Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-l7hp2 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-26T16:13:55.843Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Conclusion

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  23 September 2022

Alain Naef
Affiliation:
University of California, Berkeley

Summary

In 1992, the United Kingdom had reluctantly joined the ERM, mainly to help with inflation management at home. But in the wake of the Maastricht referendum in France, pressure mounted on sterling and other European currencies. The Government did not want to ease the pressure by increasing interest rates. This would have displeased mortgage owners that voted it in. The small tension turned into a full currency crisis. Following remarks by the Bundesbank president, the Bank had to spend $22 billion yet failed to save the pound. Britain left the ERM and stopped managing the pound altogether. The focus was now no longer on exchange rates but on inflation targeting.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2022
Creative Commons
Creative Common License - CCCreative Common License - BYCreative Common License - NCCreative Common License - ND
This content is Open Access and distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution licence CC-BY-NC-ND 4.0 https://creativecommons.org/cclicenses/

The 1992 ERM crisis was the pound’s last currency crisis. Or at least the last one where the Bank managed sterling. The market had won. The Bank no longer dared to fight against speculators, and international finance became too large to control. The Bank switched to inflation targeting and put foreign exchange intervention aside. There were some minor episodes of interventions, notably in 2011 to support the yen. An earthquake and tsunami in Japan had pushed the yen down and the G7 conducted a concerted intervention. Apart from this, intervention had lost its place in the normal arsenal of the Bank.

Strictly speaking, 1992 was not sterling’s last currency crisis. Brexit and the ensuing uncertainty triggered a series of crises. The long process from the referendum, to triggering Article 50, to finally leaving the EU all came with its fair share of shocks to the currency. But the difference with the episodes studied in this book is that the Bank was a bystander. The pound was now facing its troubles wholly unassisted by Bank of England dealers.

The end of the intervention era meant less stress for policymakers at the Bank. There were no more late-night calls to decide how much to spend to defend sterling in Tokyo or New York. Free float meant less embarrassment for Bank officials and policymakers. They no longer had to publicly admit defeat after an unexpected devaluation. By focusing only on inflation, the Bank became more independent. It could now set its own policy, focusing on inflation and not exchange rate management, which still today is the prerogative of the government.

But is intervention still a relevant policy tool today? The academic literature since the 1990s has progressively moved in that direction.Footnote 1 Some of foreign exchange intervention’s most virulent critics have toned down their views. Even the IMF, once opposed to foreign exchange intervention, has taken a more conciliatory view in its revised policy framework.Footnote 2 Intervention, the IMF argues, should not be used to generate competitive advantages. But it could be used to help steer monetary policy. This change was in part a reaction to the 2008 Financial Crisis, when traditional monetary policy lost some edge.

Foreign exchange intervention is now a legitimate policy tool. Britain’s experience over half a century offers some policy lessons. First, intervention usually does not work when it is not aligned with economic fundamentals. That is, intervention alone is rarely going to protect a country from what international finance thinks of its economy. Interest rates are usually a much more powerful tool to adjust international capital flows. They show real commitment to a policy while intervention alone does not.

Another lesson is that secrecy might not be the best solution. Transparency with market actors helps better guide exchange rates. Intervening on currency markets without communicating about it might be inefficient. The 1976 IMF crisis of the pound is a case in point. The Bank of England tried to secretly devalue sterling. Market actors did not understand what the Bank of England was trying to communicate, triggering a currency crisis.

Finally, cooperation among central banks can be powerful enough to move markets, but there are limits. The Gold Pool is a good example. Most major Western central banks joining forces to support the gold price provided stability to the international monetary system. But even the best forms of international technical cooperation can be stopped by political will. This was the case for the election of Nixon, which broke down central bank cooperation with the Fed.

Footnotes

1 Emmanuel Farhi and Matteo Maggiori, ‘A Model of the International Monetary System’, Working Paper (National Bureau of Economic Research, May 2016), https://doi.org/10.3386/w22295.

2 Tobias Adrian, Gita Gopinath and Martin Mühleisen, ‘Toward an Integrated Policy Framework for Open Economies’, IMF Policy Brief, 2020, https://www.imf.org/en/Publications/Policy-Papers/Issues/2020/10/08/Toward-an-Integrated-Policy-Framework-49813.

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

  • Conclusion
  • Alain Naef, University of California, Berkeley
  • Book: An Exchange Rate History of the United Kingdom
  • Online publication: 23 September 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108878333.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

  • Conclusion
  • Alain Naef, University of California, Berkeley
  • Book: An Exchange Rate History of the United Kingdom
  • Online publication: 23 September 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108878333.016
Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

  • Conclusion
  • Alain Naef, University of California, Berkeley
  • Book: An Exchange Rate History of the United Kingdom
  • Online publication: 23 September 2022
  • Chapter DOI: https://doi.org/10.1017/9781108878333.016
Available formats
×