We use cookies to distinguish you from other users and to provide you with a better experience on our websites. Close this message to accept cookies or find out how to manage your cookie settings.
To save content items to your account,
please confirm that you agree to abide by our usage policies.
If this is the first time you use this feature, you will be asked to authorise Cambridge Core to connect with your account.
Find out more about saving content to .
To save content items to your Kindle, first ensure [email protected]
is added to your Approved Personal Document E-mail List under your Personal Document Settings
on the Manage Your Content and Devices page of your Amazon account. Then enter the ‘name’ part
of your Kindle email address below.
Find out more about saving to your Kindle.
Note you can select to save to either the @free.kindle.com or @kindle.com variations.
‘@free.kindle.com’ emails are free but can only be saved to your device when it is connected to wi-fi.
‘@kindle.com’ emails can be delivered even when you are not connected to wi-fi, but note that service fees apply.
Fiduciaries abound in health care. Employers pretend they can act in the best interests of employees when maintaining health plans – even though they pay (directly or indirectly) for claims against those plans. Physicians pretend they can act in the best interests of patients – even when hospitals and group practices pressure them to see more patients and spend less time with them, and even though physicians and their employers are incentivized to order expensive tests and procedures. But what if, instead of ignoring these conflicts of interest, the American healthcare system abandoned the fiduciary fallacy?
Building on recent scholarship showing that targeted legislation, regulation, and self-policing – rather than broad fiduciary duties – better manage these conflicts, I use game theory to analyze different scenarios relating to the financing and provision of health care involving two actors – a provider and a payor. For this analysis, I assume that the actors are rational and behave in their own self-interest until constrained by external rules and social and professional norms. My goal is to advance this scholarship by arguing that broad fiduciary duties are inadequate to address conflicts in our healthcare system, while also proposing paths forward.
One of the most harmful adverse consequences of conflicts of interest in research is the potential introduction of bias into the science of medicine and the denigration of the integrity of scientific research. A number of facts support the concerns that financial conflicts influence the integrity of medical research. The potential for conflicts of interest can never be eliminated, but conflicts of interest can be managed and, in some cases, reduced. Strategies for doing so are most useful when they are matters of institutional and editorial policies that are focused on preventing the adverse effects of conflict of interest and are not unduly burdensome. Disclosure is the most common first step in managing conflicts of interest. Public disclosure of raw scientific data and independent monitoring of research are additional mechanisms for managing conflicts of interest. Policies and guidance on conflicts of interest are changing rapidly.
Recommend this
Email your librarian or administrator to recommend adding this to your organisation's collection.