Skip to main content Accessibility help
×
Hostname: page-component-78c5997874-v9fdk Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-05T14:27:37.850Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

16 - Risky lessons: Conditions for organizational learning

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  07 October 2011

Baruch Fischhoff
Affiliation:
Carnegie Mellon University, Pittsburgh, PA
Zvi Lanir
Affiliation:
Institute for Strategic Thought and Practice, Tel Aviv, Israel
Stephen Johnson
Affiliation:
Decision Research, Eugene OR
Raghu Garud
Affiliation:
New York University
Praveen Rattan Nayyar
Affiliation:
New York University
Zur Baruch Shapira
Affiliation:
New York University
Get access

Summary

Introduction

For both individuals and organizations, most behavior is habitual. In a given situation, people do what they have usually done. When their behavior changes, it is often gradual, as behavior patterns are shaped by the feedback that they evoke. Producing good outcomes increases a behaviors' chance of being performed again, whereas unpleasant outcomes increase the search for alternative behaviors. Learning may be defined as appropriate change or consistency (Levitt & March, 1988).

The learning process involves a series of decisions, where one option is business as usual and the other options constitute changes – either innovations or reversion to earlier behavior. Whenever learning is possible, each option must be evaluated in terms of the outcomes it can cause and the lessons it can teach. For example, a short-term loss might be weighed against the chance to learn something generally useful (e.g., passing up a favorite watering hole in order to try a new restaurant, pulling one's best sales rep off solid accounts in order to test a new territory) (Einhorn, 1986).

Decision theory provides a set of well-articulated analytical methods for making such choices (Kleindorfer, Hershey, & Kunreuther, 1992; Raiffa, 1968; Watson & Buede, 1986; von Winterfeldt & Edwards, 1986). It can incorporate both an action's direct impacts and its informational value. The value of information can be both instrumental (through improving future decisions) and intrinsic (through satisfying curiosity, reducing the aversive-ness of uncertainty, or providing the “thrill value” of trying something different).

Type
Chapter
Information
Technological Innovation
Oversights and Foresights
, pp. 306 - 324
Publisher: Cambridge University Press
Print publication year: 1997

Access options

Get access to the full version of this content by using one of the access options below. (Log in options will check for institutional or personal access. Content may require purchase if you do not have access.)

Save book to Kindle

To save this book to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected] is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part of your Kindle email address below. Find out more about saving to your Kindle.

Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations. ‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi. ‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.

Find out more about the Kindle Personal Document Service.

Available formats
×

Save book to Dropbox

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Dropbox.

Available formats
×

Save book to Google Drive

To save content items to your account, please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies. If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account. Find out more about saving content to Google Drive.

Available formats
×