Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-ndw9j Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-09T05:25:59.306Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

4 - How Severe Is the Time-Inconsistency Problem in Monetary Policy?

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 January 2010

Mathias Dewatripont
Affiliation:
Université Libre de Bruxelles
Lars Peter Hansen
Affiliation:
University of Chicago
Stephen J. Turnovsky
Affiliation:
University of Washington
Get access

Summary

INTRODUCTION

The history of inflation in the United States and other countries has occasionally been quite bad. Are the bad experiences the consequence of policy errors? Or does the problem lie with the nature of monetary institutions? The second possibility has beene xplored ina long literature, which starts at least with Kydland and Prescott (1977) and Barro and Gordon (1983). This paper seeks to make a contribution to that literature.

The Kydland–Prescott and Barro–Gordon literature focuses on the extent to which monetary institutions allow policymakers to commit to future policies. A key result is that if policymakers cannot commit to future policies, inflation rates are higher than if they can commit. That is, there is a time-inconsistency problem that introduces a systematic inflation bias. This paper investigates the magnitude of the inflation bias in two standard general equilibrium models. One is the cash–credit good model of Lucas and Stokey (1983). The other is the limited-participation model of money described in Christiano, Eichenbaum, and Evans (1997). We find that, for a large range of parameter values, there is no inflation bias.

In the Kydland–Prescott and Barro–Gordon literature, equilibrium inflationin the absence of commitment is the outcome of anin terplay between the benefits and costs of inflation. For the most part, this literature consists of reduced-form models. Our general equilibrium models in corporate the kinds of benefits and costs that seem to motivate the reduced-form specifications. To understand these benefits and costs, we must first explain why money is not neutral inour models.

Type
Chapter
Information
Advances in Economics and Econometrics
Theory and Applications, Eighth World Congress
, pp. 123 - 150
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2003

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×