Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T04:31:49.816Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

5 - Power and path dependence

from Part III - Tools for temporal analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2015

Paul Pierson
Affiliation:
University of California
James Mahoney
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Illinois
Kathleen Thelen
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Get access

Summary

A decade after a pointed critique of the discipline's retreat from the study of power (Moe 2005), evidence of a “power-free political science” is more widespread than ever. At least as it is practiced in the field of American politics – which plays a leading role in shaping the contours of the discipline as a whole – power and influence remain elusive, unhelpful, and marginalized concepts. When Americanists have gone looking for “power” – decisive political advantages for those with more resources – they mostly haven't found it. There is very little evidence showing that campaign contributions or lobbying systematically effect roll call votes in Congress (Schlozman, Verba, and Brady 2012). Stephen Ansolabehere, John de Figueiredo, and James Snyder provocatively asked, “Why is there so little money in American politics?” They found that although this was partly because donating raised big collective action problems, it was equally because money seemed to make little difference to electoral outcomes (Ansolabehere, de Figueiredo, and Snyder 2003). A broad and sophisticated study of lobbying from some of the leading scholars of interest groups recently reported that it could “find virtually no linkage between [group] resources and outcomes” (Baumgartner et al. 2009). Of course, the inability to find power in empirical research is especially puzzling given the extraordinary increase in economic inequality in the United States over the past generation.

Nor is the elusiveness of power just an empirical matter. More fundamentally, power doesn't really fit in the leading frameworks for studying American politics. These frameworks typically depict politics as fluid or “plastic.” Elections follow a Downsian logic; this cycle's loser adjusts and becomes the next cycle's winner. Take out incumbency, David Mayhew observes, and presidential elections over the past century or so have been essentially a coin toss between the two parties (Mayhew 2002). Legislatures are under the sway of Arrow's paradox of voting so that losers in any legislative struggle are well positioned to cycle back into the winner's position.

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Acemoglu, Daron, and Robinson, James. 2012. Why Nations Fail. New York: Crown Books.Google Scholar
Akram, Fares, and Rudoren, Jodi. 2013. “To Shape Young Palestinians, Hamas Creates Its Own Textbooks.” New York Times, November 4, p. A1.
Ansolabehere, Stephen, de Figueiredo, John, and Snyder, James. 2003. “Why Is There So Little Money in American Politics?”Journal of Economic Perspectives 17:105–30.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bachrach, Peter, and Baratz, Morton S.. 1962. “The Two Faces of Power.” American Political Science Review 56:947–52.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, Larry. 2010. Unequal Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., Berry, Jeffrey M., Hojnacki, Marie, Kimball, David C., and Leech, Beth L.. 2009. Lobbying and Policy Change: Who Wins, Who Loses, and Why. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Berman, Sheri. 2003. “Islamism, Revolution, and Civil Society.” Perspectives on Politics 1:257–72.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Broockman, David. 2012. “The ‘Problem of Preferences’: Medicare and Business Support for the Welfare State.” Studies in American Political Development 26 (2): 83–106.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cameron, Charles. 2000. Veto Bargaining. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Campbell, Andrea. 2003. How Policies Make Citizens. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Capoccia, Giovanni, and Keleman, Daniel. 2007. “The Study of Critical Junctures: Theory, Narrative, and Counterfactuals in Historical Institutionalism.” World Politics 59:341–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Carpenter, Daniel. 2001. The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cox, Gary, and McCubbins, Matthew. 1993. Legislative Leviathan: Party Government in the House. Berkeley: University of California Press.Google Scholar
Crenson, Matthew A. 1971. The Un-Politics of Air Pollution: A Study of Non-Decision-Making in the Cities. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A. 1961. Who Governs? Democracy and Power in an American City. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A 1982. Dilemmas of Pluralist Democracy. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert A., and Lindblom, Charles E.. 1953. Politics, Economics and Welfare: Planning and Politico-Economic Systems Resolved into Basic Social Processes. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Derthick, Martha. 1979. Policymaking for Social Security. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Edsall, Thomas. 1984. The New Politics of Inequality. New York: W. W. Norton.Google Scholar
Eisenhower, Dwight D. (1954) 1970. “Letter to Edgar Newton Eisenhower.” Document #1147, November 8. In The Papers of Dwight David Eisenhower, Vol. XV, edited by Louis Galambos. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Erickson, Robert, MacKuen, Michael, and Stimson, James. 2002. The Macro Polity. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Eskridge, William, and Ferejohn, John. 2001. “Super Statutes.” Duke Law Journal 50:1215.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Esping-Andersen, Gøsta. 1990. Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Franzese, Robert. 1999. “Partially Independent Central Banks, Politically Responsive Governments, and Inflation.” American Journal of Political Science 43:681–76.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Friedrich, Carl J. 1963. Man and His Government. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Gaventa, John. 1982. Power and Powerlessness. Champaign-Urbana: University of Illinois Press.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin. 2012. Affluence and Influence. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gilens, Martin, and Page, Benjamin I.. 2014. “Testing Theories of American Politics: Elites, Interest Groups, and Average Citizens.” Perspectives on Politics 12 (3): 564–81.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gourevitch, Peter A., and Shinn, James. 2007. Political Power and Corporate Control: The New Global Politics of Corporate Governance. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gruber, Lloyd. 2000. Ruling the World: Power Politics and the Rise of Supranational Institutions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob, and Pierson, Paul. 2002. “Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State.” Politics and Society 30:277–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob, and Pierson, Paul 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics: How Washington Made the Rich Richer – and Turned Its Back on the Middle Class. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob, and Pierson, Paul 2014. “After the ‘Master Theory’: Downs, Schattschneider, and the Rebirth of Policy-Focused Analysis.” Perspectives on Politics 12 (3): 643–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hall, Peter A. 2010. “Politics as a Process Structured in Space and Time.” Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, Washington, DC, September 2–5.
Huber, Evelyn, and Stephens, John. 2001. Development and Crisis of the Welfare State. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Huber, Evelyn, and Stephens, John 2012. Democracy and the Left: Social Policy and Inequality in Latin America. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Keyssar, Alex. 2000. The Right to Vote. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Korpi, Walter. 1985. “Power Resources Approach vs. Action and Conflict: On Causal and Intentional Explanations in the Study of Power.” Sociological Theory 3 (2): 31–45.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lang, Kurt, and Lang, Gladys Engel. 2012. “What Is This Thing We Call Public Opinion? Reflections on the Spiral of Silence.” International Journal of Public Opinion Research 24 (3): 368–86.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lindblom, Charles E. 1977. Politics and Markets. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Lukes, Stephen. 1974. Power: A Radical View. London: Macmillan.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, James. 2000. “Path Dependence in Historical Sociology.” Theory and Society 29 (4): 507–48.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mayhew, David. 2002. Electoral Realignments: A Critique of an American Genre. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
McKelvey, Richard. 1976. Intransitivities in Multidimensional Voting Models and Some Implications for Agenda Control.” Journal of Economic Theory 12 (3): 472–82.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Meltzer, Alan H., and Richard, Scott F.. 1981. “A Rational Theory of the Size of Government.” Journal of Political Economy 89 (5): 914–27.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 2005. “Power and Political Institutions.” Perspectives on Politics 3:215–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Noelle-Neuman, Elisabeth. 1974. “The Spiral of Silence: A Theory of Public Opinion.” Journal of Communication 24:43–51.Google Scholar
Patashnik, Eric. 2008. After Reform. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics.” American Political Science Review 94:251–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions and Social Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul 2006. “Public Policies as Institutions.” In Rethinking Institutions: The Art of the State, edited by Skowronek, Stephen, Shapiro, Ian, and Galvin, Daniel, 114–34. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Polsby, Nelson. 1980. Community Power and Political Theory: A Further Look at Problems of Evidence and Inference. 2nd ed. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Remnick, David. 2013. “The Party Faithful: The Settlers Move to Annex the West Bank – and Israeli Politics.” The New Yorker, January 21.
Rueschemeyer, Dietrich, Stephens, Evelyn, and Stephens, John. 1992. Capitalist Development and Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Schattschneider, E. E. 1960. The Semi-Sovereign People. New York: Holt, Rinehart and Winston.Google Scholar
Schlozman, Kay Leyman, Verba, Sidney, and Brady, Henry E.. 2012. The Unheavenly Chorus: Unequal Political Voice and the Broken Promise of American Democracy. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Siegel, Reva B. 2008. “Dead or Alive: Originalism as Popular Constitutionalism in Heller.” Harvard Law Review 122:191–245.Google Scholar
Smith, Mark. 2000. American Business and Political Power. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Starr, Paul. 2014. “Three Degrees of Entrenchment: Power, Policy, Structure.” Unpublished manuscript, Princeton University Department of Sociology.
Thelen, Kathleen. 2004. How Institutions Evolve. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Vogel, David. 1989. Fluctuating Fortunes. New York: Basic Books.Google Scholar
Wolfinger, Raymond E. 1971. “Nondecisions and the Study of Local Politics.” American Political Science Review 65:1063–80.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wuthnow, Robert. 1989. Communities of Discourse. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Zaller, John R. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×