Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-j824f Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-17T18:15:55.587Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

7 - Drift and conversion: hidden faces of institutional change

from Part III - Tools for temporal analysis

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  05 July 2015

Jacob S. Hacker
Affiliation:
Yale University
Paul Pierson
Affiliation:
University of California
Kathleen Thelen
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
James Mahoney
Affiliation:
Northwestern University, Illinois
Kathleen Thelen
Affiliation:
Massachusetts Institute of Technology
Get access

Summary

Until recently, institutionally minded scholars in the social sciences generally treated institutions as fixed. Whether defined as the rules of the political game, the standard operating procedures of bureaucracies, or the regularized norms guiding organizational behavior, institutions were associated with stability and were invoked as independent or intervening variables to explain persistent cross-national differences in outcomes. More recent work in the field, however, has attempted to provide greater insight into how institutions evolve and how institutional effects can change over time. Instead of seeing institutions as largely unchanging features of the political environment, these arguments seek to specify what kinds of institutional changes propelled by what kinds of social processes are most likely under what kinds of political configurations.

This chapter advances this more recent agenda, examining two important, common, and theoretically explicable processes through which institutional effects change over time, which we call “drift” and “conversion.” Drift occurs when institutions or policies are deliberately held in place while their context shifts in ways that alter their effects. A simple example is the US minimum wage, which is not indexed to inflation and thus declines in value as prices rise unless new federal legislation is enacted. Those wishing to effect change through drift need only prevent the updating of existing rules. Drift thus depends on how sensitive the effects of an institution are to its context, whether policies are designed in ways that foster updating in the face of changing circumstances, and whether it is easy or difficult to block such updating.

Conversion, by contrast, occurs when political actors are able to redirect institutions or policies toward purposes beyond their original intent. An example is the ability of corporations to use the Sherman Antitrust Act of 1890 to hinder labor unions. Passed amid widespread concern about corporate collusion, the legislation was meant to break up business trusts that were “in restraint of trade.” Yet corporations managed to convince federal courts that union organizing was “in restraint of trade.”

Type
Chapter
Information
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 2015

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

References

Abbott, Kenneth W., Keohane, Robert O., Moravcsik, Andrew, Slaughter, Anne-Marie, and Snidal, Duncan. 2000. “The Concept of Legalization.” International Organization 54 (3): 401–419.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Alter, Karen J. 2000. “The European Union's Legal System and Domestic Policy: Spillover or Backlash?”International Organization 54 (3): 489–518.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Arnold, R. Douglas. 1990. The Logic of Congressional Action. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
Barnes, Jeb. 2007. “Bringing the Courts Back In: Interbranch Perspectives on the Role of Courts in American Politics and Policy Making.” Annual Review of Political Science 10:25–43.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barnes, Jeb, and Burke, Thomas. 2006. “The Diffusion of Rights: From Rights on the Books to Organizational Rights Practices.” Law and Society Review 40 (3): 493–524.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bartels, Larry M. 2008. Unequal Democracy: The Political Economy of the New Gilded Age. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Baumgartner, Frank R., and Jones, Bryan D.. 1993. Agendas and Instability in American Politics. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Bawn, Kathleen, Cohena, Martin, Karola, David, Masketa, Seth, Noela, Hans, and Zaller, John. 2012. “A Theory of Political Parties: Groups, Policy Demands, and Nominations in American Politics.” Perspectives on Politics 10 (3): 571–97.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Béland, Daniel. 2007. “Ideas and Institutional Change in Social Security: Conversion, Layering, and Policy Drift.” Social Science Quarterly 88 (1): 20–38.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bendor, Jonathan, Glazer, A., and Hammond, T.. 2001. “Theories of Delegation.” Annual Review of Political Science 4:235–69.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Burke, Thomas, and Scherer, Nancy. 2012. “The Bush Administration and the Uses of Judicial Politics.” In Building Coalitions: Making Policy: The Politics of the Clinton, Bush, and Obama Presidencies, edited by Levin, M., DiSalvo, D., and Shapiro, M., 215–46. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Callander, Steven, and Krehbiel, Keith. 2012. Gridlock and Delegation in a Changing World. Working Paper No. 2100, Stanford Graduate School of Business. www.gsb.stanford.edu/faculty-research/working-papers/gridlock-delegation-changing-world.Google Scholar
Carpenter, Daniel. 2001. The Forging of Bureaucratic Autonomy: Networks, Reputations, and Policy Innovation in Executive Agencies. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Cohen, Marty, Karol, David, Noel, Hans, and Zaller, John. 2008. The Party Decides. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Culpepper, Pepper. 2011. Quiet Politics and Business Power. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Dahl, Robert. 1961. Who Governs: Democracy and Power in an American City. New Haven, CT: Yale University Press.Google Scholar
de Figueiredo, John M. 2000. Litigating Regulation: Corporate Strategy in Telecommunications. Academy of Management Proceedings, A1–A6. web.mit.edu/jdefig/www/papers/litigation_regulation.pdf.Google Scholar
Epp, Charles. 1998. The Rights Revolution: Lawyers, Activists, and Supreme Courts in Comparative Perspective. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.Google Scholar
Epp, Charles 2009. Making Rights Real: Activists, Bureaucrats, and the Creation of the Legalistic State. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Epstein, Lee, Landes, William M., and Posner, Richard A.. 2013. “How Business Fares in the Supreme Court.” Minnesota Law Review 97:1431–72.Google Scholar
Falleti, Tulia, and Lynch, Julia. 2009. “Context and Causal Mechanisms in Political Analysis.” Comparative Political Studies 42 (9): 1143–66.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frymer, Paul. 2003. “Acting When Elected Officials Won't: Federal Courts and Civil Rights Enforcement in US Labor Unions, 1935–85.” American Political Science Review 97:483–99.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Frymer, Paul 2007. Black and Blue: African Americans, the Labor Movement, and the Decline of the Democratic Party. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Galanter, Marc. 1974. “Why the ‘Haves’ Come Out Ahead: Speculations on the Limits of Legal Change.” Law and Society Review 9 (1): 165–230.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S. 2004. “Privatizing Risk without Privatizing the Welfare State: The Hidden Politics of Social Policy Retrenchment in the United States.” American Political Science Review 98 (2): 243–60.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S. 2005. “Policy Drift: The Hidden Politics of US Welfare State Retrenchment.” In Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, edited by Streeck, W. and Thelen, K., 40–82. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul. 2002. “Business Power and Social Policy: Employers and the Formation of the American Welfare State.”Politics & Society 30 (2): 277–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul 2005. “Abandoning the Middle: The Bush Tax Cuts and the Limits of Democratic Control.” Perspectives on Politics 3 (1): 33–55.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul 2010. Winner-Take-All Politics. New York: Simon and Schuster.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul 2011. Drift and Democracy: The Neglected Politics of Policy Inaction. Paper prepared for the Working Group on Institutional Change, Cambridge, MA, February.Google Scholar
Hacker, Jacob S., and Pierson, Paul 2014. “After the ‘Master Theory’: Downs, Schattschneider, and the Rebirth of Policy-Focused Analysis.” Perspectives on Politics 12(3): 643–62.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hardin, Russell. 1989. “Why a Constitution?” In The Federalist Papers and the New Institutionalism, edited by Grofman, Bernard and Wittman, Donald, 100–19. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Helmke, Gretchen, and Levitsky, Steven, eds. 2006. Informal Institutions and Democracy: Lessons from Latin America. Baltimore: Johns Hopkins University Press.Google Scholar
Immergut, Ellen. 1992. Health Politics: Interests and Institutions in Western Europe. New York: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
Johnson, Simon, and Kwak, James. 2010. 13 Bankers: The Wall Street Takeover and the Next Financial Meltdown. New York: Pantheon.Google Scholar
Jönsson, Christer, and Tallberg, Jonas. 1998. Compliance and Post-Agreement Bargaining. European Journal of International Relations 4 (4): 371–408.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Judt, Tony. 2008. Postwar: A History of Europe Since 1945. New York: Penguin.Google Scholar
Kagan, Robert A. 2003. Adversarial Legalism and American Government. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Kingdon, John W. 1984. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. New York: HarperCollins.Google Scholar
Krehbiel, Keith. 1998. Pivotal Politics: A Theory of U.S. Lawmaking. Chicago: University of Chicago Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Layzer, Judith. 2012. Open for Business: Conservatives' Opposition to Environmental Regulation. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Murillo, Maria Victoria. 2009. “Variation in Institutional Strength.” Annual Review of Political Science 12:115–33.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Levitsky, Steven, and Slater, Dan. 2011. “Ruling Politics: The Formal and Informal Foundations of Institutional Reform.” In Ruling Politics, edited by Levitsky, S. and Slater, D.. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.Google Scholar
Lieberman, Robert C. 2007. Private Power and American Bureaucracy: The EEOC and Civil Rights Enforcement. Columbia University. http://web1.millercenter.org/apd/colloquia/pdf/col_2005_0318_lieberman.pdf.Google Scholar
Lindblom, Charles E. 1982. “The Market as Prison.” Journal of Politics 44 (2): 324–36.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lynch, Julia. 2006. Age in the Welfare State: The Origins of Social Spending on Pensioners, Workers, and Children. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mahoney, James, and Thelen, Kathleen, eds. 2010. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.Google Scholar
McCarty, Nolan, Poole, Keith T., and Rosenthal, Howard. 2006. Polarized America. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.Google Scholar
McCubbins, Mathew D., Noll, Roger G., and Weingast, Barry R.. 1987. “Administrative Procedures as Instruments of Political Control.” Journal of Law, Economics, and Organization 3:243–77.Google Scholar
Melnick, R. Shep. 1994. Between the Lines: Interpreting Welfare Rights. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
“Minister gegen Über.” 2014. Der Spiegel, September 15, 71.
Moe, Terry M. 1989. “The Politics of Bureaucratic Structure.” In Can the Government Govern?, edited by Chubb, J. and Peterson, P., 267–329. Washington, DC: The Brookings Institution.Google Scholar
Moe, Terry M. 1990. “The Politics of Structural Choice: Toward a Theory of Public Bureaucracy.” In Organization Theory: From Chester Barnard to the Present and Beyond, edited by Williamson, O. E., 116–53. New York: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Offe, Claus, and Wiesenthal, Helmut. 1980. “Two Logics of Collective Action: Theoretical Notes on Social Class and Organizational Form.” Political Power and Social Theory 1:67–115.Google Scholar
Palier, Bruno. 2005. “Ambiguous Agreement, Cumulative Change: French Social Policy in the 1990s.” In Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies, edited by Streeck, Wolfgang and Thelen, Kathleen, 127–44. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Patashnik, Eric M. 2008. Reforms at Risk: What Happens After Major Policy Changes Are Enacted. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Perrow, Charles. 1986. Complex Organizations: A Critical Essay. 3rd ed. New York: McGraw-Hill.Google Scholar
Pierson, Paul. 2000. “Path Dependence, Increasing Returns, and Political Science.” American Political Science Review 94 (2): 251–67.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Pierson, Paul 2006. “Public Policies as Institutions.” In Rethinking Political Institutions: The Art of the State, edited by Shapiro, Ian, Skowronek, Stephen, and Galvin, Daniel, 114–31. New York: New York University Press.Google Scholar
Scharpf, Fritz. 2009. Föderalismusreform: Kein Ausweg aus der Politikverflectungsfalle?Frankfurt: Campus Verlag.Google Scholar
Scheingold, Stuart. 2004. The Politics of Rights: Lawyers, Public Policy, and Political Change. Ann Arbor: University of Michigan Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schneider, Ben Ross. 2013. Hierarchical Capitalism in Latin America: Business, Labor and the Challenges of Equitable Development. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Shepsle, Kenneth A. 1986. “Institutional Equilibrium and Equilibrium Institutions.” In Political Science: The Science of Politics, edited by Weisberg, H.. New York: Agathon.Google Scholar
Stepan, Alfred, and Linz, Juan J.. 2011. “Comparative Perspectives on Inequality and the Quality of Democracy in the United States.” Perspectives on Politics 9 (4): 841–56.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Streeck, Wolfgang, and Thelen, Kathleen. 2005. Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. Oxford: Oxford University Press.Google Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen. 1999. “Historical Institutionalism in Comparative Politics.” Annual Review of Political Science 2:369–404.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Thelen, Kathleen 2004. How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Comparative-Historical Perspective. New York: Cambridge University Press.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tsebelis, George. 1995. “Decision Making in Political Systems: Veto Players in Presidentialism, Parliamentarism, Multicameralism, and Multipartyism.” British Journal of Political Science 25 (3): 289–325.CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Wawro, Gregory J., and Schickler, Eric. 2007. Filibuster: Obstruction and Lawmaking in the U.S. Senate. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Weaver, R. Kent. 1986. “The Politics of Blame Avoidance.” Journal of Public Policy 6 (4): 371–98.CrossRefGoogle Scholar

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×