Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-22T16:43:41.368Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Law and Economic Institutions

from Part I - Determinants of Economic Performance

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  28 March 2008

Bruce Frier
Affiliation:
University of Michigan
Dennis Kehoe
Affiliation:
Tulane University
Walter Scheidel
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California
Ian Morris
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California
Richard P. Saller
Affiliation:
Stanford University, California
Get access

Summary

The landscape of the Greek and Roman economies (as of all other economies both past and present) is invariably configured, not just of individuals, but also of institutions, the organized activity of production and commerce. If population and technology established the basic limits within which the economies of the Greek and Roman worlds could develop, it also seems clear that law and other institutions surrounding the economy represented an exogenous factor affecting productivity in the Greek and Roman worlds. An analysis of the complex relationship between legal institutions and the economy can help us to understand better the basic relationships that characterized the economy of the Greco-Roman world. Law and legal institutions helped determine the forms within which economic activity was organized and had important consequences for the basic welfare of people of all classes in the ancient world. Legal institutions shaped the distribution of wealth between the state and citizens or subjects, between city and countryside, between elite landowners and peasant farmers, and even between masters and slaves. It is thus worth examining how these institutions are likely to have influenced economic behavior, allocation of resources, and predictable outcomes in terms of performance and growth. Did legal institutions serve to promote or inhibit the type of investment that was necessary for greater productivity and ultimately for growth in the ancient economy? Did they foster the concentration of wealth in the hands of a small elite, or instead promote a more even distribution of wealth?

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2007

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Akerlof, G. (1970) “The market for lemons: qualitative uncertainty and the market mechanism,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 84.Google Scholar
Alchian, A. A., and Demsetz, H. (1972) “Production, information costs, and economic organization,” American Economic Review 62.Google Scholar
Allen, D.W. (2000) “Transaction costs,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. 1.
Aubert, J.-J. (1994) Business Managers in Ancient Rome: A Social and Economic Study of Institores, 200 B.C.–A.D. 250. Leiden.
Beaud, M. and Dostaler, G. (1995) Economic Thought Since Keynes: A History and Dictionary of Major Economists, translated by Cauchemez, V.. London and New York.
Becker, G. S. (1992) “On the new institutional economics: comments,” in Werin, L. and Wijkander, H., eds., Contract Economics.Cambridge, MA, and Oxford.Google Scholar
Bouckaert, B. (2000) “Original assignment of private property,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000) (vol. II).
Bouckaert, B. and Geest, G., eds. (2000) Encyclopedia of Law and Economics. (5 vols.) Cheltenham, UK, and Northampton, MA. Online edition (1999): http: //allserv.rug.ac.be/∼gdegeest/generali.htm
Buckland, W. W. (1908) The Roman Law of Slavery. Cambridge.
Clague, C. (1997) “The new institutional economics and economic development,” in Clague, C., ed., Institutions and Economic Development.Baltimore and London.Google Scholar
Coase, R. H. (1988) The Firm, the Market, and the Law. Chicago.
Cohen, E. E. (1992) Athenian Economy and Society: A Banking Perspective. Princeton.
Coleman, J. L. (1988) “Efficiency, utility, and wealth maximization,” in Coleman, J. L., ed., Markets, Morals, and the Law.London.Google Scholar
Cooter, R. and Ulen, T. (2000) Law and Economics. 3rd edn. Reading, MA.
Crawford, D. J. (1976) “Imperial estates,” in Finley, M. I., ed., Studies in Roman Property.Cambridge.Google Scholar
D’Arms, J. H. (1981) Commerce and Social Standing in Ancient Rome. Cambridge, MA.
De Ligt, L. (1993a) Fairs and Markets in the Roman Empire: Economic and Social Aspects of Periodic Trade in a Pre-Industrial Society. Amsterdam.
De Ligt, L. (1999) “Legal history and economic history: the case of the actiones adiecticiae qualitatis,” Tijdschrift voor Rechtsgeschiedenis 47.Google Scholar
De Meza, D. (1998) “The Coase theorem,” in Newman, P., ed., The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics and the Law.London and New York.Google Scholar
Domar, E. D. (1970) “The causes of slavery or serfdom: a hypothesis,” Journal of Economic History 30.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, T. (1990) Economic Behavior and Institutions. Cambridge.
Engerman, S. L. (1986) “Slavery and emancipation in comparative perspective: a look at some recent debates,” Journal of Economic History 46.Google Scholar
Erdkamp, P. (1999) “Agriculture, underemployment, and the cost of rural labor in the Roman world,” CQ 49.Google Scholar
Erdkamp, P. (2001) “Beyond the limits of the ‘consumer city’: a model of the urban and rural economy in the Roman world,” Historia 50.3.Google Scholar
Fenoaltea, S. (1984) “Slavery and supervision in comparative perspective: a model,” Journal of Economic History 44.Google Scholar
Frayn, J. M. (1993) Markets and Fairs in Roman Italy: Their Social and Economic Importance from the Second Century BC to the Third Century AD. Oxford.
Friedman, M. (1953) “The methodology of positive economics,” in Essays in Positive Economics. Chicago Google Scholar
Frier, B. W. (1993a) “Law, economics, and disasters down on the farm: Remissio mercedis revisited,” BIDR 31/32 Google Scholar
Furubotn, E. G. and Richter, R. (1998) Institutions and Economic Theory: The Contribution of the New Institutional Economics. Ann Arbor, MI.
Garnsey, P. and Saller, R. (1987) The Roman Empire: Economy, Society, and Culture. Berkeley.
Greenberg, A. S. (1951) “The ancient lineage of trade-marks,” Journal of the Patent Office Society 33.Google Scholar
Harrison, A. R. W. (1968) The Law of Athens: The Family and Property. Oxford.
Hodgson, G. M. (1994) “The return of institutional economics,” in Smelser, N. J. and Swedberg, R., eds., The Handbook of Economic Sociology.Princeton.Google Scholar
Hodgson, G. M. (1999) Evolution and Institutions: On Evolutionary Economics and the Evolution of Economics. Cheltenham and Northampton, MA.
Hviid, M. (2000) “Long-term contracts and relational contracts,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. III.
Jones, E. L. (1988) Growth Recurring: Economic Change in World History. Oxford.
Kaser, M. (1971) Das römische Privatrecht. Erster Abschnitt, Das altrömische, das vorklassische und klassische Recht. 2nd edn. Munich.
Kehoe, D. P. (1988b) “Allocation of risk and investment on the estates of Pliny the younger,” Chiron 18.Google Scholar
Kehoe, D. P. (1997) Investment, Profit, and Tenancy: The Jurists and the Roman Agrarian Economy. Ann Arbor, MI.
Klein, P. G. (2000) “New institutional economics,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000) vol. 1.
Landis, W. M. and Posner, R. A. (2003) The Economic Structure of Intellectual Property Law. Cambridge, MA.
Liebowitz, S. J. and Margolis, S. E. (2000) “Path dependence,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. 1.
Macneil, I. R. (1978) “Contracts: adjustment of long-term economic relations under classical, neoclassical, and relational contract law,” Northwestern University Law Review 79.Google Scholar
McMillan, J. (2002) Reinventing the Bazaar. New York and London.
Medema, S. G. and Zerbe, R. O. Jr. (2000) “The Coase Theorem,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. I.
Mercuro, N. and Medema, S. G. (1997) Economics and the Law: From Posner to Post-Modernism. Princeton.
Millett, P. (1983) “Maritime loans and the structure of credit in fourth-century Athens,” in Garnsey, et al., eds. (1983).
Mnookin, R. H. and Kornhauser, L. (1979) “Bargaining in the shadow of the law: the case of divorce,” Yale Law Journal 88.Google Scholar
North, D. C. (1981) Structure and Change in Economic History. New York and London.
North, D. C. (1990) Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. Cambridge.
North, D. C. (1991) “Institutions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 5.Google Scholar
Panther, S. (2000) “Non-legal sanctions,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. 1.
Parássoglou, G. M. (1978) Imperial Estates in Roman Egypt. Amsterdam.
Plescia, J. (1984) “The development of agency in Roman law,” Labeo 30.Google Scholar
Rathbone, D. (1991) Economic Rationalism and Rural Society in Third-Century AD Egypt: The Heroninos Archive and the Appianus Estate. Cambridge.
Rutherford, M. (1994) Institutions in Economics: The Old and the New Institutionalism. Cambridge.
Schickert, K. (2005) Der Schutz literarischer Urheberschaft im Rom der klassischen Antike. Tübingen.
Schotter, A. (1981) The Economic Theory of Social Institutions. Cambridge.
Schwartz, W. F. (2000) “Legal error,” in Bouckaert, and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. 1.
Simon, H. A. (1983) Reason in Human Affairs. Stanford.
Speidel, M. A. (1992) “Roman army pay scales,” JRS 82.Google Scholar
Treggiari, S. (1991b) Roman Marriage. Iusti Coniuges from the Time of Cicero to the Time of Ulpian. Oxford.
Ulen, T. S. (2000) “Rational choice theory in law and economics,” in Bouckaert, , and Geest, , eds. (2000), vol. 1.
Williamson, O. E. (1979) “Transaction-cost economics: the governance of contractual relations,” Journal of Law and Economics 22.Google Scholar
Williamson, O. E. (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting. New York and London.
Williamson, O. E. (1996) The Mechanisms of Governance. New York.
Williamson, O. E. and Winter, S. G., eds. (1993) The Nature of the Firm: Origins, Evolution, and Development. New York.
Wright, G. (1978) The Political Economy of the Cotton South: Households, Markets, and Wealth in the Nineteenth Century. New York.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×