Hostname: page-component-586b7cd67f-gb8f7 Total loading time: 0 Render date: 2024-11-20T08:25:13.130Z Has data issue: false hasContentIssue false

Government spending multipliers with the Real Cost channel

Published online by Cambridge University Press:  06 July 2023

He Nie*
Affiliation:
Economics and Management School, Wuhan University, Wuhan, China
Rights & Permissions [Opens in a new window]

Abstract

In the benchmark New Keynesian (NK) model, I introduce the real cost channel to study government spending multipliers and provide simple Markov chain closed-form solutions. This model departs fundamentally from most previous interpretations of the nominal cost channel by flattening the NK Phillips Curve in liquidity traps. At the zero lower bound, I show analytically that following positive government spending shocks, the real cost channel can make inflation rise less than in a model without this channel. This then causes a smaller drop in real interest rates, resulting in a lower output gap multiplier. Finally, I confirm the robustness of the real cost channel’s effect on multipliers using extensions of two models.

Type
Articles
Copyright
© The Author(s), 2023. Published by Cambridge University Press

1. Introduction

In late 2008, the Federal Reserve had to lower the interest rate to zero to combat the Global Financial Crisis (GFC). Conventional monetary policy cannot work with a binding zero lower bound (ZLB). Therefore, the government sought to adopt an alternative effective fiscal policy to stimulate the economy during recessions. In this case, the GFC and subsequent recent recessions resulting from COVID-19 have sparked extensive fiscal policy discussions, which usually feature massive government spending.Footnote 1 For example, during the COVID-19 pandemic of 2020, the United States (US) government spent a total of $\$ $ 6.55 trillion on a series of programs to ensure the well-being of its population.

Understanding the effects of government spending at the ZLB warrants a thorough fiscal analysis. Standard New Keynesian (NK) models show that government spending multipliers can be substantially higher (e.g. above 2) at the ZLB as in Eggertsson and Woodford (Reference Eggertsson and Woodford2004), Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2011) and Zubairy (Reference Zubairy2014). This view has been challenged in recent theoretical studies.Footnote 2 In addition, a series of new empirical papers have indicated that multipliers are lower at the ZLB. For instance, Ramey and Zubairy (Reference Ramey and Zubairy2018) use US quarterly data spanning major wars and deep recessions to suggest government spending multipliers can be below 1 regardless of economic slack or near-zero rates, though estimates are more mixed at the ZLB, with a few specifications implying multipliers up to 1.5. Recently, Auerbach et al. (Reference Auerbach, Gorodnichenko, McCrory and Murphy2021) show that fiscal multipliers can be lower if used along with post-COVID supply-side constraints during recessions.

In this paper, I use a benchmark NK model with the cost channel of the expected real interest rate to provide new theoretical insights that explain, consistent with empirical papers, lower government spending multipliers when the economy is at the ZLB. More specifically, if firms need to borrow in advance to finance production, the interest rate can theoretically influence borrowing costs and firms’ marginal costs in the aggregate supply-side economy (summarized in the NK Phillips Curve). The critical difference between the model with the cost channel and the conventional model is that the interest rate should be included in firms’ marginal costs which can, in turn, influence the inflation rate.

The existence of the cost channel is shown in some empirical investigations. For instance, Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) estimate and obtain the cost channel parameter for the USA. Similarly, Chowdhury et al. (Reference Chowdhury, Hoffmann and Schabert2006) and Tillmann (Reference Tillmann2009) show the existence of the cost channel in both the USA and the UK. Recently, Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022) employs a structural vector autoregression model to confirm that the cost channel exists in almost all representative industrialized countries.

Unlike most previous literature that focuses on the nominal cost channel,Footnote 3 this paper uses the real cost channel: Firms’ marginal costs depend on expected real interest rates.Footnote 4 Furthermore, I conduct an analytical study on spending multipliers in liquidity traps. To this end, a simple two-state Markov chain, as in Eggertsson and Woodford (Reference Eggertsson and Woodford2003), is utilized to obtain closed-form solutions of spending multipliers.

At the ZLB, the results in this paper stand in stark contrast to most previous interpretations of the nominal cost channel as in Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006). I show that the introduced real cost channel can rotate the NK Phillips Curve with the expected disinflation effects during episodes of liquidity traps. The threshold of a negative natural rate shock to trigger ZLB constraints binding with the real cost channel is larger than in the classical NK model without the cost channel but less than in the model with the nominal cost channel. Therefore, the economy with the nominal cost channel is the most easily entrapped in liquidity traps.

Spending multipliers can be effective (larger than one) in liquidity traps. Intuitively, with ZLB binding, nominal interest rates remain unchanged. Government spending within a fiscal policy package can increase inflation in the short run. This can lower real interest rates and stimulate private consumption. However, the expected disinflation effects of the real cost channel result in lower marginal costs, causing inflation to rise by less than in standard models without it. Moreover, marginal costs can decrease even further with the increased strength of this channel. In this way, the real cost channel leads to a smaller drop in real interest rates. Higher real interest rates can depress people’s appetite for consumption and production activity, which, in turn, can lower the output gap multiplier. On the other hand, spending multipliers with the nominal cost channel can be invariant with the standard NK model since this nominal channel cannot modify the NK Phillips Curve slope at the ZLB.Footnote 5 In a nutshell, the output gap multiplier with the real cost channel model is smaller at the ZLB and decreases with an increase in channel strength, compared to the standard NK model and nominal cost channel models.

Additionally, I find that the output gap multiplier decreases as the strength of the real cost channel increases in normal times. Government spending can increase inflation in the short run. The real cost channel can further increase inflation due to higher borrowing costs, and this effect can be amplified with the strengthening of this channel’s impact. When nominal interest rates are free to adjust, the central bank increases rates more than inflation. The ensuing higher real interest rates curb private consumption, decreasing the output gap multiplier relative to a standard model without this channel, consistent with Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022). The nominal cost channel generates greater inflation than the real cost channel. Therefore, the nominal cost channel dampens the effects of government spending compared to the real cost channel.

This model extends to more general settings, with the real cost channel remaining robust. I analytically examine the effects of long-run government spending using a three-state Markov chain, as in Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Roulleau-Pasdeloup2023), by assuming that government spending outlasts economic recessions. Prolonged spending in normal times deflates the output gap multiplier but raises the inflation multiplier; in liquidity traps, it increases inflation through rational expectations, inflating the output gap multiplier.

As an extension, I explore introducing bounded rationality [Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020)] into the baseline model to analyze the multiplier.Footnote 6 I find that bounded rationality in normal times eases inflation and increases the output gap multiplier. Sufficiently strong cognitive discounting greatly boosts it. At the ZLB, bounded rationality decreases the output gap multiplier. Besides, the real cost channel can still operate robustly in this behavioral model.

1.1. Related literature

Seminal work focusing on the theoretical estimation of government spending effects in liquidity traps can be traced to Eggertsson (Reference Eggertsson2001). In this paper, the optimal fiscal policy in the NK economy is characterized, and the real effects of government spending are emphasized. Since then, an increasing amount of the literature has focused on the estimation of fiscal effects in theoretical and empirical settings. For example, Blanchard and Perotti (Reference Blanchard and Perotti2002) spark the earliest insights on empirically estimating the macroeconomic effects of government spending.Footnote 7 Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2011) prove that the multiplier is low in normal times in an economy following a Taylor (Reference Taylor1993)-type rule but relatively high in liquidity traps. Leeper et al. (Reference Leeper, Traum and Walker2017) study fiscal multipliers theoretically in a series of models. Two distinct monetary-fiscal policy regimes show that the short-run multiplier is robustly similar across different regimes. There are more examples among Kraay (Reference Kraay2012), Miyamoto et al. (Reference Miyamoto, Nguyen and Sergeyev2018), Ramey and Zubairy (Reference Ramey and Zubairy2018), etc.

In this paper, I add to the government spending multiplier literature by analytically addressing the role of the real cost channel on multipliers. The previous literature as in Barth III and Ramey (Reference Barth and Ramey2001), Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006), Llosa and Tuesta (Reference Llosa and Tuesta2009), and Smith (Reference Smith2016) introduces the nominal cost channel: Firms’ marginal costs augment nominal interest rates. For example, Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) confirm that cost-push shocks can emerge endogenously in the NK model with the nominal cost channel. Surico (Reference Surico2008) shows that limiting the economic cycle with the cost channel can lead to strong fluctuations in inflation and output. Recent studies have investigated the role of the real cost channel in macroeconomic dynamics. For example, Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) demonstrate that the Phillips curve appears quite flat when accounting for the real cost channel. Moreover, this study identifies a critical condition in which monetary loosening can lead to low-inflation traps when the real cost channel is present. Nie (Reference Nie2021) investigates the macroeconomic effects of tax shocks in models that incorporate the real cost channel. Inspired by their work, I modify the standard NK model by introducing expected real interest rates into firms’ marginal costs to study multipliers.

This paper allies closely with some recent literature that uses a three-state Markov chain to analytically examine the macroeconomic effects of long-run policy on the short-run economy [see Bilbiie (Reference Bilbiie2019a), Bilbiie (Reference Bilbiie2019b), Bilbiie (Reference Bilbiie2020) and Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2023)]. For example, Bilbiie (Reference Bilbiie2019b) employs a three-state Markov chain for his in-depth study on the optimal forward guidance policy in both the short and long run. In this paper, a three-state structure can allow us to analytically check the general properties of long-run government spending to echo some empirical evidence in Durevall and Henrekson (Reference Durevall and Henrekson2011), Ilzetzki et al. (Reference Ilzetzki, Mendoza and Végh2013), Leduc and Wilson (Reference Leduc and Wilson2013), Bouakez et al. (Reference Bouakez, Guillard and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2017), and Yaffe (Reference Yaffe2019).

In addition, recent contributions such as Farhi and Werning (Reference Farhi and án Werning2019) and Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020) show that bounded rationality mitigates the effects of monetary policy. This approach can rationalize the so-called “forward guidance puzzle” [see Angeletos and Lian (Reference Angeletos and Lian2018) and Coibion et al. (Reference Coibion, Georgarakos, Gorodnichenko and Weber2020)] compared to the benchmark forward-looking NK model. This paper, however, is linked with this strand of literature and comments on the interaction of the cost channel and bounded rationality on fiscal policy.

Finally, this paper is also closely related to Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022) who examines government spending multipliers at the ZLB with the nominal cost channel. Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022) includes the nominal cost channel and differentiates between the policy rate and loan rate. It turns out that this nominal channel can cause spending multipliers to be larger in liquidity traps. However, I adopt the real cost channel in this paper to explain lower government spending multipliers when the economy is at the ZLB. Simple Markov chain closed-form solutions are computed to study government spending multipliers with the real and nominal cost channels. Analytically, I further clarify the impact of the strength of the real cost channel on spending multipliers. I also study some extensions and confirm the robust role of the real cost channel on multipliers.

1.2. Organization

I specify the prototypical forward-looking NK model with the real cost channel in Section 2 and provide an analytical analysis using a two-state Markov chain on government spending multipliers. In Section 3, I study a baseline model to explore the general properties of long-run government spending effects. Another extension with bounded rationality is conducted in Section 4. Finally, this paper concludes in Section 5.

2. The baseline model with the real cost channel

Recent empirical evidence in Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022) shows that the existence of the cost channel can influence government spending multipliers. As in Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) and Surico (Reference Surico2008), the main contribution of the cost channel is that the interest rate can influence borrowing costs and the marginal cost function. In this paper, I follow Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) and Nie (Reference Nie2021) to utilize the NK model with the real cost channel specification, which means expected real interest rates can impact firms’ marginal costs and explore short-run government spending multipliers analytically.

2.1. Private sector behavior

I use a prototypical forward-looking NK model with the real cost channel as in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) and Nie (Reference Nie2021).Footnote 8 The behavior of the aggregate demand (AD) side of the economy can be summarized in the standard log-linearized Euler equation:

(1) \begin{equation} c_t=\mathbb{E}_t c_{t+1}-\frac{1}{\sigma _c}\left [R_t+\log\!(\beta )-\mathbb{E}_t\pi _{t+1}-r_t^n\right ], \end{equation}

where $c_t$ is private consumption, $\sigma _c$ is the risk aversion coefficient, $R_t$ is the nominal interest rate in level, $\pi _t$ is inflation, $\mathbb{E}_t$ is the rational expectation operator, and $r_t^n$ is the demand shock (also the natural rate shock).

The linear resource constraint in this economy is

(2) \begin{equation} y_t=(1-s_g)c_t+g_t, \end{equation}

where $y_t$ is the output gap, $s_g$ is the fraction of government spending in total production, and $g_t$ is government spending.Footnote 9 In this case, one can obtain the path of $y_t$ by substituting the resource constraint into the Euler equation below:

(3) \begin{equation} y_t=\mathbb{E}_t y_{t+1}-\frac{1}{\sigma }\left [R_t+\log\! (\beta )-\mathbb{E}_t\pi _{t+1}-r_t^n\right ]+g_t-\mathbb{E}_tg_{t+1}, \end{equation}

where $\sigma =\frac{\sigma _c}{1-s_g}$ .

The aggregate supply (AS) side of the economy can be summarized with the following log-linearized NK Phillips Curve.Footnote 10

(4) \begin{equation} \pi _t=\beta \mathbb{E}_t \pi _{t+1}+\kappa\! \left[\gamma _y y_t+\gamma _g g_t+\gamma _r(R_t+\log\! (\beta )-\mathbb{E}_t \pi _{t+1})\right ], \end{equation}

where $\beta$ is the subjective discount factor, and $\kappa$ is the elasticity of inflation with regard to marginal cost. $\gamma _y$ , $\gamma _g$ , and $\gamma _r$ are the elasticity of marginal cost elasticity with regard to the output gap, government spending, and the expected real interest rate, respectively.Footnote 11 It is of note that $\gamma _r$ in equation (4) can be seen as the strength of the cost channel which controls the impact of this channel. This model with the real cost channel can collapse to the conventional one without the cost channel if $\gamma _r=0$ .Footnote 12 In addition, it can nest the model with the nominal cost channel [represented by equation (6)] if we assume that nominal interest rates are introduced in firms’ borrowing costs as in Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006), and then, the expected disinflation term ( $-\mathbb{E}_t\pi _{t+1}$ ) of equation (4) disappears.

It is assumed that the central bank sets the nominal interest rate following the (truncated) Taylor (Reference Taylor1993)-type rule with the ZLB:

(5) \begin{equation} R_t=\max\! \left \{0,-\log\! (\beta )+\phi _\pi \pi _t\right \}. \end{equation}

2.1.1. Real versus nominal cost channel

The Phillips Curve with the nominal cost channel is

(6) \begin{equation} \pi _t=\beta \mathbb{E}_t \pi _{t+1}+\kappa\! \left [\gamma _y y_t+\gamma _g g_t+\gamma _r(R_t+\log\! (\beta ))\right ]. \end{equation}

Equation (6) is used in most previous papers working as nominal cost channel specifications such as Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) and Surico (Reference Surico2008). In these papers, the nominal interest rate is introduced in borrowing costs. Even though the specifications in equations (4) and (6) can be seen as the cost channel, the real cost channel specification in equation (4) features expected real interest rates in borrowing costs and highlights the additional role of expected disinflation denoted by the negative $\mathbb{E}_t\pi _{t+1}$ term.

Note that the two cost channels can have similar effects in normal times if the central bank follows a simple Taylor rule in equation (5). In this case, a cost-push shock endogenously emerges in the two cases as in Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006), and the two channels both increase firms’ marginal costs and inflation.

An interesting insight at the ZLB with $R_t=0$ is that the nominal cost channel as in Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) and Surico (Reference Surico2008) cannot influence the slope of the Phillips Curve. However, note that, at the ZLB, the real cost channel as in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) can rotate the Phillips Curve with expectations of disinflation. As a result, the Phillips Curve with the real cost channel is flatter than in the standard NK model without this channel, and this may explain a declining slope of the empirical Phillips Curve.

2.2. Quick tour: normal times and ZLB

In this section, I employ a two-state static Markov chain as in Eggertsson et al. (Reference Eggertsson and Woodford2003) to deal with the policy shocks vector $[r_t^n, g_t]$ . It is assumed that a specific policy shock (for example, the demand shock $r_t^n$ in this section) remains at the current short-run state (which I label $r^n_S$ with a subscript $'S'$ for the short run) with a persistence $p$ and then reverts to the long-run steady state, that is $r^n_L=0$ with a probability $1-p$ .Footnote 13 Since the NK model with the real cost channel in this paper is forward-looking, one can compute the expected output gap and inflation as follows:

(7) \begin{equation} \mathbb{E}_S y_{t+1}=p y_S, \quad \quad \mathbb{E}_S \pi _{t+1}=p\pi _S. \end{equation}

Assumption 1. I assume that the NK Phillips Curve with the real cost channel is always upward sloping in a $(\pi _S, y_S)$ graph such that

(8) \begin{equation} p\lt \frac{1-\kappa \gamma _r \phi _\pi }{\beta -\kappa \gamma _r}=\overline{p}^c. \end{equation}

As proposed by Laubach and Williams (Reference Laubach and Williams2003), Cochrane (Reference Cochrane2017), Han et al. (Reference Han, Tan and Wu2020), and Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2023), there is an implicit condition that the NK Phillips Curve is upward sloping in a $(\pi _S, y_S)$ graph as in Assumption 1. Compared with the NK model with the nominal cost channel as in Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2005) and Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006), this paper utilizes a more empirically relevant real cost channel proposed in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) and further extended in Nie (Reference Nie2021).

In this section, we discuss two cases which are the economy in normal times without ZLB binding and also in liquidity traps. There is a threshold of demand shock to trigger ZLB constraint binding. From the Taylor (Reference Taylor1993)-type rule, one can see that if the item $\{-\log\! (\beta )+\phi _\pi \pi _S\}$ is less than or equal to zero, the NK economy can be binding with the ZLB state. If not, the economy is in normal times and nominal interest rates can be free to adjust with the central bank’s monetary policy regulation. If the (negative) natural rate shock is too large, the economy can be caught up in liquidity traps. Thereby there is a boundary condition for the natural rate shock $r_S^n$ in the short run to trigger the economy into a state with ZLB binding.

Proposition 1. The boundary condition relationship among the three models is

(9) \begin{equation} \underline{r_S^{n,B}}\lt \underline{r_S^n}\lt \underline{r_S^{n,N}}, \end{equation}

where $\underline{r_S^{n,B}}$ is the boundary condition without the cost channel, $\underline{r_S^n}$ is with the real cost channel, and $\underline{r_S^{n,N}}$ is with the nominal cost channel.

Proof. See Online Appendix B.

In Proposition 1, the boundary condition to trigger the ZLB binding with the real cost channel is larger than in the conventional NK model without the cost channel since the real cost channel features the supply-side effects of interest rates. In other words, the economy can get stuck more easily in liquidity traps with the real cost channel than in the traditional model. On the other hand, the boundary condition with the nominal cost channel is larger than in the model with the real cost channel due to expectations of disinflation. Therefore, among the three models, the model with the nominal cost channel is the most easily entrapped in liquidity traps.Footnote 14

In the following sections, I will focus on government spending shocks and discuss the issues of the output gap and inflation multipliers.

2.3. Government spending: theoretical analysis

To obtain transparent results, I abstract from demand shocks and focus only on the effects of government spending shocks with the real cost channel. First, I compare the multiplier relationship among the three models. Second, I deliver the general property of the strength of the cost channel on the multiplier by using simple Markov chain closed-form solutions.

2.3.1. Government spending multipliers in normal times

I assume that a positive government spending shock $g_S\gt 0$ follows the Markov process. It starts in the short run, stays with the persistence probability $p$ , and returns to the steady-state $g_L=0$ in the long run with a probability $1-p$ . If the short-run economy is in normal times, I can rewrite the Euler equation (3) and the Phillips Curve with the real cost channel [equation (4)]:

(10) \begin{align} y_S &=-\frac{1}{\sigma (1-p)}(\phi _\pi -p)\pi _S+g_S\end{align}
(11) \begin{align} \pi _S &=\kappa \frac{\gamma _y }{1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)}y_S+\kappa \frac{\gamma _g}{1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)}g_S. \end{align}
Fiscal multipliers

I find that a positive government spending shock can move the Euler equation upward and shift down the Phillips Curve in a $(\pi _t,y_t)$ graph. The solutions with the real cost channel of the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O}$ and inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I}$ can be computed as follows:Footnote 15

(12) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O}=\frac{\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)]-\kappa \gamma _g(\phi _\pi -p)}{\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)]+\kappa \gamma _y(\phi _\pi -p)} \end{align}
(13) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I}=\frac{ \bigg [1+\frac{\gamma _g}{\gamma _y}\bigg ] \kappa \gamma _y\sigma (1-p)}{\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)]+\kappa \gamma _y(\phi _\pi -p)}. \end{align}

The expected real interest rate can be in both the denominator and numerator of the output gap multiplier since the real cost channel here can influence the inflation rate and further impact the output gap through expectations. Regarding the inflation multiplier, the expected real interest rate is included in the denominator since the cost channel can impact this multiplier directly. In normal times, since the denominator of the multiplier equation is higher than the numerator, the multiplier is less than one.Footnote 16

In normal times, the real cost channel reduces the output gap multiplier, consistent with Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022). Positive government spending shocks elevate short-run inflation;Footnote 17 the real cost channel further heightens borrowing costs and inflation.Footnote 18 With adjustable nominal interest rates, the central bank increases rates by more than inflation.Footnote 19 The ensuing higher real interest rates curb private consumption, decreasing the output gap multiplier compared to the scenario where this channel is absent.

As in Online Appendix C, compared to the nominal cost channel, the inflation multiplier with the real cost channel can be smaller. If we compare the NK Phillips Curve in equations (6) and (4), less influence is triggered by the real cost channel, which can echo the fact of lower inflation in the Euro area in normal times [Koester et al. (Reference Koester, Lis, Nickel, Osbat and Smets2021)]. In this scenario, the nominal cost channel can further reduce the output gap multiplier compared to the real cost channel.

I also explore the effects of the strength of the real cost channel $\gamma _r$ on spending multipliers. The power of the real cost channel can directly leverage the increment of inflation. On the other hand, we can see that higher inflation can crowd out more private consumption, hence leading to a much lower output gap multiplier given a stronger real cost channel. Therefore, the output gap multiplier decreases in $\gamma _r$ , whereas the inflation multiplier increases in $\gamma _r$ . I summarize the above theoretical results in Proposition 2.

Proposition 2. In normal times, the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O}$ decreases in $\gamma _r$ , whereas the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I}$ increases in $\gamma _r$ . The output gap multiplier relationship among the three models is

(14) \begin{equation} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,N}\lt \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O}\lt \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,B}, \end{equation}

and the inflation multiplier relationship is

(15) \begin{equation} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,B}\lt \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I}\lt \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,N}, \end{equation}

where in normal times: $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,B}$ is the output gap multiplier without the cost channel and $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,N}$ is with the nominal cost channel; $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,B}$ is the inflation multiplier without the cost channel, and $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,N}$ is with the nominal cost channel.

Proof. See Online Appendix C.

2.3.2. Government spending multipliers at ZLB

In this part, I focus on the case when the short-run economy is stuck at the ZLB.Footnote 20 The Euler equation (3) and the Phillips Curve with the real cost channel [equation (4)] can be rewritten as:

(16) \begin{align} y_S& =-\frac{1}{\sigma (1-p)}[\log\! (\beta )-p\pi _S]+g_S \end{align}
(17) \begin{align} \pi _S& =\frac{\kappa \gamma _y}{1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp}y_S+\kappa \frac{\gamma _g }{1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp}g_S+\frac{\kappa \gamma _r\log\! (\beta )}{1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp}. \end{align}
Fiscal multipliers

In liquidity traps, one can use the Euler equation and the Phillips Curve to obtain the solutions with the real cost channel of the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O}$ and the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I}$ :Footnote 21

(18) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O}=\frac{\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp]+\kappa \gamma _gp}{\sigma (1-p)(1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp)-\kappa \gamma _yp} \end{align}
(19) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I}=\frac{ \bigg [1+\frac{\gamma _g}{\gamma _y}\bigg ] \kappa \gamma _y\sigma (1-p)}{\sigma (1-p)(1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp)-\kappa \gamma _yp}. \end{align}

From the solutions, the expected real interest rate can be in both the denominator and numerator of the output gap multiplier. The real cost channel here can influence the inflation rate and further impact the output gap through expectations. The real cost channel can impact the inflation multiplier directly through the NK Phillips Curve.

In liquidity traps, the denominator of the multiplier equation is lower than the numerator; thus, the output gap at the ZLB is larger than one. At the ZLB, with no cost channel, nominal interest rates remain unchanged, and an increase in government spending can generate inflation. Therefore, government spending leads to a drop in real interest rates, which, in turn, gives incentives to households to save less and consume more. This can be seen as the crowding effects as in Bouakez et al. (Reference Bouakez, Guillard and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2017).

However, following positive spending shocks, the real cost channel can decrease short-run inflation through expectations of disinflation in firms’ real borrowing costs. Intuitively, lower marginal costs arise due to expected disinflation during liquidity trap episodes. Further, expectations of disinflation can translate into realized lower inflation rates through rational expectations and sticky prices. In this case, the real cost channel can make inflation rates rise by less than in the conventional model following positive spending shocks, and there is a smaller drop in real interest rates. Higher real interest rates due to the real cost channel can depress not only people’s appetite for consumption but also decrease production activity, which results in a decline in the effects of government spending on output. Hence compared to the standard NK model without the real cost channel, both the output gap multiplier and the inflation multiplier with the real cost channel are lower.

On the other hand, as explained in Section 2.1.1, the nominal cost channel cannot modify the NK Phillips Curve slope at the ZLB. Spending multipliers with this nominal cost channel can be invariant with the standard NK model since this channel in liquidity traps cannot be included in the partial derivative of government spending to the output gap/inflation in the calculation of fiscal multipliers.

I next discuss the effects of the strength of the real cost channel $\gamma _r$ on spending multipliers. The stronger the power of the real cost channel, the lower inflation rates due to expectations of disinflation in liquidity traps. In this case, higher real interest rates due to lower inflation can depress people’s appetite for consumption, which results in more decline in the output gap multiplier. In a nutshell, both the inflation and the output gap multipliers with the real cost channel decrease in $\gamma _r$ . I summarize the main theoretical results in Proposition 3.

Proposition 3. At the ZLB, both the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O}$ and the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I}$ decrease in $\gamma _r$ . The output gap multiplier relationship among the three models is

(20) \begin{equation} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O}\lt \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,N}=\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,B}, \end{equation}

and the inflation multiplier relationship is

(21) \begin{equation} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I}\lt \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,N}=\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,B}, \end{equation}

where in liquidity traps: $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,B}$ is the output gap multiplier without the cost channel and $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,N}$ is with the nominal cost channel; $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,B}$ is the inflation multiplier without the cost channel and $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,N}$ is with the nominal cost channel.

Proof. See Online Appendix D.

Comparison with the literature

Our study contrasts with that of Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022) who shows that higher borrowing costs with the nominal cost channel can increase inflation which makes the output gap multiplier larger than in the standard model at the ZLB. As in Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022), the Phillips Curve with the nominal cost channel at the ZLB is steeper in a $(y_S,\pi _S)$ graph than in the standard NK model.Footnote 22 In this paper, I stress that inflation in the short run with the real cost channel can be lower due to expected disinflation in real borrowing costs.Footnote 23 Thus, I can use the real cost channel to explain lower spending multipliers in liquidity traps as in Ramey and Zubairy (Reference Ramey and Zubairy2018).

Taking stock of the denominator of the multiplier

As discussed extensively in Bilbiie (Reference Bilbiie2008), Mertens and Ravn (Reference Mertens and Ravn2014), Borağan Aruoba et al. (Reference Aruoba, Cuba-Borda and Schorfheide2018), and Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2023), the denominator of the multiplier in the standard NK model at the ZLB can be negative due to a highly persistent $p$ .Footnote 24 In this case, the output gap and inflation multipliers are negative in equations (18)–(19).

However, as described at length in Nie (Reference Nie2021), in the presence of the real cost channel, the denominator with the ZLB binding is less likely to be negative than in the standard model.Footnote 25 I use the result from Nie (Reference Nie2021): The denominator can be always positive if assuming the elasticity of marginal costs w.r.t. the output gap $\gamma _y$ is sufficiently small and meets the following condition:

(22) \begin{align} \gamma _y\lt \Gamma (\gamma _r), \end{align}

where $\Gamma (\gamma _r)=\frac{(\beta -\kappa \gamma _r-1+\kappa \gamma _r\phi _\pi )\gamma _r\phi _\pi (\beta -\kappa \gamma _r)}{\sigma _r(1-\kappa \gamma _r\phi _\pi )}$ increases in $\gamma _r$ —See Online Appendix E.

As in condition (22), $\gamma _y$ is lower than the composite parameter $\Gamma (\gamma _r)$ , ensuring that the denominator is always positive. Assuming that $\gamma _y$ is small enough for a given $\gamma _r$ , this condition can always hold. In particular, the assumption with a low $\gamma _y$ is in line with the empirical finding as in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022): $\gamma _y$ is very small while the key parameter $\gamma _r$ leveraging the strength of the real cost channel is much larger than $\gamma _y$ .

Bearing this in mind, in the following numerical exercise, I will consider only the case in which the denominator of the spending multiplier is positive.

2.4. Numerical results: benchmark

In this paper, I follow Budianto et al. (Reference Budianto, Nakata and Schmidt2020), Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Roulleau-Pasdeloup2021), and Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) to set the parameterization reported in Table 1.Footnote 26

Table 1. Parameterization

I first provide numerical AS/AD figures with a contractionary natural rate shock in three NK Phillips Curves shown in Figure 1. The natural rate shock can move the Euler equation. If there is a temporary short-term natural rate shock $r^n_S$ (−2.2%), which exceeds the boundary condition, the economy can be in liquidity traps.Footnote 27 In this case, the conventional monetary policy cannot work since the nominal interest rate is bounded at zero. Deflationary pressure can lead to higher real interest rates and further stimulate people to save but consume less. From Figure 1, it is clear that the real cost channel can change the Phillips Curve slope in liquidity traps and the Phillips Curve is locally flat as in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022). The curve with the nominal cost channel at the ZLB shares the same slope as the conventional model. The numerical results also echo Proposition 1 that the case with the nominal cost channel is the most easily entrapped in liquidity traps among the three models.Footnote 28 This Proposition can be further confirmed in the impulse response to a contractionary natural rate shock—See Online Appendix F.

Figure 1. AS/AD curves with natural rate shock in three models.

I compare spending multipliers of the models in normal times without the cost channel ( $\gamma _r=0$ ) vs. with the cost channel as in Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) vs. with the real cost channel in Figure 2.Footnote 29 It can be seen that the output gap multiplier is lower than one as in Lewis (Reference Lewis2021), and it decreases in $\gamma _r$ . On the contrary, the inflation multiplier increases in $\gamma _r$ . It is observed that the output gap multiplier with the real cost channel is larger than that with the nominal cost channel while less than its counterpart without the cost channel. This can echo the theoretical analysis in Proposition 2. See Online Appendix G for numerical results w.r.t. the persistence $p$ in the three models. These numerical results robustly echo Proposition 2. I also find that the output gap multiplier decreases in $p$ , whereas the inflation multiplier is higher with the duration of increment of time.

Figure 2. Spending multipliers in normal times.

Figure 3 shows spending multipliers in liquidity traps. The simulation results can illustrate quantitatively our theoretical analysis in Proposition 3. On the one hand, one can see that the output gap multiplier is effective as in Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2011) and Schmidt (Reference Schmidt2017). The real cost channel can attenuate the output gap and inflation multipliers simultaneously. The spending multipliers decrease in $\gamma _r$ . The nominal cost channel multipliers are invariant with the standard NK model without the cost channel.Footnote 30 See Online Appendix G for numerical results w.r.t. $p$ in the three models, and these results further confirm our theoretical analysis. In addition, the output gap and inflation multipliers increase in $p$ .

Figure 3. Spending multipliers at ZLB.

3. Government spending: long-run policy

As in recent contributions by Sarin et al. (Reference Sarin, Summers, Zidar and Zwick2021) and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Roulleau-Pasdeloup2021), long-run policy effects are usually overlooked or often even computed numerically in the literature. In this section, I follow Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Roulleau-Pasdeloup2023) to use a three-state Markov chain to assess long-run government spending analytically.

3.1. Policy and shocks

I assume that government spending is longer-lived than demand shock. To be more specific, government spending in the short run $g_S$ can merge into medium-run government spending $g_M$ with a persistence $q$ and then collapse to the steady-state $g_L=0$ with a probability $1-q$ .Footnote 31 The natural rate shock $r^n_S$ operates in the short run with a probability $p$ and then returns to the long run $r^n_L=0$ with a probability $1-p$ . The graphical representation of our policy can be seen in Figure 4.

Figure 4. Long-run government spending: a graphical representation.

With this in mind, for current monetary policy, I use an adapted Taylor rule:Footnote 32

(23) \begin{equation} R_t = \begin{cases} \max\! \left [0;-\log\! (\beta )+\phi _\pi \pi _S\right ]\,\, \, \, \, \, \, \, \, \, \, \,\,\,\text{In the short run} \\ -\log\! (\beta )+\phi _\pi ^q \pi _M\, \hphantom{max\left [0;+r_S^n\ \right ]}\, \text{In the medium run}\\ -\log\! (\beta )\ \hphantom{\max \left [0;+r_S^n+\phi _\pi \pi _S\, \right ]}\, \, \,\text{In the long run} \end{cases} \end{equation}

One can use the above equation (23) to trace the path of government spending. In the medium run, the output gap and inflation can be expressed as the product of medium-run multipliers and medium-run government spending as follows:

(24) \begin{equation} y_M=\mathcal{M}_{M}^{O}\cdot g_M \, \, \, \, \pi _M=\mathcal{M}_{M}^{I} \cdot g_M, \end{equation}

where $\mathcal{M}_{M}^{O}$ is the medium-run output gap multiplier and $\mathcal{M}_{M}^{I}$ is the medium-run inflation multiplier. See Online Appendix I for the medium-run spending multipliers.Footnote 33 In this case, since the model is forward-looking, I can generate the expected output gap below, and one can show the expected inflation using the same manner.

(25) \begin{align} \notag \mathbb{E}_Sy_{t+1}&=py_S+(1-p)qy_M\\ \notag &=py_S+(1-p)q\mathcal{M}_{M}^{O}g_M\\ &=py_S+(1-p)q\mathcal{M}_{M}^{O}\zeta g_S. \end{align}

3.2. Long-run government spending: theoretical analysis

This section discusses the analytical results regarding the government spending multiplier with a three-state Markov structure.

3.2.1. Multipliers with long-run government spending in normal times

In normal times, one can use the Euler equation and the Phillips Curve in Online Appendix J to compute the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,\text{long}}$ and the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,\text{long}}$ :

(26) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,\text{long}}&=\frac{\Theta _{AD}\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)]-\Theta _{AS}(\phi _\pi -p)}{\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)]+\kappa \gamma _y(\phi _\pi -p)} \end{align}
(27) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,\text{long}}&=\frac{ \bigg (\kappa \gamma _y\Theta _{AD}+\Theta _{AS}\bigg ) \sigma (1-p)}{\sigma (1-p)[1-\beta p-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)]+\kappa \gamma _y(\phi _\pi -p)}. \end{align}

Long-run government spending can increase short-run inflation through rational expectations and sticky prices. In normal times, the central bank increases nominal interest rates to combat higher prices caused by inflation. In that way, long-run spending policy can crowd out more private consumption due to higher short-run real interest rates. Additionally, the real cost channel can increase marginal costs and inflation. Thus, the inflation multiplier can increase depending on the strength of the real cost channel $\gamma _r$ , and this result is the same as the case in Section 2. Similarly, the real cost channel can lower the output gap. In summary, the output gap multiplier reduces in $\gamma _r$ whereas the inflation multiplier grows in $\gamma _r$ —For a formal proof, see Online Appendix K.

3.2.2. Multipliers with long-run government spending at ZLB

At the ZLB, I use the Euler equation and the Phillips Curve in Online Appendix J to produce the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,\text{long}}$ and the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,\text{long}}$ :

(28) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,\text{long}}&=\frac{\Theta _{AD}\sigma (1-p)( 1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp)+\Theta _{AS}p}{\sigma (1-p)(1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp)-\kappa \gamma _yp} \end{align}
(29) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,\text{long}}&=\frac{ \bigg (\kappa \gamma _y\Theta _{AD}+\Theta _{AS}\bigg ) \sigma (1-p)}{\sigma (1-p)(1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp)-\kappa \gamma _yp}. \end{align}

Once the liquidity trap has subsided, the extension of government spending policy can cause inflation to increase. The nominal interest rate is zero, and higher inflation can help stimulate our NK economy since it can lower short-run real interest rates and then increase private consumption. At this time, the spending multiplier is larger, which is in line with Bachmann and Sims (Reference Bachmann and Sims2012) who empirically show that long-term spending effects are larger than in the short-term policy model. However, the real cost channel can reduce the effectiveness of long-run government spending. The cost channel can dampen inflation due to expectations of disinflation in the real borrowing cost. Thus, the output gap and inflation multipliers decrease as the real cost channel becomes stronger—See Online Appendix L for an analytical analysis.

3.3. Numerical results with long-run government spending

The numerical results of short-run and long-run spending policies that vary with the strength of the real cost channel $\gamma _r$ are presented in Figure 5.Footnote 34 In normal times, it is observed that long-run government spending can decrease the output gap multiplier. Moreover, long-run government spending can result in a larger inflation multiplier compared to short-run policies. The output gap multiplier falls in $\gamma _r$ while the inflation multiplier increases in $\gamma _r$ . See Online Appendix M for numerical results w.r.t. the persistence $p$ . I find that the output gap multiplier can be negative with long-run spending.

Figure 5. Spending multipliers with long-run spending policy in normal times.

At the ZLB, the numerical results are reported in Figure 6. We find that long-run government spending can further increase the output gap and inflation multipliers. The two spending multipliers decrease in $\gamma _r$ . Noteworthy is that the output gap multiplier can be more effective for a prolonged spending policy in recessions. Similar results can be found in Online Appendix M for numerical results w.r.t. $p$ .

Figure 6. Spending multipliers with long-run spending policy at ZLB.

4. A behavioral model

As can be seen in Section 3, long-run government spending can drive spending multipliers at the ZLB. In our baseline model in Section 2, it is the consensus that agents have rational expectations. In this section, I extend the baseline model to address the role of rational expectations. I develop a model similar to Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020) and incorporate it into our simple benchmark setup. This model considers bounded rationality, where agents can be short-sighted about the world.

4.1. The NK model with Bounded Rationality

I use the model in Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020) to show the behavior of the aggregate demand-side economy:

(30) \begin{equation} c_t=\bar m\mathbb{E}_t c_{t+1}-\frac{1}{\sigma _c}\left (i_t-\mathbb{E}_t\pi _{t+1}-r^n\right ), \end{equation}

where $\bar m \in [0,1]$ is the cognitive discounting parameter in Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020).Footnote 35

In this case, one can obtain the path of $y_t$ by substituting the resource constraint into the Euler equation:

(31) \begin{equation} y_t=\bar m(1-s_g)\mathbb{E}_t y_{t+1}-\frac{1}{\sigma }(R_t+\log\! (\beta )-\mathbb{E}_t\pi _{t+1}-r^n)+g_t-\bar m(1-s_g)\mathbb{E}_t g_{t+1}, \end{equation}

where $\sigma =\frac{\sigma _c}{1-s_g}$ .

As in Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020), I can derive the NK Phillips Curve with the real cost channel:

(32) \begin{equation} \pi _t=\beta \bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]\mathbb{E}_t \pi _{t+1}+\kappa \left [\gamma _y y_t+\gamma _g g_t+\gamma _r(R_t+\log\! (\beta )-\mathbb{E}_t \pi _{t+1})\right ], \end{equation}

where $\varphi \in (0,1)$ is the share of firms that cannot adjust their prices.

4.2. Government spending with bounded rationality: theoretical results

This section presents the analytical results regarding government spending multipliers with bounded rationality.

4.2.1. Multipliers with bounded rationality in normal times

In normal times, I use the Euler equation and the Phillips Curve with the consideration of bounded rationality—see Online Appendix N, to produce the solutions of the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,BR}$ and the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,BR}$ below:Footnote 36

(33) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{O,BR}=\frac{\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]\bigg \{1-\beta p\bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)\bigg \}-\kappa \gamma _g(\phi _\pi -p)}{\sigma (1-p\bar m(1-s_g))\bigg \{1-\beta p\bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)\bigg \}+\kappa \gamma _y(\phi _\pi -p)} \end{align}
(34) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,N}^{I,BR}=\frac{ \bigg [1+\frac{\gamma _g}{\gamma _y}\bigg ] \kappa \gamma _y\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]}{\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]\bigg \{1-\beta p\bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]-\kappa \gamma _r(\phi _\pi -p)\bigg \}+\kappa \gamma _y(\phi _\pi -p)}. \end{align}

In normal times, cognitive discounting can reduce the expectation effects in our baseline model which can lower inflation following a positive spending shock. This means that there is a lower rise in real interest rates, hence a higher output gap multiplier compared to the baseline model. In this case, the inflation multiplier with bounded rationality can be lower, whereas the output gap multiplier can be higherFootnote 37 —see Online Appendix O for a formal proof. Since the introduced bounded rationality is independent of the strength of the real cost channel $\gamma _r$ , the effects of this channel on spending multipliers are the same as the baseline model results. Specifically, the output gap multiplier decreases in $\gamma _r$ while the inflation multiplier increases.

I find that the output gap multiplier can be large (near one) in normal times if we suppose agents have relatively intense bounded rationality which means the expectation effects are extremely weak. Intuitively, agents tend to consume today but not to save since future consumption has less or no effect on today’s decisions. In this case, the crowding-out effects of government spending should be much attenuated, and the output gap multiplier can be near one. This result echoes the previous empirical evidence that the output gap multiplier can be large in normal times as in Auerbach and Gorodnichenko (Reference Auerbach and Gorodnichenko2012) and Acconcia et al. (Reference Acconcia, Corsetti and Simonelli2014).

4.2.2. Multipliers with bounded rationality at ZLB

At the ZLB, one can use the Euler equation and the Phillips Curve with bounded rationality—see Online Appendix N, to produce the output gap multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,BR}$ and the inflation multiplier $\mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,BR}$ :

(35) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{O,BR}=\frac{\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]\bigg \{1-\beta p\bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]+\kappa \gamma _rp\bigg \}+\kappa \gamma _gp}{\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]\bigg \{1-\beta p\bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]+\kappa \gamma _rp\bigg \}-\kappa \gamma _y p} \end{align}
(36) \begin{align} \mathcal{M}_{S,Z}^{I,BR}=\frac{ \bigg [1+\frac{\gamma _g}{\gamma _y}\bigg ] \kappa \gamma _y\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]}{\sigma [1-p\bar m(1-s_g)]\bigg \{1-\beta p\bar m\bigg [\varphi +\frac{1-\beta \varphi }{1-\beta \varphi \bar{m}}(1-\varphi )\bigg ]+\kappa \gamma _r p\bigg \}-\kappa \gamma _y p}. \end{align}

At the ZLB, inflation caused by government spending can be lower due to cognitive discounting. Thus, it can increase real interest rates by less than in the standard model, which, in turn, can lower the output gap multiplier.Footnote 38 The effects on the strength of the real cost channel are the same as for the baseline model in liquidity traps. Specifically, the output gap and inflation multipliers decrease in $\gamma _r$ —see Online Appendix P for a proof.

4.3. Numerical results with bounded rationality

Figure 7 shows how spending multipliers with bounded rationality vary with the value of $\gamma _r$ for various values of $\bar m$ in normal times. The main takeaway is that the output gap multiplier can be larger with a lower $\bar m$ while the inflation multiplier can be lower under bounded rationality. In addition, the output gap multiplier decreases in $\gamma _r$ , whereas the inflation multiplier increases in $\gamma _r$ . See Online Appendix Q for numerical results w.r.t. $p$ . I find that the output gap multiplier can decrease in $p$ with rational expectations ( $\bar m=1$ ) but increase in $p$ with a small $\bar m$ .

Figure 7. Spending multipliers with bounded rationality in normal times.

The numerical simulation in Figure 8 shows that the inflation and output gap multipliers are lower with bounded rationality in liquidity traps. In addition, the role of the real cost channel with bounded rationality is the same as that of the baseline model. As in Online Appendix Q, the output gap multiplier increases numerically in $p$ .

Figure 8. Spending multipliers with bounded rationality at ZLB.

5. Concluding remarks

This paper considers the standard New Keynesian model with the real cost channel to explore government spending multipliers. The general properties of spending multipliers are identified using this analytical framework. During episodes of liquidity traps, it is found that the output gap multiplier with the real cost channel is smaller compared to the standard model without this channel, and it decreases as the strength of the real cost channel increases. I use this theoretical result to explain the lower government spending multiplier observed when nominal interest rates are fixed at the lower bound, consistent with empirical studies. The extent to which firms are subject to real borrowing costs can make government spending less effective in stimulating the economy in times of recession. In normal times, the output gap multiplier also decreases with this channel.

The robust role of the real cost channel on spending multipliers is confirmed. More specifically, our results on the role of the real cost channel, if one considers long-run government spending policy, are the same as for the short-run model. The benchmark model is also modified to include bounded rationality while retaining analytical tractability. Cognitive behavior can alter spending multipliers; however, the real cost channel still operates. This framework is sufficiently flexible that one can introduce heterogeneity along the lines of Bhandari et al. (Reference Bhandari, Evans, Golosov and Sargent2021), Cantore and Freund (Reference Cantore and Freund2021), and Bayer et al. (Reference Bayer, Born and Luetticke2022) while retaining analytical tractability. I leave the analyses of other extensions to future work.

Supplementary material

To view supplementary material for this article, please visit http://doi.org/10.1017/S1365100523000251.

Footnotes

*

I would like to thank my advisor, Jordan Roulleau-Pasdeloup, for his extensive comments. I would also thank Chang Liu, Paul Gabriel Jackson, Denis Tkachenko, Yujie Yang as well as participants in NUS GRS and the CEC-NTU Joint Online workshop 2021 for their comments and suggestions.

1 See discussions on the fiscal tool to resist recessions as in Eggertsson (Reference Eggertsson2011), Kollmann et al. (Reference Kollmann, Roeger and Veld2012), Bouakez et al. (Reference Bouakez, Guillard and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2020), and House et al. (Reference House, Proebsting and Tesar2020).

2 See for example, Kiley (Reference Kiley2014), Mertens and Ravn (Reference Mertens and Ravn2014) and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Roulleau-Pasdeloup2021).

3 There are a series of papers with the nominal cost channel specification which means that nominal interest rates are augmented in firms’ marginal costs, such as Barth III and Ramey (Reference Barth and Ramey2001), Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006), Llosa and Tuesta (Reference Llosa and Tuesta2009), and Smith (Reference Smith2016).

4 Compared to the nominal cost channel, as explained at length in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022), the real cost channel can be more empirically relevant to the US data. Furthermore, Nie (Reference Nie2021) formally proves that the real cost channel is theoretically appealing since it can ensure the equilibrium uniqueness/existence with temporary shocks.

5 In the calculation of fiscal multipliers, we need to gain the partial derivative of government spending to inflation/the output gap. If the introduced cost channel cannot change the NK Phillips Curve slope, the partial derivative should be the same as for the standard model.

6 There is a similar consideration with monetary policy. As in Nakata et al. (Reference Nakata, Ogaki, Schmidt and Yoo2019) and Budianto et al. (Reference Budianto, Nakata and Schmidt2020), the favorable effects of Forward Guidance—a promised long-run interest rate binding—on short-run inflation can be much attenuated if the economic agents cannot fully comprehend the world as represented by the NK model with rational expectations.

7 See Ramey (Reference Ramey2011) for a survey on the estimation of government spending multipliers in the literature.

8 In this paper, we define the nominal cost channel as the cost channel of the nominal interest rate and the real cost channel as the cost channel of the expected real interest rate.

9 Following Christiano et al. (Reference Christiano, Eichenbaum and Evans2011), I define $g_t=(G_t-G)/Y$ .

10 The derivation of the NK Phillips Curve with the real cost channel can be seen in Online Appendix A.

11 See Online Appendix A for exact expressions of these parameters.

12 See Gertler et al. (Reference Gertler, Gali and Clarida1999) and Woodford (Reference Woodford2003).

13 The subscripts $'S'$ and $'L'$ denote the state in the short and long run, respectively. The superscripts $'B'$ and $'N'$ denote the standard NK model without the cost channel and the model with the nominal cost channel, respectively. The duration of the short-run state can be calculated as $T=\frac{1}{1-p}$ . For instance, if $p=0.5$ , $T=\frac{1}{1-0.5}=2$ quarters.

15 The superscripts $'O'$ and $'I'$ denote the output gap multiplier and the inflation multiplier, respectively. The subscript $'N'$ denotes the economy in normal times.

14 In this paper, the three models refer to the conventional model without the cost channel, the model with the nominal cost channel, and the model with the real cost channel.

16 Government spending in normal times can crowd out private consumption, echoing classical empirical evidence as in Amano and Wirjanto (Reference Amano and Wirjanto1997) and Barro and Redlick (Reference Barro and Redlick2011).

17 An increase in government spending requires households to produce more, leading to longer working hours. To compensate for this, households demand a higher real wage. This, in turn, increases firms’ marginal costs, causing prices, which are set as a markup over the marginal cost, to also increase. This results in inflation.

18 This mechanism conforms with Ravenna and Walsh (Reference Ravenna and Walsh2006) such that cost-push shocks can emerge endogenously in the NK model with the cost channel.

19 With Taylor (Reference Taylor1993)-type rules followed by the central bank, there will be a rise in nominal interest rates by more than one-for-one with inflation pressure.

20 In this paper, the zero (effective) lower bound is a state when $R_t=0$ with the simple assumption that there are no cash storing costs in Galí (Reference Galí2015).

21 The subscript $'Z'$ denotes that the economy is stuck at the ZLB.

22 Abo-Zaid (Reference Abo-Zaid2022) differentiates between the policy rate and the loan rate, making the Phillips Curve steep in recessions. In that setup, if the two rates are equal, the nominal cost channel cannot impact the Phillips Curve slope in liquidity traps and cannot impact spending multipliers.

23 The Phillips Curve is locally flat with the real cost channel during recessions as in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022). Besides, Hazell et al. (Reference Hazell, Herreño, Nakamura and øn Steinsson2020) empirically document that the NK Phillips Curve is flat during the Great Recession.

24 The denominator of the multiplier in the standard model is $\mathcal{D}^B_Z=\sigma (1-p)(1-\beta p)-\kappa \gamma _yp$ and can be negative with a large $p$ .

25 The denominator of the multiplier with the real cost channel is $\mathcal{D}_Z=\sigma (1-p)(1-\beta p+\kappa \gamma _rp)-\kappa \gamma _yp$ , and one can show that $\mathcal{D}_Z=\mathcal{D}_Z^B+\sigma (1-p)\kappa \gamma _rp$ . Therefore, $\mathcal{D}_Z$ is larger than $\mathcal{D}_Z^B$ and less likely to be negative—See Nie (Reference Nie2021) for details.

26 The calibration method for the real cost channel closely follows Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022). To be more specific, Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022) implicitly set $\kappa =1$ in their calibration. The calibration of the cost channel parameters, $\kappa \gamma _r$ and $\kappa \gamma _y$ , in this paper matches Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022). The elasticity of inflation w.r.t. real interest rates equals 0.2, as estimated in Beaudry et al. (Reference Beaudry, Hou and Portier2022). The other parameters are calibrated in a standard way as in Budianto et al. (Reference Budianto, Nakata and Schmidt2020) and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Roulleau-Pasdeloup2021). In addition, the persistence $p$ is set to ensure that the denominator of the multiplier remains positive, even in models without the cost channel.

27 This calibration mimics, for example, the case of the Great Recession.

28 Among the three models, the boundary condition for the natural rate shock with the nominal cost channel is the most restrictive, causing the economy to fall into liquidity traps.

29 For the purpose of illustration, the range of the parameter $\gamma _r$ is from 0 to 1.

30 In Online Appendix H, the numerical result demonstrates a significant decrease in the output multiplier as we increase $\gamma _r$ from 0 to 1 under the assumption that the persistence of government spending shocks is $p=0.8$ , exceeding the benchmark’s $p=0.7$ .

31 The subscript $'M'$ means that the state is in the medium run.

32 In this section, to be in line with Section 2, I consider two economic states in the short run, which are normal times and the ZLB. In the medium run, I simply assume the demand shock reverts to zero and the economy is in normal times.

33 I follow a simple rule in Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup (Reference Nie and Roulleau-Pasdeloup2023) to deal with the medium-run shock: It is generally assumed that medium-run spending is contingent on short-run spending but it is lower than short-run spending such that $g_M=\zeta g_S$ , where $\zeta$ is a discount parameter.

34 In our simulation results, it is assumed that $q=0.7$ and $\zeta =0.5$ .

35 As in Gabaix (Reference Gabaix2020), this parameter can measure the attention to the future, which is a form of global cognitive discounting. Relative to rational expectations ( $\bar m=1$ ), when the behavioral agents contemplate future events, their expectations are geared to the steady state of the economy.

36 For simplicity, in this section, a simple two-state Markov chain is used to calculate fiscal multipliers.

37 Similar results can also arise with long-run government spending since the cognitive agent can decrease the expectation effects, which is in spirit with Nakata et al. (Reference Nakata, Ogaki, Schmidt and Yoo2019) and Farhi and Werning (Reference Farhi and án Werning2019).

38 At the ZLB, bounded rationality weakens the multiplier, echoing the dampening effects of myopia, as shown in McKay et al. (Reference McKay, Nakamura and Steinsson2016) and Angeletos and Lian (Reference Angeletos and Lian2018).

References

Abo-Zaid, S. (2022) The government spending multiplier in a model with the cost channel. Macroeconomic Dynamics 26(1), 72101.10.1017/S1365100520000061CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Acconcia, A., Corsetti, G. and Simonelli, S. (2014) Mafia and public spending: Evidence on the fiscal multiplier from a quasi-experiment. American Economic Review 104(7), 21852209.10.1257/aer.104.7.2185CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Amano, R. A. and Wirjanto, T. S. (1997) Intratemporal substitution and government spending. Review of Economics and Statistics 79(4), 605609.10.1162/003465397557187CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Angeletos, G.-M. and Lian, C. (2018) Forward guidance without common knowledge. American Economic Review 108(9), 24772512.10.1257/aer.20161996CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Aruoba, S. B., Cuba-Borda, P. and Schorfheide, F. (2018) Macroeconomic dynamics near the ZLB: A tale of two countries. The Review of Economic Studies 85(1), 87118.10.1093/restud/rdx027CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Auerbach, A. J., Gorodnichenko, Y., McCrory, P. and Murphy, D. (2021) Fiscal multipliers in the COVID19 recession. Technical Report. National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Auerbach, A. and Gorodnichenko, Y. (2012) Fiscal multipliers in recession and expansion. In: “Fiscal Policy after the Financial Crisis” NBER Chapters. National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.Google Scholar
Bachmann, R. and Sims, E. R. (2012) Confidence and the transmission of government spending shocks. Journal of Monetary Economics 59(3), 235249.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.02.005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barro, R. J. and Redlick, C. J. (2011) Macroeconomic effects from government purchases and taxes. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(1), 51102.10.1093/qje/qjq002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bayer, C., Born, B. and Luetticke, R. (2022) The liquidity channel of fiscal policy. Journal of Monetary Economics 134, 86117.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2022.11.009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Beaudry, P., Hou, C. and Portier, F. (2022), Monetary Policy When the Phillips Curve is Quite Flat. CEPR Discussion Paper DP15184, Working Paper.Google Scholar
Bhandari, A., Evans, D., Golosov, M. and Sargent, T. J. (2021) Inequality, business cycles, and monetary-fiscal policy. Econometrica 89(6), 25592599.10.3982/ECTA16414CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilbiie, F. O. (2020) The new Keynesian cross. Journal of Monetary Economics 114, 90108.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.03.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilbiie, F. O. (2019a) Monetary Policy and Heterogeneity: An Analytical Framework. CEPR Discussion Papers 12601, C.E.P.R. Discussion Papers.Google Scholar
Bilbiie, F. O. (2008) Limited asset markets participation, monetary policy and (inverted) aggregate demand logic. Journal of Economic Theory 140(1), 162196.10.1016/j.jet.2007.07.008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bilbiie, F. O. (2019b) Optimal forward guidance. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 11(4), 310345.Google Scholar
Blanchard, O. and Perotti, R. (2002) An empirical characterization of the dynamic effects of changes in government spending and taxes on output. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 117(4), 13291368.10.1162/003355302320935043CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouakez, H., Guillard, M. and Roulleau-Pasdeloup, J. (2017) Public investment, time to build, and the zero lower bound. Review of Economic Dynamics, January 23, 6079.10.1016/j.red.2016.09.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Bouakez, H., Guillard, M. and Roulleau-Pasdeloup, J. (2020) The optimal composition of public spending in a deep recession. Journal of Monetary Economics 114, 334349.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.03.006CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Budianto, F., Nakata, T. and Schmidt, S. (2020) Average inflation targeting and the interest rate lower bound. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Cantore, C. and Freund, L. B. (2021) Workers, capitalists, and the government: Fiscal policy and income (re) distribution. Journal of monetary economics 119, 5874.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2021.01.004CrossRefGoogle ScholarPubMed
Chowdhury, I., Hoffmann, M. and Schabert, A. (2006) Inflation dynamics and the cost channel of monetary transmission. European Economic Review 50(4), 9951016.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2005.01.007CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. L. (2011) When is the government spending multiplier large? Journal of Political Economy 119(1), 78121.10.1086/659312CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Christiano, L. J., Eichenbaum, M. and Evans, C. L. (2005) Nominal rigidities and the dynamic effects of a shock to monetary policy. Journal of Political Economy 113(1), 145.10.1086/426038CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Cochrane, J. H. (2017) The new-Keynesian liquidity trap. Journal of Monetary Economics 92(C), 4763.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2017.09.003CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Coibion, O., Georgarakos, D., Gorodnichenko, Y. and Weber, M. (2020) Forward guidance and household expectations. Technical Report. National Bureau of Economic Research.Google Scholar
Durevall, D. and Henrekson, M. (2011) The futile quest for a grand explanation of long-run government expenditure. Journal of Public Economics 95(7-8), 708722.10.1016/j.jpubeco.2011.02.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, G. B. and Woodford, M, P. (2003) Zero bound on interest rates and optimal monetary policy. Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 2003(1), 139233.10.1353/eca.2003.0010CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, G. B. (2001) Real Government Spending in a Liquidity Trap. Princeton University. Unpublished manuscript.Google Scholar
Eggertsson, G. B. (2011) What fiscal policy is effective at zero interest rates? NBER Macroeconomics Annual 25(1), 59112.10.1086/657529CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, G. B. and Woodford, M. (2003) Optimal Monetary Policy in a Liquidity Trap. NBER Working Papers 9968, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.3386/w9968CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Eggertsson, G. B. and Woodford, M. (2004) Optimal Monetary and Fiscal Policy in a Liquidity Trap. Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w10840CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Farhi, E. and án Werning, I. (2019) Monetary policy, bounded rationality, and incomplete markets. American Economic Review 109(11), 38873928.10.1257/aer.20171400CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Gabaix, X. (2020) A behavioral new Keynesian model. American Economic Review 110(8), 22712327.10.1257/aer.20162005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Galí, J. (2015) Monetary Policy, Inflation, and the Business Cycle: An Introduction to the New Keynesian Framework and Its Applications. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press.Google Scholar
Gertler, M., Gali, J. and Clarida, R. (1999) The science of monetary policy: A new Keynesian perspective. Journal of Economic Literature 37(4), 16611707.Google Scholar
Han, Z., Tan, F. and Wu, J. (2020) Learning from monetary and fiscal policy. Available at SSRN 3726905.10.2139/ssrn.3726905CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Hazell, J., Herreño, J., Nakamura, E. and øn Steinsson, J (2020) The Slope of the Phillips Curve: Evidence from U.S. States. Working Paper, National Bureau of Economic Research.10.3386/w28005CrossRefGoogle Scholar
House, C. L., Proebsting, C. and Tesar, L. L. (2020) Austerity in the aftermath of the great recession. Journal of Monetary Economics 115, 3763.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2019.05.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Barth, M. J. III, Ramey, V. A. (2001) The cost channel of monetary transmission. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 16, 199240.10.1086/654443CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ilzetzki, E., Mendoza, E. G. and Végh, C. A. (2013) How big (small?) are fiscal multipliers? Journal of Monetary Economics 60(2), 239254.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2012.10.011CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kiley, M. T. (2014), Policy Paradoxes in the New Keynesian Model. Finance and Economics Discussion Series 2014-29, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System (U.S.).Google Scholar
Koester, G., Lis, E., Nickel, C., Osbat, C. and Smets, F. (2021) Understanding low inflation in the euro area from 2013 to 2019: Cyclical and structural drivers. ECB Occasional Paper (2021280).10.2139/ssrn.3928302CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kollmann, R., Roeger, W., Veld, J. (2012) Fiscal policy in a financial crisis: Standard policy versus bank rescue measures. American Economic Review 102(3), 7781.10.1257/aer.102.3.77CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Kraay, A. (2012) How large is the government spending multiplier? Evidence from World Bank lending. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 127(2), 829887.10.1093/qje/qjs008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Laubach, T. and Williams, J. C. (2003) Measuring the natural rate of interest. Review of Economics and Statistics 85(4), 10631070.10.1162/003465303772815934CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leduc, S. and Wilson, D. (2013) Roads to prosperity or bridges to nowhere? Theory and evidence on the impact of public infrastructure investment. NBER Macroeconomics Annual 27(1), 89142.10.1086/669173CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Leeper, E. M., Traum, N. and Walker, T. B. (2017) Clearing up the fiscal multiplier morass. American Economic Review 107(8), 24092454.10.1257/aer.20111196CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Lewis, D. J. (2021) Identifying shocks via time-varying volatility. The Review of Economic Studies 88(6), 30863124.10.1093/restud/rdab009CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Llosa, L.-G. and Tuesta, V. (2009) Learning about monetary policy rules when the cost-channel matters. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 33(11), 18801896.10.1016/j.jedc.2009.05.001CrossRefGoogle Scholar
McKay, A., Nakamura, E. and Steinsson, J. (2016) The power of forward guidance revisited. American Economic Review 106(10), 31333158.10.1257/aer.20150063CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Mertens, K. R. S. M. and Ravn, M. O. (2014) Fiscal policy in an expectations-driven liquidity trap. The Review of Economic Studies 81(4), 16371667.10.1093/restud/rdu016CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Miyamoto, W., Nguyen, T. L. and Sergeyev, D. (2018) Government spending multipliers under the zero lower bound: Evidence from Japan. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 10(3), 247277.Google Scholar
Nakata, T., Ogaki, R., Schmidt, S. and Yoo, P. (2019) Attenuating the forward guidance puzzle: Implications for optimal monetary policy. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 105, 90106.10.1016/j.jedc.2019.05.013CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nie, H. (2021) The macroeconomic effects of tax shocks: The real cost channel. Available at SSRN 3905695.10.2139/ssrn.3905695CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Nie, H. and Roulleau-Pasdeloup, J. (2023) The promises (and perils) of control-contingent forward guidance. Review of Economic Dynamics 49, 7798.10.1016/j.red.2022.07.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramey, V. A. (2011) Identifying government spending shocks: It’s all in the timing. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 126(1), 150.10.1093/qje/qjq008CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ramey, V. A. and Zubairy, S. (2018) Government spending multipliers in good times and in bad: Evidence from US historical data. Journal of Political Economy 126(2), 850901.10.1086/696277CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Ravenna, F. and Walsh, C. E. (2006) Optimal monetary policy with the cost channel. Journal of Monetary Economics 2(53), 199216.10.1016/j.jmoneco.2005.01.004CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roulleau-Pasdeloup, J. (2023) Analyzing linear DSGE models: The method of undetermined Markov states. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 151, 104629.10.1016/j.jedc.2023.104629CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Roulleau-Pasdeloup, J. (2021) The public investment multiplier: Insights from a new analytical framework. Working Paper.Google Scholar
Sarin, N., Summers, L. H., Zidar, O. M. and Zwick, E. (2021) Rethinking How We Score Capital Gains Tax Reform. NBER Working Papers 28362, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc.10.3386/w28362CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Schmidt, S. (2017) Fiscal activism and the zero nominal interest rate bound. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 49(4), 695732.10.1111/jmcb.12395CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Smith, A. L. (2016) When does the cost channel pose a challenge to inflation targeting central banks? European Economic Review 89, 471494.10.1016/j.euroecorev.2016.09.002CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Surico, P. (2008) The cost channel of monetary policy and indeterminacy. Macroeconomic Dynamics 5(12), 724735.10.1017/S1365100508070338CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Taylor, J. B. (1993) Discretion versus policy rules in practice. Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy 39(1), 195214.10.1016/0167-2231(93)90009-LCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Tillmann, P. (2009) Optimal monetary policy with an uncertain cost channel. Journal of Money, Credit and Banking 41(5), 885906.10.1111/j.1538-4616.2009.00237.xCrossRefGoogle Scholar
Woodford, M. (2003) Optimal interest-rate smoothing. The Review of Economic Studies 70(4), 861886.10.1111/1467-937X.00270CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Yaffe, D. L. (2019) The Interstate Multiplier. University of California, San Diego Working paper.Google Scholar
Zubairy, S. (2014) On fiscal multipliers: Estimates from a medium scale DSGE model. International Economic Review 55(1), 169195.10.1111/iere.12045CrossRefGoogle Scholar
Figure 0

Table 1. Parameterization

Figure 1

Figure 1. AS/AD curves with natural rate shock in three models.

Figure 2

Figure 2. Spending multipliers in normal times.

Figure 3

Figure 3. Spending multipliers at ZLB.

Figure 4

Figure 4. Long-run government spending: a graphical representation.

Figure 5

Figure 5. Spending multipliers with long-run spending policy in normal times.

Figure 6

Figure 6. Spending multipliers with long-run spending policy at ZLB.

Figure 7

Figure 7. Spending multipliers with bounded rationality in normal times.

Figure 8

Figure 8. Spending multipliers with bounded rationality at ZLB.

Supplementary material: PDF

Nie supplementary material

Online Appendix

Download Nie supplementary material(PDF)
PDF 1.3 MB