which will of course vary with their capacities and expectations. Others argue that wellbeing is feeling secure about the future. Economists have, mostly unsuccessfully, tried to argue that the fundamental concept is (economic) welfare. However wellbeing is conceptualised, measurement matters so that governments can know how people are feeling: for example, do communities and individuals feel safe in their homes?
Some argue for a single consistent approach to valuation. Thus, conventional economists use Gross National Product (GNP) and Gross Domestic Product (GDP). However many argue that because GNP and GDP are both just measures of economic activity and not of welfare, we should find ways of valuing non-monetarised components. They propose using stated preference ‘willingness to pay’ techniques (Competition Commission, 2010). This can entail including nonmarketed production and other ‘goods’ such as leisure; making deductions for production which does not contribute to welfare or imposes social or environmental costs; reclassifying items between consumption and investment, or between intermediate and final production; and so on. These types of adjustment all have problems, for example, because they do not and cannot easily take into account income distribution (Carr-Hill and Lintott, 2002). Similarly, while there has been interesting work carried out using time as the basis for valuation (Gershuny, 2011) the basic problem is forcing the assessment of welfare into one dimension.
Instead, many argue that we should move completely away from the framework of national accounts. There are three main approaches, explored overleaf. The first is the postulate that there is a minimum set of basic needs which should be satisfied for everyone, which are, unfortunately, usually aggregated into an index. The second is the investigation into people's quality of life through surveys, whether ‘objectively’ measured (for example, proportions of households without basic amenities) or self-reported (for example, happiness or satisfaction). The third is the eclectic compilation of administrative and survey data according to a list of ‘concerns’.
To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.
To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.