Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-25T06:40:29.117Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false
This chapter is part of a book that is no longer available to purchase from Cambridge Core

2 - Scenarios Involving Marginal Analysis

Julie Glass
Affiliation:
California State University
Lynn Paringer
Affiliation:
California State University
Jane Lopus
Affiliation:
California State University
Warren Page
Affiliation:
New York City College of Technology, City University of New York
Get access

Summary

Introduction

Many economic decisions involve investigating the effects of small changes on various outcomes. Analyzing the effects of small or incremental changes allows us to investigate factors affecting cost, revenue, and profit in microeconomics. Economists use the term “marginal” to connote the change due to a one unit change in something. For example, to an economist, marginal cost (MC) means the change in total cost from producing one more unit of q, and marginal revenue (MR) is the change in total revenue from selling one more unit of q. Since the rate of change at a value is represented by the derivative, the word “marginal” in economics is approximated by the derivative. Thus, MC = d(TC)/dq. Knowing how a function changes can also be useful in economics situations where it may be difficult to obtain exact data, but where approximations will suffice for decision-making.

Fixed costs (e.g., lease payments on a rented building, fixed monthly fee for the business answer phone, installment payments for purchased equipment) are incurred regardless of whether any output is generated, and do not depend on the amount of output the firm produces. Variable costs vary with the output level of the firm. A cost function is derived from observation of the relationship between costs and level of output. A principal goal of the economist/mathematician is to model the costs of operation as closely as possible to what actually occurs in the production process and to tie the costs of production to the level of output being produced.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Mathematical Association of America
Print publication year: 2013

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×