Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-s2hrs Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T16:35:04.856Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - The Risks of Deliberation: Second Opinions

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 June 2014

Adrian Vermeule
Affiliation:
Harvard Law School, Massachusetts
Get access

Summary

A standing anxiety of constitutional rulemaking, especially in the liberal tradition, is that lawmakers within the constitutional system will make hasty or ill-considered decisions under the influence of passion or prejudice. Accordingly, constitutional rulemakers often institute precautions against such decisions; second-opinion mechanisms are a leading example of such precautions. Many institutional structures, rules, and practices have been justified as mechanisms for requiring or permitting decision makers to obtain second opinions. Examples include judicial review of statutes or of agency action, bicameralism, the separation of powers, and certain elements of the law of legislative procedure. These deliberative procedural mechanisms have many attractions, especially from the standpoint of liberal theorists: they are in some sense value-neutral, and thus promise to improve the quality of decision making without dictating substantive outcomes a priori.

Yet additional layers of deliberation and procedure are never costless or risk-free, and second opinions are hardly costless either. Such mechanisms increase the direct costs and opportunity costs of the lawmaking system and, under certain conditions, can actually have perverse results, encouraging rather than suppressing ill-considered decisions. In this chapter, I will attempt a mature consideration of both sides of the ledger. I will thus illustrate both the conditions under which second-opinion mechanisms increase the expected quality of decisions and the overall utility of the constitutional system, and also the conditions under which such mechanisms create countervailing risks or perverse effects, and thus create costs in excess of their benefits.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Elster, Jon, The Night of August 4, 1789: A Study of Social Interaction in Collective Decision-Making, 45 Revue Européenne des Sciences Sociales71 (2007)Google Scholar
Yellin, Joel, High Technology and the Courts: Nuclear Power and the Need for Institutional Reform, 94 Harv. L. Rev. 489, 497 (1981)Google Scholar
Van Alstyne, William, Congress, the President, and the Power to Declare War: A Requiem for Vietnam, 121 U. Pa. L. Rev. 1, 20 (1972)Google Scholar
Black, Charles, A Note on Senatorial Consideration of Supreme Court Nominees, 79 Yale L.J. 657, 660 (1969)Google Scholar
Gewirtzman, Doni, Our Founding Feelings: Emotion, Commitment, and Imagination in Constitutional Culture, 43 U. Rich. L. Rev. 623, 646–47 (2009)Google Scholar
Vermeule, Adrian, The Constitutional Law of Congressional Procedure, 71 U. Chi. L. Rev. 361, 431–34 (2004)Google Scholar
Gersen, Jacob E., Temporary Legislation, 74 U. Chi. L. Rev. 247, 266–73 (2007)Google Scholar
Roach, Kent, The Role and Capacities of Courts and Legislatures in Reviewing Canada’s Anti-Terrorism Law, 24 Windsor Rev. Legal & Soc. Issues5, 6 (2008)Google Scholar
Stone, Harlan F., The Common Law in the United States, 50 Harv. L. Rev. 4, 25 (1936))Google Scholar
Sacks, Albert M., The Supreme Court, 1953 Term – Foreword, 68 Harv. L. Rev. 96 (1954)Google Scholar
Whittington, Keith E., Herbert Wechsler’s Complaint and the Revival of Grand Constitutional Theory, 34 U. Rich. L. Rev509 (2001)Google Scholar
Franck, Thomas M., On Proportionality of Countermeasures in International Law, 102 Am. J. Int’l L. 715, 717 (2008)Google Scholar
Bickel, Alexander M., The Supreme Court, 1960 Term – Foreword: The Passive Virtues, 75 Harv. L. Rev. 40, 77–78 (1961)Google Scholar
Coenen, Dan T., A Constitution of Collaboration: Protecting Fundamental Values with Second-Look Rules of Interbranch Dialogue, 42 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 1575, 1704–08 (2001)Google Scholar
Nagel, Robert F., Disagreement and Interpretation, 56 Law & Contemp. Probs. 11, 13 (1993)Google Scholar
Applegate, John S., A Beginning And Not An End In Itself: The Role of Risk Assessment in Environmental Decision-Making, 63 U. Cin. L. Rev. 1643, 1652 (1995)Google Scholar
Zywicki, Todd & Sanders, Anthony B., Posner, Hayek, and the Economic Analysis of Law, 93 Iowa L. Rev. 559, 579 (2008)Google Scholar
Peller, Gary, In Defense of Habeas Corpus Relitigation, 16 Harv. C.R.-C.L. L. Rev. 579, 602–90 (1982)Google Scholar
Cover, Robert M., The Uses of Jurisdictional Redundancy: Interest, Ideology and Innovation, 22 Wm. & Mary L. Rev. 639, 648 (1981)Google Scholar
Vul, Edward & Pashler, Harold, Measuring the Crowd Within: Probabilistic Representations within Individuals, 19 Pscyhol. Sci. 645 (2008)Google Scholar
Herzog, Stefan M. & Hertwig, Ralph, The Wisdom of Many in One Mind: Improving Individual Judgments with Dialectical Bootstrapping, 20 Psychol. Sci. 231 (2009)Google Scholar
Bayliss, Sir Richard, Second Opinions, 296 Brit. Med. J. 808, 808 (1988)Google Scholar
Vermeule, Adrian, The Parliament of the Experts, 58 Duke L.J. 2231, 2233–35 (2009)Google Scholar
Higginson, Thomas Wentworth, The Birth of a Nation, 68 Harper’s New Monthly Mag. 238, 242 (1884)Google Scholar
Larrick, Richard P. & Soll, Jack B., Intuitions About Combining Opinions: Misappreciation of the Averaging Principle, 52 Mgmt. Sci. 111, 112 (2006)Google Scholar
Yaniv, Ilan, The Benefit of Additional Opinions, 13 Current Directions in Psychol. Sci. 75, 75 (2004)Google Scholar
Banerjee, Abhijit V., A Simple Model of Herd Behavior, 107 Q.J. Econ. 797 (1992)Google Scholar
Bikhchandani, Sushil et al., A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades, 100 J. Pol. Econ. 992 (1992)Google Scholar
Welch, Ivo, Sequential Scales, Learning, and Cascades, 47 J. Fin. 695 (1992)Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur, Ethnic Norms and Their Transformation Through Reputational Cascades, 27 J. Legal Stud. 623 (1998)Google Scholar
Kuran, Timur & Sunstein, Cass, Availability Cascades and Risk Regulation, 51 Stan. L. Rev. 683 (1999)Google Scholar
Fallon, Richard H., Jr., Legitimacy and the Constitution, 118 Harv. L. Rev. 1787 (2005)Google Scholar
Boswell, James, The Journal of a Tour to the Hebrides with Samuel Johnson, L.L.D. 29 (London, Routledge, Warne & Routledge, 1860)
Martin, Suzanne Grisez et al., Impact of a Mandatory Second-Opinion Program on Medicaid Surgery Rates, 20 Med. Care21, 31 (1982)Google Scholar
Stephenson, Matthew C., Information Acquisition and Institutional Design, 124 Harv. L. Rev. 1422, 1438–46 (2011)Google Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×